Добавил:
Upload Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:
Public-Administration-in-Southeast-Asia.pdf
Скачиваний:
188
Добавлен:
21.03.2016
Размер:
4.4 Mб
Скачать

Decentralization and Local Governance in the Philippines 369

18.3.2.3 Fiscal Decentralization Issues

18.3.2.3.1 Macroeconomic Stability

Former DBM Secretary Benjamin Diokno questioned the rationale and viability of the 40% mandated share of IRA from the internal revenues. He noted the important role of the national government in managing macroeconomic stability given the fiscal problems confronting the country. The 40% share had no functional or computational basis; rather, it was a result of political grandstanding in Congress, where both the former senate president and the Speaker of the House during the LGC deliberations, had the intention of running for the presidency in 1992 (Diokno 2003). Thus, there would have been political incentives for them should they receive the support of local governments.

Some economists believe that the arguments to increase the share of local government in the national budget and broaden the taxable items (including sharing of centrally collected taxes) may face the risk of leading the country into serious macroeconomic stability problems; perhaps there is a lack of recognition that the country suffers from serious fiscal restraints, e.g., budget deficit and the increasing debt service payments.

The central issue is the equitable redistribution of resources from richer to poorer local governments, which can only be done by central government through a good fiscal transfers system. Obviously, poor local governments have low tax bases, which by increasing their revenue powers will not necessarily make significant gains to raise their revenue compared to geographically rich ones.

18.3.2.3.2 Policy Design Issues of the Internal Revenue Allotment

Manasan’s (2007) policy notes on the IRA design issues and challenges10 categorized the criticisms on IRA into four major issues: (1) vertical imbalances, (2) lack of equalizing feature in the IRA,

(3) disincentive effects on local revenue generation, and (4) poor predictability of IRA. As a result, the current IRA design leads to the inadequacy of funds for LGU expenditure functions, i.e., the cost of devolved functions,11 creation of mandatory positions, unfunded mandates, and 20% DF. It widens the geographic disparities in human development outcomes and level of economic development. It tends to provide a substitutive effect for tax revenues of provinces and cities. And finally, the non-appropriation in full, i.e., 40%, or the untimely release of IRA (between 1998 and 2004), has undermined the effective planning of LGUs.

Observers of the implementation of the LGC have articulated apprehensions about the insufficiency of IRA for the devolved functions and the payment of salaries for devolved personnel; uncertainty of receiving their estimated IRA shares; problem of equality of sharing among levels of LGUs; and the responsiveness of the criteria (i.e., population, land area, and equal sharing) to the funding needs of poorer LGUs (Ilago 1997). The “IRA formula has bias for cities,” which paradoxically have higher revenue earning capacities to finance the delivery of services (Gatmaytan 2001). Evidence has also shown that the IRA formula has a counter-equalizing effect; the per

10This paper perhaps summarizes Manasan’s analyses on the IRA issue since she wrote, “Intergovernmental Fiscal Relations, Fiscal Federalism, and Economic Development in the Philippines” in 1992. PIDS policy notes are observations and analyses by PIDS researchers on certain policy issues to provide useful inputs for decision making.

11In an earlier study, Manasan argues that computation for the cost of devolved functions covered only the personnel and facilities transferred to LGUs, and the maintenance and operating expenses (MOOE); not the “true cost” of devolved functions.

©2011 by Taylor and Francis Group, LLC

370 Public Administration in Southeast Asia

capita income of LGUs is positively correlated with their IRA share from national government (Pardo 2005; Guevara 2004; Manasan 1992).

18.3.2.3.3Dependency of Local Government Units on Internal Revenue Allotment

Some argue that most LGUs are heavily dependent, while some are completely dependent on IRA. The IRA structure does not encourage LGUs to mobilize revenue, and serves as a substitute for local revenues. Hence, they fail to update their real property values and LGU revenue codes (Pardo 2006; Gatmaytan 2001). As a result, there is high IRA dependency among LGUs; they are unable to maximize their revenue potentials.

18.3.2.3.4 Disruptive Effect of the Creation of New Local Government Units

The changing number of LGUs continues to disrupt and cause irregular resource allocation of IRA among LGUs. There is a huge incentive for municipalities to attain city status, thereby increasing “equity share” to their IRA. This has been disruptive to the entire IRA package for LGUs. LGU classification is also another mismatching factor in the IRA (Brillantes and Tiu Sonco).

18.3.2.3.5 Disparate Planning, Unhealthy Competition, and Corruption

The extant number of sub-national governments in the Philippines does not promote economies of scale in both service delivery functions and local economic development. There is a tendency for local governments to compete on service areas, production, and utilization of meager resources, instead of maximizing mutual benefits. The revenue share of local governments from mining and exploitation of national wealth continues to be a gray area. Some believe that the authorization for extraction of resources by multinational companies has become a source of corruption by central and local government officials.

18.3.2.3.6Danger of Borrowing by Local Government Units with Inadequate Safety Nets

This opens up a threat to unsustainable debt trap at the local government level, and eventually might lead to distorting the macroeconomic stability and financial burden at the national level. Indeed, there are potential dangers of borrowing by LGUs, using the IRA as collateral, for unsound development projects. For instance, a province in the Visayas borrowed a few hundred million pesos for supposedly agricultural development projects. The project components include the procurement and distribution of fertilizers to farmers; and the purchase of a number of heavy equipment, which are intended for lease to contractors. There is a danger that the provincial government might not be able to pay the debt from expected and/projected revenues since the investments do not provide clear revenue generation potentials. This might further aggravate the LGU’s inability to provide social services once the debt becomes mature for repayment. The IRA it will receive from national government will be captured by the bank or the lending institution. There were also allegations that the distribution of fertilizers was based on political favors received by key local officials from the LCEs of the municipalities and individual farmers in the recent local and national elections (2005 and 2007) (Tiu Sonco 2008).

© 2011 by Taylor and Francis Group, LLC

Соседние файлы в предмете [НЕСОРТИРОВАННОЕ]