Добавил:
Upload Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:
Economics of strategy 6th edition.pdf
Скачиваний:
441
Добавлен:
26.03.2016
Размер:
3.36 Mб
Скачать

312 Chapter 9 Strategic Positioning for Competitive Advantage

FIGURE 9.10

The Economic Logic of Benefit Leadership

P, C

(Price, unit cost) Indifference curve

F

PF

E

PE

CF

C

CE

 

q

qE

q (Quality)

qF

All firms except the benefit leader offer a product with a cost CE and price–quality position at point E. The benefit leader offers a product with a higher-quality level, qF, and in so doing, incurs a higher cost CF, resulting in a cost disadvantage of DC. Consumer surplus parity is achieved when the cost leader operates at point F by charging a price PF. At point F, PF 2 PE . CF 2 CE, or, rearranging terms, PF 2 CF . PE 2 CE. This tells us that despite its cost disadvantage, the benefit leader achieves a higher profit margin than its lower-benefit competitors.

Figure 9.10 illustrates the economic logic of benefit leadership using a value map. For simplicity, let’s consider an industry in which all firms except the benefit leader offer a product with a cost CE and price–quality position at point E. Suppose the benefit leader offers a product with a higher-quality level, qF, and in so doing, incurs a somewhat higher cost CF, resulting in a cost disadvantage of DC. Market shares in the industry will be stable when the benefit leader and its lower-quality competitors attain consumer surplus parity. Consumer surplus parity is achieved when the benefit leader operates at point F by charging a price PF. From the figure, notice that PF 2 PE . CF 2 CE, or rearranging terms, PF 2 CF . PE 2 CE. Given consumer surplus parity between the benefit leader and its lower-quality competitors, the benefit leader achieves a higher profit margin. In essence, the leader’s benefit advantage gives it the “wiggle room” to charge a price premium relative to its lower-benefit, lower-cost rivals without sacrificing market share.

Extracting Profits from Cost and Benefit Advantage

A firm that creates more value than its competitors would like to capture as much as possible of that value for itself in the form of profits. If consumers have identical preferences (i.e., the same value map applies to all consumers in the market), value

Strategic Positioning: Cost Advantage and Benefit Advantage 313

extraction takes an especially stark form. When a firm increases its consumer surplus “bid” slightly above competitors, it captures the entire market. This leads to two clear recipes for retaining profits for a firm that creates more value than its competitors. Both involve making consumer surplus bids that the firm’s rivals cannot match:

1.A cost leader that has benefit parity with its rivals can lower its price just below the unit cost of the firm with the next lowest unit cost. This makes it unprofitable for higher-cost competitors to respond with price cuts of their own and thus allows the firm to capture the entire market.

2.A benefit leader that has cost parity with its rivals can raise its price just below the sum of the following: (1) its unit cost, plus (2) the additional benefit DB creates relative to the competitor with the next highest B. To top this consumer surplus bid, a competitor would have to cut price below its unit cost, which would be unprofitable. At this price, then, the firm with the benefit advantage captures the entire market.

What happens if one firm is a cost leader and the other is a benefit leader? If consumers have identical preferences, then the firm that offers the higher B 2 C can capture the entire market, by setting price at the point where the other firm cannot make a better consumer surplus bid and still cover its costs.

These extreme scenarios, in which one firm captures the entire market, result because consumers are assumed to have identical preferences. This would not happen in a market characterized by horizontal differentiation. As we discuss in Chapters 5 and 10, horizontal differentiation is likely to be strong when there are many product attributes that consumers weigh in assessing overall benefit B, and consumers disagree about the desirability of those attributes. In markets where there is horizontal differentiation, lowering price or boosting quality will attract some consumers, but others will not switch unless the differential in price or quality is large enough. In these markets, the price elasticity of demand an individual firm faces becomes a key determinant of a seller’s ability to extract profits from its competitive advantage. Table 9.2 summarizes how the price elasticity of demand facing a firm influences the choice between two polar strategies for exploiting competitive advantage: a margin strategy and a share strategy.

Consider, first, a firm that has a cost advantage. When the firm’s product has a low price elasticity of demand (i.e., when consumers are not very price-sensitive because of strong horizontal differentiation among competitors’ products), even deep price cuts will not increase the firm’s market share much. In this case, the optimal way for a firm to exploit its cost advantage is through a margin strategy: the firm maintains price parity with its competitors and profits from its cost advantage primarily through high price–cost margins rather than through higher market shares. By contrast, when the firm’s product has a high price elasticity of demand (i.e., when consumers are price sensitive because horizontal differentiation is weak), modest price cuts can lead to significant increases in market share. In this case, the firm should exploit its cost advantage through a share strategy: the firm underprices its competitors to gain market share at their expense. In practice, the distinction between a margin strategy and a share strategy is one of degree and firms with cost advantages will often pursue mixed strategies: cutting price to gain share but also “banking” some of the cost advantage through higher margins.

Table 9.2 illustrates the notion that the logic governing the exploitation of a benefit advantage is analogous to that governing the exploitation of a cost advantage.

314 Chapter 9 Strategic Positioning for Competitive Advantage

TABLE 9.2

Exploiting a Competitive Advantage through Pricing

 

 

 

Type of Advantage

 

 

Cost Advantage

Benefit Advantage

 

 

(lower C than competitors)

(higher B than competitors)

 

 

 

 

 

High price

• Modest price cuts gain lots

• Modest price hikes lose lots

 

elasticity of

 

of market share.

of market share.

 

demand (weak

• Exploit advantage through

• Exploit advantage through

 

horizontal

 

higher market share than

higher market share than

 

differentiation)

 

competitors.

competitors.

 

 

Share strategy: Underprice

Share strategy: Maintain

 

 

 

competitors to gain share.

price parity with competitors

Firm’s Price

 

 

 

(let benefit advantage drive

 

 

 

share increases).

Elasticity of

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Demand

Low price

Big price cuts gain little

• Big price hikes lose little

 

elasticity of

 

share.

share.

 

demand

• Exploit advantage through

• Exploit advantage through

 

(strong horizontal

 

higher profit margins.

higher profit margins.

 

differentiation)

Margin strategy: Maintain

Margin strategy: Charge

 

 

 

price parity with

price premium relative to

 

 

 

competitors (let lower costs

competitors.

 

 

 

drive higher margins).

 

 

 

 

 

 

When a firm has a benefit advantage in a market in which consumers are price sensitive, even a modest price hike could offset the firm’s benefit advantage and nullify the increase in market share that the benefit advantage would otherwise lead to. In this case, the best way for the firm to exploit its benefit advantage is through a share strategy. A share strategy involves charging the same price as competitors and exploiting the firm’s benefit advantage by capturing a higher market share than competitors. By contrast, when consumers are not price sensitive, large price hikes will not completely erode the market share gains that the firm’s benefit advantage creates. The best way for the firm to exploit its benefit advantage is through a margin strategy: it charges a price premium relative to competitors (sacrificing some market share in the process), and it exploits its advantage mainly through higher profit margins.

The prospect of competitor reactions can alter the broad recommendations in Table 9.2. For instance, in markets with price-sensitive consumers, a share strategy of cutting price to exploit a cost advantage would be attractive if competitors’ prices remained unchanged. However, it would probably be unattractive if the firm’s competitors quickly matched the price cut because the net result will be lower margins with little or no net gain in the firm’s market share. In this case, a margin strategy might well be a more attractive option.

Comparing Cost and Benefit Advantages

Under what circumstances is one source of advantage likely to be more profitable than the other? Though no definitive rules can be formulated, the underlying economics of the firm’s product market and the current positions of firms in the industry

Strategic Positioning: Cost Advantage and Benefit Advantage 315

can sometimes create conditions that are more hospitable to one kind of advantage versus another.

An advantage based on lower cost is likely to be more profitable than an advantage built on superior benefits when:

The nature of the product limits opportunities for enhancing its perceived benefit B. This might be the case for commodity products, such as chemicals and paper. If so, then, more opportunities for creating additional value may come from lowering C rather than from increasing B. Still, we must bear in mind that the drivers of differentiation include far more than just the physical attributes of the product and that opportunities may exist for differentiation through better after-sale service, superior location, or more rapid delivery than competitors offer.

Consumers are relatively price sensitive and will not pay much of a premium for enhanced product quality, performance, or image. This would occur when most consumers are much more price sensitive than quality sensitive. Graphically, this corresponds to the case in which consumer indifference curves are relatively flat, indicating that a consumer will not pay much more for enhanced quality. Opportunities for additional value creation are much more likely to arise through cost reductions than through benefit enhancements.

The product is a search good. As detailed in Chapter 10, a search good is one whose objective quality attributes the typical buyer can assess prior to the point of purchase. Examples include commodity products as well as items such as stationery and office furniture. With search goods, the potential for differentiation lies largely in enhancing the product’s observable features. But if buyers can discern among different offerings, so can competitors, which raises the risk that the enhancements will be imitated.

An advantage based on superior benefits is likely to be relatively more profitable than an advantage based on cost efficiency when:

The typical consumer will pay a significant price premium for attributes that enhance B. This corresponds to the case in which the typical consumer’s indifference curve is relatively steep. A firm that can differentiate its product by offering even a few additional features may command a significant price premium.

Economies of scale or learning are significant, and firms are already exploiting them. In this case, opportunities for achieving a cost advantage over these larger firms are limited, and the best route toward value creation would be to offer a product that is especially well tailored to a particular niche of the market. Microbreweries, such as the Boston Beer Company, have attempted to build a competitive advantage in this way.

The product is an experience good. An experience good is a product whose quality can be assessed only after the consumer has purchased it and used it for a while. Examples include automobiles, appliances, and consumer packaged goods. As we discuss in Chapter 10, consumers often judge experience goods on the basis of a firm’s image, reputation, or credibility, which can be difficult for rivals to imitate or neutralize. In the early 2000s, Sony’s strong reputation in consumer electronics helped it become a dominant player in the widescreen television market despite the fact that its LCD technology was inferior to the DLP technology offered by Samsung, a Korean firm with a weaker reputation at that time.

Соседние файлы в предмете [НЕСОРТИРОВАННОЕ]