Добавил:
Upload Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:
OECD_Tax administration 2013-1.pdf
Скачиваний:
25
Добавлен:
02.04.2015
Размер:
4.64 Mб
Скачать

24 – 1. INSTITUTIONAL ARRANGEMENTS FOR TAX ADMINISTRATION

-structured primarily on a functional basis, and with a dedicated large taxpayer operation overseeing the largest taxpayers; and

-with a headquarters operation sufficiently resourced and empowered to carry out all strategic planning tasks, as well as provide guidance, technical advice, and direction and support to operational units.

There are clearly defined responsibilities and relationships at the national, regional and local levels.

There are flexible processes in place for resource allocation at all levels of the organisation.

More is said about the structural and organisational arrangements of revenue bodies covered by this series later in this chapter and, in particular, in Chapter 2.

The revenue body as an institution

There have been considerable changes in the organisation of public sector functions over the last decade. As noted in Kidd and Crandall (2006):

Restructuring of government has been a constant theme over the last three decades as Governments have sought to deliver services more effectively and at a lower cost to citizens.

A key part of the reforms made has centered on organisational autonomy. As noted in Crandall (2010):

[…] there has been a tendency for governments to increase the autonomy of its departments and agencies. The basic principle is that such autonomy can lead to better performance by removing impediments to effective and efficient management while maintaining appropriate accountability and transparency.

Autonomy can mean many things, including independence or even self-government, but in the context of public sector administration it usually refers to … the degree to which a government department or agency is able to operate independently from government, in terms of legal form and status, funding and budget, and financial, human resources and administrative practices […].

While the trend toward increased autonomy is clearly a general one for governments, revenue administration has been very much at the forefront of this movement. Many believe there is a compelling case for increased autonomy for revenue administration because it is the source of revenue for the whole of government. It is recognised that the problems addressed by increased autonomy affect the entire government but, it is argued, such problems are felt much more acutely in revenue administration as compared to most other public sector activities, largely on account of the specialised skills needed and because of its revenue-producing role. This “uniqueness” argument may not be as strong as its proponents believe, especially in the context of world-wide public service reform and good governance initiatives.

Activity to reform revenue administration by revamping institutional arrangements and increasing revenue body autonomy has been uneven across countries covered by the CIS. As a result, there is in 2012 a fairly divergent set of institutional set ups in place. For the purposes of this series, four broad categories of institutional setups for conducting tax

TAX ADMINISTRATION 2013: COMPARATIVE INFORMATION ON OECD AND OTHER ADVANCED AND EMERGING ECONOMIES – © OECD 2013

1. INSTITUTIONAL ARRANGEMENTS FOR TAX ADMINISTRATION – 25

administration have been identified, although in practice there are a number of exceptions.2 These are:

A single directorate in ministry of finance (MOF): Tax administration functions are the responsibility of a single organisational unit (e.g. a directorate) located within the structure of the ministry of finance (or its equivalent).

Multiple directorates in MOF: Tax administration functions are the responsibility of multiple organisational units (e.g. directorates) located within the ministry of finance (often sharing necessary support functions such as information technology and human resources);

Unified semi-autonomous body: Tax administration functions, along with necessary support functions (e.g. information technology, human resources) are carried out by a unified semi-autonomous body, the head of which reports to a government minister.

Unified semi-autonomous body with board: Tax administration functions, along with necessary support functions (e.g. information technology, human resources) are carried out by a unified semi-autonomous body, the head of which reports to a government minister and oversight body/board of management comprised of external officials.

As indicated in Table 1.1, 31 of 52 surveyed countries have established a unified semi-autonomous body (or in the case of China a separate ministry) responsible for tax administration (and in some cases customs administration) operations, while the balance of countries operate with other (generally less unified and/or autonomous) models.3 To a large extent, these varied institutional arrangements reflect underlying differences in the political structures and systems of public sector administration in surveyed countries, as well as longstanding historical practice. Key observations from the data provided are set out below:

All but five surveyed countries (i.e. India, Luxembourg, Malaysia, Malta 4 and Cyprus) have merged the administration of direct and indirect taxes within a single revenue collection body; where this approach is not followed, tax administration is carried out by a number of separate directorates/agencies, generally forming part of the internal structure of the Ministry of Finance.

In the 32 OECD member countries that have a separate regime of social security contributions (SSC), 19 countries have them collected by a separate social security agency (or multiple agencies),5 while the balance of countries have integrated the collection of these revenues with normal tax administration operations; in the 15 of 18 non-OECD countries that administer SSC integration is preferred and eight countries adopt this approach.

Thirty four countries have separate bodies for tax and customs administration; of these, 18 countries have allocated excise administration to the customs body, not the revenue body.

The national revenue body in the majority of European OECD member countries is also responsible for the collection of real property taxes (and in many, motor vehicle taxes), while in virtually all non-European OECD member countries these taxes are administered by the revenue bodies of sub-national governments.

TAX ADMINISTRATION 2013: COMPARATIVE INFORMATION ON OECD AND OTHER ADVANCED AND EMERGING ECONOMIES – © OECD 2013

26 – 1. INSTITUTIONAL ARRANGEMENTS FOR TAX ADMINISTRATION

Table 1.1. Institutional arrangements for tax administration

 

Nature of

 

Major tax types administered by the national revenue body/multiple directorates

Country

PIT

SSC

CIT

VAT

Excises

Real estate

Other taxes: Estate: E;

body *

Wealth: W; Motor vehicle: M

OECD countries

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Australia

USB

9

n.app.

9

9

9

x

-

Austria

SDMOF

9

x

9

9

9

x

M

Belgium

MDMOF/1

9

x

9

9

9

x

M/1

Canada

USBB

9/1

9/2

9/1

9/1

9

x

/ 2

Chile

USB/1

9

x/2

9

9

9

9

E -/3

Czech Rep.

USB

9

x

9

9

x

9

E, M

Denmark

USB/1

9

x

9

9

9

9

 

Estonia

SDMOF

9

9

9

9

9

9

M/2

Finland

USB

9

9

9

9

x/1

9

E

France

SDMOF

9

x

9

9

x

9

E, W, M

Germany

Other/1

9

x

9

9

x

9/2

 

Greece

MDMOF

9

x/1

9

9

9

9

E, W, M

Hungary

USB

9

9

9

9

9

x

E, M

Iceland

USB

9

9

9

9

9

x

W, M

Ireland

USB

9

9

9

9

9

x

E, M

Israel

SDMOF

9

x

9

9

9

9

M

Italy

Other/1

9

x

9

9

x

x

-

Japan

USB

9

x

9

9

9

x

E, M

Korea

USB

9

x

9

9

9

9/1

E

Luxembourg

MDMOF/1

9

x

9

9

9

x

E, W

Mexico

USBB

9

x

9

9

9

x

 

Netherlands

SDMOF

9

9

9

9

9

x

E, M

New Zealand

USB

9

n.app.

9

9

x

x

-

Norway

USB

9

9

9

9

x

x

E, W

Poland

MDMOF/1

9

x

9

9

x

x

 

Portugal

SDMOF

9

x

9

9

9

9

E, M

Slovak Rep.

USB

9

x/1

9

9

x

x

M

Slovenia

USB

9

9

9

9

x

9

 

Spain

USB

9

x

9

9

9

x

 

Sweden

USBB/1

9

9

9

9

9

9

 

Switzerland

SDMOF/1

9

x

9

9

x

x

-

Turkey

Other/1

9

x

9

9

9

9

 

United Kingdom

USBB

9

9

9

9

9

9

E

United States

USBB

9

9

9

n.app.

9

x

E

Non-OECD countries

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Argentina

USBB/1

9

9

9

9

9

x

 

Brazil

USB/1

9

9

9

x/2

x

9

W

Bulgaria

USBB

9

9

9

9

x

x

 

China

Other/1

9

9/2

9

9

9

9

 

Colombia

USBB

9

x

9

9

x

x

E, W

Cyprus

MDMOF/1

9

x

9

9

9

9

-

Hong Kong, China

SDMOF

9

x

9

x

x

x

-

India

USB

9

x

9

x

x

x

W

Indonesia

SDMOF

9

x

9

9

x

9

-

Latvia

USB

9

9

9

9

9

9

M

Lithuania

USB

9

x

9

9

9

9

 

Malaysia

Other/1

9

x

9

x

x

9

-

Malta

MDMOF/1

9

9

9

9

9

x

-

Romania

USB

9

9

9

9

9

x

 

Russia

USB

9

x

9

9

9

9/1

M

Saudi Arabia

SDMOF

x/1

x

9

x

x

x

-

Singapore

USBB

9

x

9

9

x

9

E

South Africa

USBB

9

9/1

9

9

9

x

E

For notes indicated by “/ (number)”, see Notes to Tables section at the end of the chapter, p. 51.

*USB: Unified semi-autonomous body; USBB: Unified semi-autonomous body with formal board or advisory group comprised of external officials; SDMOF: Single directorate in Ministry of Finance; MDMOF: Multiple directorates in MOF.

Source: CIS survey responses & Secretariat research (e.g. revenue body reports).

TAX ADMINISTRATION 2013: COMPARATIVE INFORMATION ON OECD AND OTHER ADVANCED AND EMERGING ECONOMIES – © OECD 2013

1. INSTITUTIONAL ARRANGEMENTS FOR TAX ADMINISTRATION – 27

Based on research conducted for this series, management boards/advisory bodies comprised of external members have been established in 11 countries to oversee and/or provide advice on the operation of tax administration arrangements.

The practice of establishing a separate unified body for tax administration covering all taxes (and sometimes customs), removed from the formal internal structure of the MOF (or its equivalent) and with a broad range of autonomous powers mirrors a broader development in public sector administration sometimes described as the “executive agency” model. The model, in a revenue administration context often referred to as the “revenue authority model”, has been the subject of a fair amount of external scrutiny on behalf of various national and international organisations (Jenkins, 1994; Taliercio, 2004; Kidd and Cradall, 2006; Mann, 2004). The rationale for this model has been described in the following terms (Delay, Devas, and Hubbard, 1998):

The arguments for the executive agency model relate primarily to effectiveness and efficiency: 1) as a single purpose agency, it can focus its efforts on the single task; 2) as an autonomous organisation, it can manage its affairs in a businesslike way, free of political interference in day-to-day operations; and 3) freed from the constraints of the civil service system, it can recruit, retain (or dismiss) and motivate staff to a higher level of performance.

It is beyond the scope of this series to explore in detail the pros and cons of this development other than to emphasise a few key points drawn from the cited research:

Studies conducted to evaluate the success or otherwise of the “revenue authority” model for tax administration have not been able to draw any firm conclusions as to its overall impacts on revenue body efficiency and effectiveness.

As noted in a 2005 study report prepared by the UK Department for International Development (DFID), and in other reports, on experience with revenue authorities, there are a number of practical issues concerning the quantification of any benefits resulting from the introduction of the model. These include: 1) measurement: the difficulty inherent in gauging the impacts, in quantitative terms, of a concept such as autonomy; 2) data: limitations with obtaining relevant data items on preand post-implementation basis; and 3) attribution/causality: the existence of exogenous factors that make it very difficult to establish causality and thus to attribute any observed benefits to specific initiatives (including the model itself).

Effective implementation of the model requires various types of support (e.g. good relationships with the MOF, strong leadership by senior management, and human resource policies for achieving good performance and addressing poor performance).

As noted in the IMF working paper, improved effectiveness and efficiency is likely to flow most directly from an ongoing commitment to the reform of structures, systems and processes, in particular, well designed programs of service and enforcement, the sound allocation of resources, and effective management. Implementation of a new governance structure is, at best, a first step in this direction.

Many countries that have applied the model see it as a catalyst for reform. As noted in Kidd and Crandall (2006):

Notwithstanding the lack of demonstrated basis for establishing a revenue authority, there is a strong perception held by those countries that have adopted the revenue authority concept that this particular governance model has made a significant contribution to reform and improved performance.

TAX ADMINISTRATION 2013: COMPARATIVE INFORMATION ON OECD AND OTHER ADVANCED AND EMERGING ECONOMIES – © OECD 2013

Соседние файлы в предмете [НЕСОРТИРОВАННОЕ]