Добавил:
Upload Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:
Economics of strategy 6th edition.pdf
Скачиваний:
441
Добавлен:
26.03.2016
Размер:
3.36 Mб
Скачать

An Introduction to Structure 445

replicate its complex structure and systems in international settings, such as Indonesia, China, or India. Even small changes in structure and systems required to do business overseas seemed to harm performance. It was only after the turn of the millennium, following years of trial and error, that Lincoln learned how to more effectively adapt to its new markets.9

Approaches to Coordination

There are two alternative approaches for developing coordination within firms.10 The first emphasizes autonomy or self-containment, whereas the second emphasizes strong lateral relations. When firms organize using autonomous work units, unit managers control information about operating decisions. Operating information remains within the units, and unit managers provide summary financial and accounting data, including profit data when available, to headquarters. But the flow of information across units is minimal. Firms that are organized this way are more likely to employ corporate strategies featuring mergers and acquisitions, since units that are organized autonomously are easier to both append to a current structure or to detach from that structure and transfer to the control of an acquirer.

A common approach to self-containment is to organize into separate product groups, each of which contains the basic business functions of manufacturing and sales and could plausibly exist by itself in the marketplace (as a spinoff). These autonomous groups, often called profit centers, are controlled on the basis of a target profit goal. Managers in autonomous groups are rewarded for meeting or exceeding a profit goal and punished for failing to meet it. Managers in autonomous divisions may have limited interactions with their counterparts in other units. Diversified firms, such as Procter & Gamble and Johnson & Johnson, make frequent use of profit centers. As discussed in Chapter 2, there is considerable research evidence questioning whether such diversification is profitable. After all, if individual profit centers are fully autonomous, there is little to be gained by joining under a single corporate umbrella. When groups focus on other performance measures besides profit, such as cost, revenue, or investment goals, they are called responsibility centers. Research programs at pharmaceutical companies often make use of responsibility centers and base their performance judgments on such criteria of research productivity as patents and research publications.

The alternative to self-contained groupings is the development of lateral relations across units. Lateral relations make sense when realizing economies of scale or scope requires close coordination among work groups. Lateral relations can be informal, such as with ad hoc or temporary teams or liaisons, or they can be formalized within the firm’s structure. An example of a formal attempt to foster lateral relations is the matrix organization, in which employees are subject to two or more sets of managers at once. This occurs, for example, when an engineer reports both to a research and development department and a project office, or when a salesperson reports both to the head of sales for a particular product and to a regional manager. We discuss matrix organizations in more detail in the next section.

A firm’s authority is often described in terms of centralization or decentralization. As more decisions are made by senior managers, the firm is said to be more centralized regarding those decisions. Since 2000, centralization decisions have been associated with efforts by corporations to adjust to harsher industry conditions and generally declining demand. An example of this can be seen in the 2008 announcement that the European aerospace firm EADS was considering an extensive restructuring that would consolidate the firm’s five divisions into three. Conversely, as more decisions

446 Chapter 13 Strategy and Structure

EXAMPLE 13.1 ABB’S MATRIX ORGANIZATION12

Asea Brown Boveri (ABB) is a large global producer of heavy capital equipment, such as turbine generators and railway engines. It was formed in 1988 when ASEA of Sweden merged with Brown Boveri of Switzerland. Soon after the merger, ABB’s senior management concluded that to be more responsive to customer needs in different parts of the world, ABB’s organization would have to be decentralized and made flexible to local conditions. ABB was thus reorganized. The reorganization resulted in a matrix structure in which ABB’s 1,300 local business units (e.g., its railway engine division in Norway) were organized along two dimensions: products and geography. On the product dimension, ABB created 65 business areas (BAs), each responsible for one of ABB’s product lines. On the geography dimension, ABB created countrywide organizations. At the intersection of a matrix were local business units, each responsible for a particular product line within a particular country. The head of each local unit was subject to “dual reporting.” That is, the manager for a particular product line in a given country would report to both the worldwide business area manager for that product line and to the head of the countrywide organization for that country.

Some of the immediate successes that arose from ABB’s restructuring were reductions in manufacturing costs through rationalizing production operations and improving new product development through better targeting of R&D funding. The BAs organized themselves according to a “lead center”

concept. Under this concept, for each product line, one location was chosen to provide worldwide product leadership and support. All R&D and process improvement efforts were concentrated in this location, from which successful strategies were transferred to other locations. Each lead center became the single source for the collective knowledge within each of ABB’s product lines.

ABB’s matrix structure also encouraged healthy competition among the various geographic units that made up a BA. The units that provided the most efficient manufacturing facilities were retained to cater to the BA’s worldwide requirements. These plants were then expanded to achieve global-scale production levels, thereby giving them scale efficiencies. This helped the company become the leader in almost all the product groups in which it competed. Inefficient plants were shut down or sold. ABB encountered one serious problem with its matrix structure, however. Because the structure essentially requires multiple reporting, important decisions had to be taken by multimember teams from all over the world. This slowed down decision making. To overcome this, ABB embarked on an ambitious internal mail and information system based on Lotus Notes. This system allowed managers to freely communicate, exchange files and data, and thus make decisions more quickly. With over 70,000 users around the world, ABB’s Lotus Notes network became a backbone for reporting and decision making within the organization.

are made at lower levels, the firm becomes more decentralized regarding those decisions. Decentralization is frequently associated with diversification, so that as the variety of a firm’s businesses increases, decision making will naturally devolve to the firm’s divisions. An example of such a decentralized firm would be Johnson & Johnson, a diversified corporation with significant businesses in consumer products, pharmaceuticals, and medical devices.

Firms are often referred to as either centralized or decentralized, but the situation in most firms is more complicated because they are often centralized on some dimensions and decentralized on others. Because a firm delegates operating authority to

Соседние файлы в предмете [НЕСОРТИРОВАННОЕ]