
- •BUSINESSES IN THE BOOK
- •Preface
- •Brief Contents
- •CONTENTS
- •Why Study Strategy?
- •Why Economics?
- •The Need for Principles
- •So What’s the Problem?
- •Firms or Markets?
- •A Framework for Strategy
- •Boundaries of the Firm
- •Market and Competitive Analysis
- •Positioning and Dynamics
- •Internal Organization
- •The Book
- •Endnotes
- •Costs
- •Cost Functions
- •Total Cost Functions
- •Fixed and Variable Costs
- •Average and Marginal Cost Functions
- •The Importance of the Time Period: Long-Run versus Short-Run Cost Functions
- •Sunk versus Avoidable Costs
- •Economic Costs and Profitability
- •Economic versus Accounting Costs
- •Economic Profit versus Accounting Profit
- •Demand and Revenues
- •Demand Curve
- •The Price Elasticity of Demand
- •Brand-Level versus Industry-Level Elasticities
- •Total Revenue and Marginal Revenue Functions
- •Theory of the Firm: Pricing and Output Decisions
- •Perfect Competition
- •Game Theory
- •Games in Matrix Form and the Concept of Nash Equilibrium
- •Game Trees and Subgame Perfection
- •Chapter Summary
- •Questions
- •Endnotes
- •Doing Business in 1840
- •Transportation
- •Communications
- •Finance
- •Production Technology
- •Government
- •Doing Business in 1910
- •Business Conditions in 1910: A “Modern” Infrastructure
- •Production Technology
- •Transportation
- •Communications
- •Finance
- •Government
- •Doing Business Today
- •Modern Infrastructure
- •Transportation
- •Communications
- •Finance
- •Production Technology
- •Government
- •Infrastructure in Emerging Markets
- •Three Different Worlds: Consistent Principles, Changing Conditions, and Adaptive Strategies
- •Chapter Summary
- •Questions
- •Endnotes
- •Definitions
- •Definition of Economies of Scale
- •Definition of Economies of Scope
- •Economies of Scale Due to Spreading of Product-Specific Fixed Costs
- •Economies of Scale Due to Trade-offs among Alternative Technologies
- •“The Division of Labor Is Limited by the Extent of the Market”
- •Special Sources of Economies of Scale and Scope
- •Density
- •Purchasing
- •Advertising
- •Costs of Sending Messages per Potential Consumer
- •Advertising Reach and Umbrella Branding
- •Research and Development
- •Physical Properties of Production
- •Inventories
- •Complementarities and Strategic Fit
- •Sources of Diseconomies of Scale
- •Labor Costs and Firm Size
- •Spreading Specialized Resources Too Thin
- •Bureaucracy
- •Economies of Scale: A Summary
- •The Learning Curve
- •The Concept of the Learning Curve
- •Expanding Output to Obtain a Cost Advantage
- •Learning and Organization
- •The Learning Curve versus Economies of Scale
- •Diversification
- •Why Do Firms Diversify?
- •Efficiency-Based Reasons for Diversification
- •Scope Economies
- •Internal Capital Markets
- •Problematic Justifications for Diversification
- •Diversifying Shareholders’ Portfolios
- •Identifying Undervalued Firms
- •Reasons Not to Diversify
- •Managerial Reasons for Diversification
- •Benefits to Managers from Acquisitions
- •Problems of Corporate Governance
- •The Market for Corporate Control and Recent Changes in Corporate Governance
- •Performance of Diversified Firms
- •Chapter Summary
- •Questions
- •Endnotes
- •Make versus Buy
- •Upstream, Downstream
- •Defining Boundaries
- •Some Make-or-Buy Fallacies
- •Avoiding Peak Prices
- •Tying Up Channels: Vertical Foreclosure
- •Reasons to “Buy”
- •Exploiting Scale and Learning Economies
- •Bureaucracy Effects: Avoiding Agency and Influence Costs
- •Agency Costs
- •Influence Costs
- •Organizational Design
- •Reasons to “Make”
- •The Economic Foundations of Contracts
- •Complete versus Incomplete Contracting
- •Bounded Rationality
- •Difficulties Specifying or Measuring Performance
- •Asymmetric Information
- •The Role of Contract Law
- •Coordination of Production Flows through the Vertical Chain
- •Leakage of Private Information
- •Transactions Costs
- •Relationship-Specific Assets
- •Forms of Asset Specificity
- •The Fundamental Transformation
- •Rents and Quasi-Rents
- •The Holdup Problem
- •Holdup and Ex Post Cooperation
- •The Holdup Problem and Transactions Costs
- •Contract Negotiation and Renegotiation
- •Investments to Improve Ex Post Bargaining Positions
- •Distrust
- •Reduced Investment
- •Recap: From Relationship-Specific Assets to Transactions Costs
- •Chapter Summary
- •Questions
- •Endnotes
- •What Does It Mean to Be “Integrated?”
- •The Property Rights Theory of the Firm
- •Alternative Forms of Organizing Transactions
- •Governance
- •Delegation
- •Recapping PRT
- •Path Dependence
- •Making the Integration Decision
- •Technical Efficiency versus Agency Efficiency
- •The Technical Efficiency/Agency Efficiency Trade-off
- •Real-World Evidence
- •Double Marginalization: A Final Integration Consideration
- •Alternatives to Vertical Integration
- •Tapered Integration: Make and Buy
- •Franchising
- •Strategic Alliances and Joint Ventures
- •Implicit Contracts and Long-Term Relationships
- •Business Groups
- •Keiretsu
- •Chaebol
- •Business Groups in Emerging Markets
- •Chapter Summary
- •Questions
- •Endnotes
- •Competitor Identification and Market Definition
- •The Basics of Competitor Identification
- •Example 5.1 The SSNIP in Action: Defining Hospital Markets
- •Putting Competitor Identification into Practice
- •Empirical Approaches to Competitor Identification
- •Geographic Competitor Identification
- •Measuring Market Structure
- •Market Structure and Competition
- •Perfect Competition
- •Many Sellers
- •Homogeneous Products
- •Excess Capacity
- •Monopoly
- •Monopolistic Competition
- •Demand for Differentiated Goods
- •Entry into Monopolistically Competitive Markets
- •Oligopoly
- •Cournot Quantity Competition
- •The Revenue Destruction Effect
- •Cournot’s Model in Practice
- •Bertrand Price Competition
- •Why Are Cournot and Bertrand Different?
- •Evidence on Market Structure and Performance
- •Price and Concentration
- •Chapter Summary
- •Questions
- •Endnotes
- •6: Entry and Exit
- •Some Facts about Entry and Exit
- •Entry and Exit Decisions: Basic Concepts
- •Barriers to Entry
- •Bain’s Typology of Entry Conditions
- •Analyzing Entry Conditions: The Asymmetry Requirement
- •Structural Entry Barriers
- •Control of Essential Resources
- •Economies of Scale and Scope
- •Marketing Advantages of Incumbency
- •Barriers to Exit
- •Entry-Deterring Strategies
- •Limit Pricing
- •Is Strategic Limit Pricing Rational?
- •Predatory Pricing
- •The Chain-Store Paradox
- •Rescuing Limit Pricing and Predation: The Importance of Uncertainty and Reputation
- •Wars of Attrition
- •Predation and Capacity Expansion
- •Strategic Bundling
- •“Judo Economics”
- •Evidence on Entry-Deterring Behavior
- •Contestable Markets
- •An Entry Deterrence Checklist
- •Entering a New Market
- •Preemptive Entry and Rent Seeking Behavior
- •Chapter Summary
- •Questions
- •Endnotes
- •Microdynamics
- •Strategic Commitment
- •Strategic Substitutes and Strategic Complements
- •The Strategic Effect of Commitments
- •Tough and Soft Commitments
- •A Taxonomy of Commitment Strategies
- •The Informational Benefits of Flexibility
- •Real Options
- •Competitive Discipline
- •Dynamic Pricing Rivalry and Tit-for-Tat Pricing
- •Why Is Tit-for-Tat So Compelling?
- •Coordinating on the Right Price
- •Impediments to Coordination
- •The Misread Problem
- •Lumpiness of Orders
- •Information about the Sales Transaction
- •Volatility of Demand Conditions
- •Facilitating Practices
- •Price Leadership
- •Advance Announcement of Price Changes
- •Most Favored Customer Clauses
- •Uniform Delivered Prices
- •Where Does Market Structure Come From?
- •Sutton’s Endogenous Sunk Costs
- •Innovation and Market Evolution
- •Learning and Industry Dynamics
- •Chapter Summary
- •Questions
- •Endnotes
- •8: Industry Analysis
- •Performing a Five-Forces Analysis
- •Internal Rivalry
- •Entry
- •Substitutes and Complements
- •Supplier Power and Buyer Power
- •Strategies for Coping with the Five Forces
- •Coopetition and the Value Net
- •Applying the Five Forces: Some Industry Analyses
- •Chicago Hospital Markets Then and Now
- •Market Definition
- •Internal Rivalry
- •Entry
- •Substitutes and Complements
- •Supplier Power
- •Buyer Power
- •Commercial Airframe Manufacturing
- •Market Definition
- •Internal Rivalry
- •Barriers to Entry
- •Substitutes and Complements
- •Supplier Power
- •Buyer Power
- •Professional Sports
- •Market Definition
- •Internal Rivalry
- •Entry
- •Substitutes and Complements
- •Supplier Power
- •Buyer Power
- •Conclusion
- •Professional Search Firms
- •Market Definition
- •Internal Rivalry
- •Entry
- •Substitutes and Complements
- •Supplier Power
- •Buyer Power
- •Conclusion
- •Chapter Summary
- •Questions
- •Endnotes
- •Competitive Advantage Defined
- •Maximum Willingness-to-Pay and Consumer Surplus
- •From Maximum Willingness-to-Pay to Consumer Surplus
- •Value-Created
- •Value Creation and “Win–Win” Business Opportunities
- •Value Creation and Competitive Advantage
- •Analyzing Value Creation
- •Value Creation and the Value Chain
- •Value Creation, Resources, and Capabilities
- •Generic Strategies
- •The Strategic Logic of Cost Leadership
- •The Strategic Logic of Benefit Leadership
- •Extracting Profits from Cost and Benefit Advantage
- •Comparing Cost and Benefit Advantages
- •“Stuck in the Middle”
- •Diagnosing Cost and Benefit Drivers
- •Cost Drivers
- •Cost Drivers Related to Firm Size, Scope, and Cumulative Experience
- •Cost Drivers Independent of Firm Size, Scope, or Cumulative Experience
- •Cost Drivers Related to Organization of the Transactions
- •Benefit Drivers
- •Methods for Estimating and Characterizing Costs and Perceived Benefits
- •Estimating Costs
- •Estimating Benefits
- •Strategic Positioning: Broad Coverage versus Focus Strategies
- •Segmenting an Industry
- •Broad Coverage Strategies
- •Focus Strategies
- •Chapter Summary
- •Questions
- •Endnotes
- •The “Shopping Problem”
- •Unraveling
- •Alternatives to Disclosure
- •Nonprofit Firms
- •Report Cards
- •Multitasking: Teaching to the Test
- •What to Measure
- •Risk Adjustment
- •Presenting Report Card Results
- •Gaming Report Cards
- •The Certifier Market
- •Certification Bias
- •Matchmaking
- •When Sellers Search for Buyers
- •Chapter Summary
- •Questions
- •Endnotes
- •Market Structure and Threats to Sustainability
- •Threats to Sustainability in Competitive and Monopolistically Competitive Markets
- •Threats to Sustainability under All Market Structures
- •Evidence: The Persistence of Profitability
- •The Resource-Based Theory of the Firm
- •Imperfect Mobility and Cospecialization
- •Isolating Mechanisms
- •Impediments to Imitation
- •Legal Restrictions
- •Superior Access to Inputs or Customers
- •The Winner’s Curse
- •Market Size and Scale Economies
- •Intangible Barriers to Imitation
- •Causal Ambiguity
- •Dependence on Historical Circumstances
- •Social Complexity
- •Early-Mover Advantages
- •Learning Curve
- •Reputation and Buyer Uncertainty
- •Buyer Switching Costs
- •Network Effects
- •Networks and Standards
- •Competing “For the Market” versus “In the Market”
- •Knocking off a Dominant Standard
- •Early-Mover Disadvantages
- •Imperfect Imitability and Industry Equilibrium
- •Creating Advantage and Creative Destruction
- •Disruptive Technologies
- •The Productivity Effect
- •The Sunk Cost Effect
- •The Replacement Effect
- •The Efficiency Effect
- •Disruption versus the Resource-Based Theory of the Firm
- •Innovation and the Market for Ideas
- •The Environment
- •Factor Conditions
- •Demand Conditions
- •Related Supplier or Support Industries
- •Strategy, Structure, and Rivalry
- •Chapter Summary
- •Questions
- •Endnotes
- •The Principal–Agent Relationship
- •Combating Agency Problems
- •Performance-Based Incentives
- •Problems with Performance-Based Incentives
- •Preferences over Risky Outcomes
- •Risk Sharing
- •Risk and Incentives
- •Selecting Performance Measures: Managing Trade-offs between Costs
- •Do Pay-for-Performance Incentives Work?
- •Implicit Incentive Contracts
- •Subjective Performance Evaluation
- •Promotion Tournaments
- •Efficiency Wages and the Threat of Termination
- •Incentives in Teams
- •Chapter Summary
- •Questions
- •Endnotes
- •13: Strategy and Structure
- •An Introduction to Structure
- •Individuals, Teams, and Hierarchies
- •Complex Hierarchy
- •Departmentalization
- •Coordination and Control
- •Approaches to Coordination
- •Types of Organizational Structures
- •Functional Structure (U-form)
- •Multidivisional Structure (M-form)
- •Matrix Structure
- •Matrix or Division? A Model of Optimal Structure
- •Network Structure
- •Why Are There So Few Structural Types?
- •Structure—Environment Coherence
- •Technology and Task Interdependence
- •Efficient Information Processing
- •Structure Follows Strategy
- •Strategy, Structure, and the Multinational Firm
- •Chapter Summary
- •Questions
- •Endnotes
- •The Social Context of Firm Behavior
- •Internal Context
- •Power
- •The Sources of Power
- •Structural Views of Power
- •Do Successful Organizations Need Powerful Managers?
- •The Decision to Allocate Formal Power to Individuals
- •Culture
- •Culture Complements Formal Controls
- •Culture Facilitates Cooperation and Reduces Bargaining Costs
- •Culture, Inertia, and Performance
- •A Word of Caution about Culture
- •External Context, Institutions, and Strategies
- •Institutions and Regulation
- •Interfirm Resource Dependence Relationships
- •Industry Logics: Beliefs, Values, and Behavioral Norms
- •Chapter Summary
- •Questions
- •Endnotes
- •Glossary
- •Name Index
- •Subject Index

274 • Chapter 8 • Industry Analysis
Unionized labor has substantial supplier power. Currently, nearly half of Boeing’s workforce is unionized. The unions have cooperated in developing work rules to encourage and protect specific investments by workers. But unions have threatened to strike (and have gone on strike) over wages and can extract a substantial fraction of Boeing profits. Boeing’s decision to outsource much of the production of the 787, as well as to open a new assembly plant in South Carolina (a state without a strong union presence), may have been responses to such threats. It is unclear what percentage of Airbus’s workforce is unionized. European labor regulations are stricter than U.S. regulations, providing greater protection of unionized employees. However, a significant percentage of work on Airbus planes is done by subcontractors, serving to mitigate the effects of regulations.
Buyer Power
There are two categories of buyers, each of which has limited power. Some airlines own their own fleets, but many also lease aircraft from aircraft-leasing companies. These companies purchase airframes directly from the manufacturer and then lease the planes to the airlines, keeping the assets off the airlines’ books. The major airlines and the largest leasing companies often place orders for dozens of planes at a time. One company’s order can make up approximately 15 percent of all of Boeing’s or Airbus’s commercial airframe orders in a single year.
The fact that there are few substitutes works to the advantage of the manufacturers, but only to the point where it begins to compete with its rival manufacturer to maintain a minimum level of backlog orders. In addition, in times of economic downturns, buyers have the ability to cancel deliveries of aircraft, directly affecting the profitability of manufacturers.
Table 8.2 summarizes the five forces of the commercial aviation industry. As long as market conditions are favorable, Airbus and Boeing will prosper, threatened only by Bombardier and Embraer, and then only in a segment of their market.
Professional Sports
Our next example of industry analysis explores the popular world of professional sports. We focus on the four major U.S. sports leagues—Major League Baseball (MLB), the National Basketball Association (NBA), the National Football League (NFL), and the National Hockey League (NHL). Most of this analysis would apply equally well to sports leagues in other nations, such as European club football (i.e., soccer). For the most part, we will perform our analysis by assuming that team owners are trying to maximize profits. In reality, many team owners would gladly
TABLE 8.2
Five-Forces Analysis of the Commercial Aviation Industry
Force |
Threat to Profits |
Internal rivalry |
Low to medium |
Entry |
Low |
Substitutes/complements |
Medium |
Supplier power |
Medium |
Buyer power |
Medium |
|
|
Applying the Five Forces: Some Industry Analyses • 275
sacrifice some profits in exchange for a title; owning a sports team is the ultimate billionaire’s “hobby.”
Market Definition
It is difficult to define the markets in which professional sports teams compete. Each league competes for labor in a single national (or international) labor market, yet individual teams may be monopolists in the output of, say, “professional football entertainment” in their home cities. We will bear these distinctions in mind as we address how each of the five forces affects firm and industry profits in the major professional sports.
Internal Rivalry
Competition on the playing field does not equate to competition in the business world. Exciting athletic competition that will attract fans requires considerable coordination (some would say collusion) among the teams. Teams must agree on rules and schedules and employ the same pool of referees. They share national broadcast revenues. A sports league also requires some degree of competitive balance to attract fan interest. This has given rise to rules and other arrangements that are jointly designed and agreed-upon by all teams in the league. Teams do not coordinate on ticket prices, but they do not have to. When it comes to competition in output markets, most sports teams have substantial market power.
Most sports teams generate the lion’s share of revenues from ticket sales. (The exception is the NFL, whose 32 teams split over $3 billion in annual payments from a consortium of television networks.) One might argue that sports teams attempting to maximize their ticket revenues are competing against other local entertainment options. For example, the Chicago Bulls professional basketball team vies for customers who might instead consider attending local blues, jazz, and classical music concerts, theaters, movies, restaurants, the DePaul Blue Demons college basketball games, and the Chicago Blackhawks professional hockey games. But the Bulls are monopolists in the market for Chicago professional basketball, and the elasticity of substitution between Bulls tickets and other entertainment events is modest.3 Even teams that face direct competition in their local markets—for example, the Chicago White Sox and Chicago Cubs in major league baseball—have fiercely loyal fans who would hardly think of buying tickets to their cross-town rivals’ games just to save a few dollars. When it comes to selling tickets to see a major sport, nearly every team in the NFL, NBA, MLB, and NHL has considerable market power.
When sports teams do compete against each other in the traditional business sense, the “playing field” is the market for labor. The market to employ athletes hardly fits the “textbook” model of competition. Athletes in all four major sports are unionized, so the market for their labor is subject to labor laws. These laws are particularly important when it comes to employment of new ballplayers (i.e., rookies). Labor laws permit managers and unionized workers in any U.S. industry, including professional sports, to set conditions for employment of new workers through their collective bargaining agreements. One of the conditions in sports collective bargaining agreements is that new players are assigned to teams though rookie drafts.
All sports fans know how the rookie market works. Each major sports league conducts a rookie draft at the conclusion of its season. Only players meeting certain criteria based on age and/or educational attainment are eligible to be drafted. Teams pick in reverse order of their past performance, so that the worst teams get to choose
276 • Chapter 8 • Industry Analysis
the best players, and all teams have one-year exclusive rights to contract with their chosen players.4 Depending on the league, rookies are afforded some latitude in negotiating their initial contract terms, including length and salary. Rookies have few alternatives if they do not wish to sign with the team that drafted them; mainly, they can refuse to play for one year (and lose one year’s compensation), or they can sign with another league. Because these alternatives are generally very unattractive, sports teams have tremendous bargaining power over rookies. Some baseball teams, such as the Pittsburgh Pirates and Washington Nationals, have managed to remain reasonably prosperous by relying on low-priced young players. (On occasion, these low-payroll teams have great on-field success.) By contrast, some basketball teams, such as the Indiana Pacers, have shied away from drafting very young rookies, feeling that by the time these athletes develop into stars, their contracts will have expired and they will be free agents, able to sell themselves to the highest bidders.
At one time, all the major sports leagues had rules limiting the mobility of veterans. The NFL had the “Rozelle Rule,” named for its famous commissioner Pete Rozelle, which required any team that signed a player from another team to pay compensation, often in the form of a future draft pick. The NBA and NHL had similar rules. By the early 1980s, these rules had been eliminated as part of collective bargaining agreements.
Baseball’s route toward a free labor market was more circuitous. For years, professional baseball contracts contained a provision known as the reserve clause. If a player refused to sign the contract offered by his team, the reserve clause gave the team the right to automatically renew his expiring contract for the next year. The traditional interpretation of the reserve clause was that if a player continued to remain unsigned, a team could renew the old contract year after year in perpetuity. As a result, baseball players had virtually no bargaining power vis-à-vis their teams. The reserve clause explains why the immortal Babe Ruth never earned more than $100,000 per season—roughly $1 million today in inflation-adjusted dollars—far less than major league stars earn today.
In 1970, St. Louis Cardinals outfielder Curt Flood (who balked at being traded to the Philadelphia Phillies) filed an antitrust challenge to the reserve clause. In a confusing 1972 ruling, the Supreme Court cited Justice Learned Hand’s old ruling that baseball was the “national pastime” and was therefore exempt from antitrust laws. For a time it appeared as if the reserve clause had dodged a bullet and would remain intact. However, in 1975, two major league baseball pitchers, Andy Messersmith and Dave McNally, challenged the interpretation of the reserve clause, contending that the right to re-sign a player who refuses to sign a contract extended, not indefinitely as baseball owners had always contended, but for just one year. Arbitrator Peter Seitz agreed with the Messersmith–McNally interpretation, ruling that a ball club could renew an unsigned player’s contract for just one year, after which the player would become a “free agent” who would be able to sell his services to the highest bidder. Seitz, who had been retained by Major League Baseball, was promptly fired, and baseball owners went to court to challenge his decision. In February 1976, a federal judge upheld Seitz’s ruling, ushering in baseball’s free agency era.
For many reasons, competition in the input market for free agents can be intense. There are numerous competitors—in principle, every team in the league is a potential buyer. There is little differentiation—most players can be equally productive on any team and have little hometown loyalty, though some may take a small pay cut in order to play in a big market like New York or a warm-weather market like Miami.
A few factors soften wage competition, however. Very few athletes can make a major impact on a team’s chances of winning a championship; as a result, salaries for midlevel athletes fall well short of the salaries of superstars. Moreover, the number of
Applying the Five Forces: Some Industry Analyses • 277
serious competitors for a star athlete is limited. When superstar pitcher Cliff Lee became a free agent after the 2010 season, only two or three teams entered the bidding war. He signed with the Philadelphia Phillies for $120 million over five years. Despite paying huge salaries to Lee and other stars, the Phillies’ owners reportedly earned more than $15 million on total expenses of about $250 million, a tidy return on sales. (The Phillies’ owners also enjoyed all the perks of ownership, which should be considered part of their “profit” from owning the team.)
Most professional sports team owners will say that unchecked competition in the labor market makes it almost impossible to make a profit. This is why owners have been so adamant in seeking “salary caps” that limit the total amount teams can pay their players. The NHL owners went so far as to cancel the entire 2004–2005 season to force players to accept a salary cap, and the NBA owners threatened to do the same in 2011. Through the salary cap, teams and players share the profits they enjoy from their monopoly status in the output market. The most important issue in contract negotiations is the magnitude of the cap; this is what determines who gets the largest piece of the monopoly pie. Instead of a salary cap, baseball has a “luxury tax” that kicks in when a team’s aggregate salaries exceed roughly $180 million. Thus far, only a handful of teams have ever paid the tax.
Entry
Sports team owners are a motley group—they include media companies like Cablevision (owner of the NBA New York Knicks and NHL New York Rangers) and Time Warner (MLB’s Atlanta Braves), and the 100,000 local fans who own stock in the Green Bay Packers. (Don’t bother trying to become a part owner—the Packers are not issuing new shares, and existing shares may not be resold.) Many owners are wealthy businessmen for whom owning a sports team is the ultimate high-priced hobby. They include Micky Aronson (heir to the Carnival Cruise empire and owner of the Miami Heat basketball team); real estate tycoon Malcolm Glazer (owner of the NFL Tampa Bay Buccaneers and, much to the chagrin of their fans, English Soccer League powerhouse Manchester United); Mark Cuban (who sits on the bench and prowls the locker room of his Dallas Mavericks); and Mikhail Prokhorov (a Russian billionaire who recently purchased the Brooklyn Nets).
There is no shortage of rich men (and the occasional rich woman) who want to enjoy the limelight of sports team ownership. But it is not so easy—the barriers to entry are very high. Each league has rules governing the addition of new franchises. Potential new owners must pay current owners hundreds of millions of dollars. Most potential owners also offer to build new stadiums, knowing that visiting team owners will share ticket revenues (and therefore might be more inclined to vote in favor of league expansion). Incumbent team owners usually have the right to veto new franchises in their own geographic markets, further hindering entry. Unable to start sports teams from scratch, billionaires looking to join a league are usually forced to purchase an existing team. During the early to mid-2000s, the number of billionaires increased faster than the supply of teams, resulting in dramatic increases in purchase prices. A few teams like the NFL Dallas Cowboys and MLB New York Yankees would reportedly sell for over $1 billion, and Prokhorov paid $200 million for an 80 percent stake in the Nets, a perennial doormat in the NBA. So even though some sports teams post operating losses, their owners may be enjoying huge capital gains.
Short of buying an existing team, the only other way for a would-be sports entrepreneur to enter the professional sports market is to form an entire new league. This raises the stakes for entry considerably—most of the new teams must succeed or the
278 • Chapter 8 • Industry Analysis
entire league is likely to fail. Though the risks are high, the rewards can be even higher, and a number of leagues have come and gone over the years, including the World Football League, the United States Football League (USFL), the XFL, and the Arena Football League (the NFL is very profitable), the American Basketball Association (ABA), and the World Hockey League.
Entry barriers are so severe that new leagues feel the need to differentiate their product in order to survive: The ABA introduced the 3-point shot; the USFL played its games in late winter and spring; the XFL offered a more violent game that shared ownership and marketing savvy with the World Wrestling Federation. The Arena Football League plays indoors on a field the size of a hockey rink.
Not every new league fails. The Arena Football League is 25 years old, though few fans feel it is an adequate substitute for the NFL. The older American Football League (AFL) and, to a lesser extent, the ABA, can be considered success stories, and the paths to their success were very similar. The AFL began in 1960, just as the NFL’s popularity was on the rise. The AFL took advantage of three of the NFL’s shortcomings: the NFL had teams in just 13 cities, the NFL style downplayed the exciting passing game, and NFL players had yet to earn the rights to free agency and the high salaries that would result. The AFL began with eight teams, six of which were located in cities that did not have NFL franchises.5 AFL teams emphasized passing, and the resulting high scoring games proved appealing to many fans. Even so, AFL teams lost money year after year. Following the dictum that you have to spend money to make money, in 1965 the AFL launched its most brazen attack on the NFL.
In the previous year, 1964, the AFL signed a $34 million television contract with NBC. (CBS had exclusive rights to NFL games.) AFL teams used the money to outbid the NFL for superstar players. New York Jets owner Sonny Werblin moved first by signing University of Alabama star quarterback Joe Namath to a deal paying an unprecedented $427,000 for the first year. When the AFL’s Denver Broncos made a big offer to University of Illinois star Dick Butkus, the NFL assured the future Hall- of-Famer that he would receive “wheelbarrows” full of money if he signed with them. (He chose the NFL’s Chicago Bears.) Soon, both leagues were giving wheelbarrows of money to stars like Roman Gabriel, John Brodie, and Pete Gogolak. After Oakland Raiders head coach Al Davis became the AFL’s commissioner in April 1966, the bidding wars intensified. The AFL, which was never profitable, took big losses, but it did not matter. The NFL was losing money for the first time in over a decade and sued for peace. In June 1966, the two leagues merged. The owners of AFL teams got what they wanted—the same fan base enjoyed by the NFL. In today’s NFL, the American Football Conference still consists largely of former AFL teams.
The American Basketball Association (ABA) started in 1967. Like the AFL, most of the original 11 teams were located in non-NBA cities. Like the AFL, the ABA emphasized scoring, with a wide-open “up and down the court game” and the innovative 3-point shot. Like the AFL, the ABA paid big dollars to sign budding superstars such as “Dr. J” Julius Erving and scoring phenom Rick Barry. All of these strategies helped the ABA enjoy a loyal fan base. But because games were played in secondary markets like Pittsburgh, Louisville, and New Orleans, the national fan base was never large enough to generate a big television contract, and the league was unprofitable. The ABA did have one thing going for it that the AFL did not: basketball fans had become disenchanted with the NBA, and attendance was falling. In 1977, when the NBA agreed to absorb four ABA teams, it hoped that the infusion of the upbeat style embodied by Dr. J would change the league’s fortunes. Indeed, Dr. J’s popularity heralded a new era for basketball, based on stars rather than teams. The later success of the NBA and