Добавил:
Upload Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:

economics_of_money_banking__financial_markets

.pdf
Скачиваний:
143
Добавлен:
10.06.2015
Размер:
27.11 Mб
Скачать

C h a p t e r

20 The International Financial System

PREVIEW

Thanks to the growing interdependence between the U.S. economy and the economies of the rest of the world, a countryÕs monetary policy can no longer be conducted without taking international considerations into account. In this chapter, we examine how international financial transactions and the structure of the international financial system affect monetary policy. We also examine the evolution of the international financial system during the past half century and consider where it may be heading in the future.

Intervention in the Foreign Exchange Market

Foreign Exchange

Intervention and

the Money Supply

In Chapter 19, we analyzed the foreign exchange market as if it were a completely free market that responds to all market pressures. Like many other markets, however, the foreign exchange market is not free of government intervention; central banks regularly engage in international financial transactions called foreign exchange interventions in order to influence exchange rates. In our current international financial arrangement, called a managed float regime (or a dirty float), exchange rates fluctuate from day to day, but central banks attempt to influence their countriesÕ exchange rates by buying and selling currencies. The exchange rate analysis we developed in Chapter 19 is used here to explain the impact that central bank intervention has on the foreign exchange market.

The first step in understanding how central bank intervention in the foreign exchange market affects exchange rates is to see the impact on the monetary base from a central bank sale in the foreign exchange market of some of its holdings of assets denominated in a foreign currency (called international reserves). Suppose that the Fed decides to sell $1 billion of its foreign assets in exchange for $1 billion of U.S. currency. (This transaction is conducted at the foreign exchange desk at the Federal Reserve Bank of New YorkÑsee Box 1.) The FedÕs purchase of dollars has two effects. First, it reduces the FedÕs holding of international reserves by $1 billion. Second, because its purchase of currency removes it from the hands of the public, currency in

462

C H A P T E R 2 0 The International Financial System 463

Box 1: Inside the Fed

A Day at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Foreign Exchange Desk

Although the U.S. Treasury is primarily responsible

Although by statute the Treasury has the lead role in

for foreign exchange policy, decisions to intervene in

setting foreign exchange policy, it strives to reach a

the foreign exchange market are made jointly by the

consensus among all three partiesÑthe Treasury, the

U.S. Treasury and the Federal Reserve as represented

Board of Governors, and the Federal Reserve Bank of

by the FOMC (Federal Open Market Committee).

New York. If they decide that a foreign exchange

The actual conduct of foreign exchange intervention

intervention is necessary that dayÑan unusual

is the responsibility of the foreign exchange desk at

occurrence, as a year may go by without a U.S. for-

the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, which is right

eign exchange interventionÑthe manager instructs

next to the open market desk.

his traders to carry out the agreed-on purchase or

The manager of foreign exchange operations at the

sale of foreign currencies. Because funds for exchange

New York Fed supervises the traders and analysts

rate intervention are held separately by the Treasury

who follow developments in the foreign exchange

(in its Exchange Stabilization Fund) and the Federal

market. Every morning at 7:30, a trader on his staff

Reserve, the manager and his staff are not trading the

who has arrived at the New York Fed in the predawn

funds of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York;

hours speaks on the telephone with counterparts at

rather they act as an agent for the Treasury and the

the U.S. Treasury and provides an update on

FOMC in conducting these transactions.

overnight activity in overseas financial and foreign

As part of their duties, before every FOMC meet-

exchange markets. Later in the morning, at 9:30, the

ing, the staff help prepare a lengthy document full of

manager and his staff hold a conference call with sen-

data for the FOMC members, other Reserve bank

ior staff at the Board of Governors of the Federal

presidents, and Treasury officials. It describes devel-

Reserve in Washington. In the afternoon, at 2:30,

opments in the domestic and foreign markets over

they have a second conference call, which is a joint

the previous five or six weeks, a task that keeps them

briefing of officials at the board and the Treasury.

especially busy right before the FOMC meeting.

circulation falls by $1 billion. We can see this in the following T-account for the Federal Reserve:

FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM

Assets

 

 

Liabilities

Foreign assets (inter-

 

Currency in

 

national reserves)

$1 billion

circulation

$1 billion

Because the monetary base is made up of currency in circulation plus reserves, this decline in currency implies that the monetary base has fallen by $1 billion.

If instead of paying for the foreign assets sold by the Fed with currency, the persons buying the foreign assets pay for them by checks written on accounts at domestic banks,

464 P A R T V

International Finance and Monetary Policy

then the Fed deducts the $1 billion from the deposit accounts these banks have with the Fed. The result is that deposits with the Fed (reserves) decline by $1 billion, as shown in the following T-account:

FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM

Assets

 

Liabilities

 

Foreign assets (inter-

 

Deposits with

 

national reserves)

$1 billion

the Fed (reserves)

$1 billion

In this case, the outcome of the Fed sale of foreign assets and the purchase of dollar deposits is a $1 billion decline in reserves and a $1 billion decline in the monetary base because reserves are also a component of the monetary base.

We now see that the outcome for the monetary base is exactly the same when a central bank sells foreign assets to purchase domestic bank deposits or domestic currency. This is why when we say that a central bank has purchased its domestic currency, we do not have to distinguish whether it actually purchased currency or bank deposits denominated in the domestic currency. We have thus reached an important conclusion: A central bankÕs purchase of domestic currency and corresponding sale of foreign assets in the foreign exchange market leads to an equal decline in its international reserves and the monetary base.

We could have reached the same conclusion by a more direct route. A central bank sale of a foreign asset is no different from an open market sale of a government bond. We learned in our exploration of the money supply process that an open market sale leads to an equal decline in the monetary base; therefore, a sale of foreign assets also leads to an equal decline in the monetary base. By similar reasoning, a central bank purchase of foreign assets paid for by selling domestic currency, like an open market purchase, leads to an equal rise in the monetary base. Thus we reach the following conclusion: A central bankÕs sale of domestic currency to purchase foreign assets in the foreign exchange market results in an equal rise in its international reserves and the monetary base.

The intervention we have just described, in which a central bank allows the purchase or sale of domestic currency to have an effect on the monetary base, is called an unsterilized foreign exchange intervention. But what if the central bank does not want the purchase or sale of domestic currency to affect the monetary base? All it has to do is to counter the effect of the foreign exchange intervention by conducting an offsetting open market operation in the government bond market. For example, in the case of a $1 billion purchase of dollars by the Fed and a corresponding $1 billion sale of foreign assets, which, as we have seen, would decrease the monetary base by $1 billion, the Fed can conduct an open market purchase of $1 billion of government bonds, which would increase the monetary base by $1 billion. The resulting T-account for the foreign exchange intervention and the offsetting open market operation leaves the monetary base unchanged:

Unsterilized

Intervention

 

C H A P T E R 2 0

The International Financial System

465

 

FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM

 

Assets

 

Liabilities

 

Foreign assets (inter-

 

Monetary base

 

national reserves)

$1 billion

(reserves)

0

Government bonds

$1 billion

 

 

A foreign exchange intervention with an offsetting open market operation that leaves the monetary base unchanged is called a sterilized foreign exchange intervention.

Now that we understand that there are two types of foreign exchange interventionsÑ unsterilized and sterilizedÑletÕs look at how each affects the exchange rate.

Your intuition might lead you to suspect that if a central bank wants to lower the value of the domestic currency, it should sell its currency in the foreign exchange market and purchase foreign assets. Indeed, this intuition is correct for the case of an unsterilized intervention.

Recall that in an unsterilized intervention, if the Federal Reserve decides to sell dollars in order to buy foreign assets in the foreign exchange market, this works just like an open market purchase of bonds to increase the monetary base. Hence the sale of dollars leads to an increase in the money supply, and we find ourselves analyzing exactly the situation already described in Figure 7 of Chapter 19, which is reproduced here as Figure 1. The higher money supply leads to a higher U.S. price level in the long run and so to a lower expected future exchange rate. The resulting decline in the expected appreciation of the dollar increases the expected return on foreign deposits and shifts the RF schedule to the right. In addition, the increase in the money supply will lead to a higher real money supply in the short run, which causes the interest rate on dollar deposits to fall. The resulting lower expected return on dollar deposits translates as a leftward shift in the RD schedule. The fall in the expected return on dollar deposits and the increase in the expected return on foreign deposits means that foreign assets have a higher expected return than dollar deposits at the old equilibrium exchange rate. Hence people will try to sell their dollar deposits, and the exchange rate will fall. Indeed, as we saw in the previous chapter, the increase in the money supply will lead to exchange rate overshooting, whereby the exchange rate falls by more in the short run than it does in the long run.

Our analysis leads us to the following conclusion about unsterilized interventions in the foreign exchange market: An unsterilized intervention in which domestic currency is sold to purchase foreign assets leads to a gain in international reserves, an increase in the money supply, and a depreciation of the domestic currency.

The reverse result is found for an unsterilized intervention in which domestic currency is purchased by selling foreign assets. The purchase of domestic currency by selling foreign assets (reducing international reserves) works like an open market sale to reduce the monetary base and the money supply. The decrease in the money supply raises the interest rate on dollar deposits and shifts RD rightward, while causing

466 P A R T V

International Finance and Monetary Policy

F I G U R E 1 Effect of a Sale of

Dollars and a Purchase of Foreign

Assets

A sale of dollars and the consequent open market purchase of foreign assets increase the monetary base. The resulting rise in the money supply leads to a higher domestic price level in the long run, which leads to a lower expected future exchange rate. The resulting decline in the expected appreciation of the dollar raises the expected return on foreign deposits, shifting the RF schedule rightward from R1F to RF2. In the short run, the domestic interest rate i D falls, shifting RD from RD1 to RD2. The short-run outcome is that the exchange rate falls from E1 to E2. In the long run, however, the interest rate returns to i D1, and RD returns to RD1. The exchange rate therefore rises from E2 to E3 in the long run.

Exchange Rate, Et

RD2

RD1

 

 

(euros/$)

 

 

RF

RF

 

 

 

 

 

 

1

2

E1

 

1

 

 

E3

 

3

 

 

E2

 

2

 

 

 

i D

i D

Expected Return

 

2

1

(in $ terms)

 

 

 

Sterilized

Intervention

RF to shift leftward, because it leads to a lower U.S. price level in the long run and thus to a higher expected appreciation of the dollar, and hence a lower expected return on foreign deposits. The increase in the expected return on dollar deposits relative to foreign deposits will mean that people will want to buy more dollar deposits, and the exchange rate will rise. An unsterilized intervention in which domestic currency is purchased by selling foreign assets leads to a drop in international reserves, a decrease in the money supply, and an appreciation of the domestic currency.

The key point to remember about a sterilized intervention is that the central bank engages in offsetting open market operations, so that there is no impact on the monetary base and the money supply. In the context of the model of exchange rate determination we have developed here, it is straightforward to show that a sterilized intervention has no effect on the exchange rate. Remember that in our model, foreign and domestic deposits are perfect substitutes, so equilibrium in the foreign exchange market occurs when the expected returns on foreign and domestic deposits are equal. A sterilized intervention leaves the money supply unchanged and so has no way of directly affecting interest rates or the expected future exchange rate.1 Because the

1Note that a sterilized intervention could indicate what central banks want to happen to the future exchange rate and so might provide a signal about the course of future monetary policy. In this way, a sterilized intervention could lead to shifts in the RF schedule, but in reality it is the future change in monetary policy, not the sterilized intervention, that is the ultimate source of exchange rate effects. For a discussion of the signaling effect, see Maurice Obstfeld, ÒThe Effectiveness of Foreign Exchange Intervention: Recent Experience, 1985Ð1988,Ó in

International Policy Coordination and Exchange Rate Fluctuations, ed. William H. Branson, Jacob A. Frenkel, and Morris Goldstein (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1990), pp. 197Ð237.

C H A P T E R 2 0 The International Financial System 467

expected returns on dollar and foreign deposits are unaffected, the expected return schedules remain at RD1 and RF1 in Figure 1, and the exchange rate remains unchanged

at E1.

At first it might seem puzzling that a central bank purchase or sale of domestic currency that is sterilized does not lead to a change in the exchange rate. A central bank purchase of domestic currency cannot raise the exchange rate, because with no effect on the domestic money supply or interest rates, any resulting rise in the exchange rate would mean that the expected return on foreign deposits would be greater than the expected return on domestic deposits. Given our assumption that foreign and domestic deposits are perfect substitutes (equally desirable), this would mean that no one would want to hold domestic deposits.2 So the exchange rate would have to fall back to its previous level, where the expected returns on domestic and foreign deposits were equal.

Balance of Payments

http://research.stlouisfed.org /fred/data/exchange.html

This web site contains exchange rates, balance of payments, and trade data.

Because international financial transactions such as foreign exchange interventions have considerable effects on monetary policy, it is worth knowing how these transactions are measured. The balance of payments is a bookkeeping system for recording all receipts and payments that have a direct bearing on the movement of funds between a nation (private sector and government) and foreign countries.

Here we examine the key items in the balance of payments that you often hear about in the media.

The current account shows international transactions that involve currently produced goods and services. The difference between merchandise exports and imports, the net receipts from trade, is called the trade balance. When merchandise imports are greater than exports (by $427 billion), we have a trade deficit; if exports are greater than imports, we have a trade surplus.

Three additional items included in the current account are the net receipts that arise from investment income, the purchase and sale of services, and unilateral transfers (gifts, pensions, and foreign aid). In 2001, for example, net investment income was negative $19 billion for the United States because Americans received less investment income from abroad than they paid out. Americans bought less in services from foreigners than foreigners bought from Americans, so net services generated $79 billion in receipts. Since Americans made more unilateral transfers to foreign countries (especially foreign aid) than foreigners made to the United States, net unilateral transfers were negative $50 billion. The sum of the previous three items plus the trade balance is the current account balance, which in 2001 showed a deficit of $417 billion ( $427 $19 $79 $50 $417 billion).

Another important item in the balance of payments is the capital account, the net receipts from capital transactions. In 2001 the capital account was $416 billion,

2If domestic and foreign deposits are not perfect substitutes, a sterilized intervention can affect the exchange rate. However, most studies find little evidence to support the position that sterilized intervention has a significant impact on foreign exchange rates. For a further discussion of the effects of sterilized versus unsterilized intervention, see Paul Krugman and Maurice Obstfeld, International Economics, 5th ed. (Reading, Mass.: Addison Wesley Longman, 2000).

468 P A R T V

International Finance and Monetary Policy

indicating that $416 billion more capital came into the United States than went out. Another way of saying this is that the United States had a net capital inflow of $416 billion.3 The sum of the current account and the capital account equals the official reserve transactions balance, which was negative $1 billion in 2001 ( $417 $416 $1 billion). When economists refer to a surplus or deficit in the balance of payments, they actually mean a surplus or deficit in the official reserve transactions balance.

Because the balance of payments must balance, the official reserve transactions balance, which equals the current account plus the capital account, tells us the net amount of international reserves that must move between governments (as represented by their central banks) to finance international transactions: i.e.,

Current account capital account

net change in government international reserves

This equation shows us why the current account receives so much attention from economists and the media. The current account balance tells us whether the United States (private sector and government combined) is increasing or decreasing its claims on foreign wealth. A surplus indicates that America is increasing its claims on foreign wealth, and a deficit, as in 2001, indicates that the country is reducing its claims on foreign wealth.4

Financial analysts follow the current account balance closely because they believe that it can provide information on the future movement of exchange rates. The current account balance provides some indication of what is happening to the demand for imports and exports, which, as we saw in the previous chapter, can affect the exchange rate. In addition, the current account balance provides information about what will be happening to U.S. claims on foreign wealth in the long run. Because a movement of foreign wealth to American residents can affect the demand for dollar assets, changes in U.S. claims on foreign wealth, reflected in the current account balance, can affect the exchange rate over time.5

Evolution of the International Financial System

Before examining the impact of international financial transactions on monetary policy, we need to understand the past and current structure of the international financial system.

3Note that the capital account balance number reported above includes a statistical discrepancy item that represents errors due to unrecorded transactions involving smuggling and other capital flows ( $39 billion in 2001). Many experts believe that the statistical discrepancy item, which keeps the balance of payments in balance, is primarily the result of large hidden capital flows, and this is why it is included in the capital account balance reported above.

4The current account balance can also be viewed as showing the amount by which total saving exceeds private sector and government investment in the United States. We can see this by noting that total U.S. saving equals the increase in total wealth held by the U.S. private sector and government. Total investment equals the increase in the U.S. capital stock (wealth physically in the United States). The difference between them is the increase in U.S. claims on foreign wealth.

5If American residents have a greater preference for dollar assets than foreigners do, a movement of foreign wealth to American residents when there is a balance-of-payments surplus will increase the demand for dollar assets over time and will cause the dollar to appreciate.

Gold Standard

Bretton Woods

System

C H A P T E R 2 0 The International Financial System 469

Before World War I, the world economy operated under the gold standard, meaning that the currency of most countries was convertible directly into gold. American dollar bills, for example, could be turned in to the U.S. Treasury and exchanged for approximately 201 ounce of gold. Likewise, the British Treasury would exchange 14 ounce of gold for £1 sterling. Because an American could convert $20 into 1 ounce of gold, which could be used to buy £4, the exchange rate between the pound and the dollar was effectively fixed at $5 to the pound. Tying currencies to gold resulted in an international financial system with fixed exchange rates between currencies. The fixed exchange rates under the gold standard had the important advantage of encouraging world trade by eliminating the uncertainty that occurs when exchange rates fluctuate.

To see how the gold standard operated in practice, let us see what occurs if, under the gold standard, the British pound begins to appreciate above the $5 par value. If an American importer of £100 of English tweed tries to pay for the tweed with dollars, it costs more than the $500 it cost before. Nevertheless, the importer has another option involving the purchase of gold that can reduce the cost of the tweed. Instead of using dollars to pay for the tweed, the American importer can exchange the $500 for gold, ship the gold to Britain, and convert it into £100. The shipment of gold to Britain is cheaper as long as the British pound is above the $5 par value (plus a small amount to pay for the cost of shipping the gold).

Under the gold standard, the appreciation of the pound leads to a British gain of international reserves (gold) and an equal U.S. loss. Because a change in a countryÕs holdings of international reserves (gold) leads to an equal change in its monetary base, the movement of gold from the United States to Britain causes the British monetary base to rise and the American monetary base to fall. The resulting rise in the British money supply raises the British price level, while the fall in the U.S. money supply lowers the U.S. price level. The resulting increase in the British price level relative to the United States then causes the pound to depreciate. This process will continue until the value of the pound falls back down to its $5 par value.

A depreciation of the pound below the $5 par value, on the contrary, stimulates gold shipments from Britain to the United States. These shipments raise the American money supply and lower the British money supply, causing the pound to appreciate back toward the $5 par value. We thus see that under the gold standard, a rise or fall in the exchange rate sets in motion forces that return it to the par value.

As long as countries abided by the rules under the gold standard and kept their currencies backed by and convertible into gold, exchange rates remained fixed. However, adherence to the gold standard meant that a country had no control over its monetary policy, because its money supply was determined by gold flows between countries. Furthermore, monetary policy throughout the world was greatly influenced by the production of gold and gold discoveries. When gold production was low in the 1870s and 1880s, the money supply throughout the world grew slowly and did not keep pace with the growth of the world economy. The result was deflation (falling price levels). Gold discoveries in Alaska and South Africa in the 1890s then greatly expanded gold production, causing money supplies to increase rapidly and price levels to rise (inflation) until World War I.

World War I caused massive trade disruptions. Countries could no longer convert their currencies into gold, and the gold standard collapsed. Despite attempts to revive it in the interwar period, the worldwide depression, beginning in 1929, led to its permanent

470 P A R T V

International Finance and Monetary Policy

demise. As the Allied victory in World War II was becoming certain in 1944, the Allies met in Bretton Woods, New Hampshire, to develop a new international monetary system to promote world trade and prosperity after the war. In the agreement worked out among the Allies, central banks bought and sold their own currencies to keep their exchange rates fixed at a certain level (called a fixed exchange rate regime). The agreement lasted from 1945 to 1971 and was known as the Bretton Woods system.

The Bretton Woods agreement created the International Monetary Fund (IMF), headquartered in Washington, D.C., which had 30 original member countries in 1945 and currently has over 180. The IMF was given the task of promoting the growth of world trade by setting rules for the maintenance of fixed exchange rates and by making loans to countries that were experiencing balance-of-payments difficulties. As part of its role of monitoring the compliance of member countries with its rules, the IMF also took on the job of collecting and standardizing international economic data.

The Bretton Woods agreement also set up the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, commonly referred to as the World Bank, also headquartered in Washington, D.C., which provides long-term loans to help developing countries build dams, roads, and other physical capital that would contribute to their economic development. The funds for these loans are obtained primarily by issuing World Bank bonds, which are sold in the capital markets of the developed countries.6

Because the United States emerged from World War II as the worldÕs largest economic power, with over half of the worldÕs manufacturing capacity and the greater part of the worldÕs gold, the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates was based on the convertibility of U.S. dollars into gold (for foreign governments and central banks only) at $35 per ounce. The fixed exchange rates were to be maintained by intervention in the foreign exchange market by central banks in countries besides the United States who bought and sold dollar assets, which they held as international reserves. The U.S. dollar, which was used by other countries to denominate the assets that they held as international reserves, was called the reserve currency. Thus an important feature of the Bretton Woods system was the establishment of the United States as the reserve currency country. Even after the breakup of the Bretton Woods system, the U.S. dollar has kept its position as the reserve currency in which most international financial transactions are conducted. However, with the creation of the euro in 1999, the supremacy of the U.S. dollar may be subject to a serious challenge (see Box 2).

How a Fixed Exchange Rate Regime Works. The most important feature of the Bretton Woods system was that it set up a fixed exchange rate regime. Figure 2 shows how a fixed exchange rate regime works in practice using the model of exchange rate determination we learned in the previous chapter. Panel (a) describes a situation in which the domestic currency is initially overvalued: The schedule for the expected return on foreign deposits RF1 intersects the schedule for the expected return on domestic deposits RD1 at exchange rate E 1, which is lower than the par (fixed) value of the exchange rate Epar. To keep the exchange rate at Epar, the central bank must intervene in the foreign exchange market to purchase domestic currency by selling foreign assets, and this action, like an open market sale, means that the monetary base and

6In 1960, the World Bank established an affiliate, the International Development Association (IDA), which provides particularly attractive loans to third-world countries (with 50-year maturities and zero interest rates, for example). Funds for these loans are obtained by direct contributions of member countries.

C H A P T E R 2 0 The International Financial System 471

Box 2: Global

The Euro’s Challenge to the Dollar

With the creation of the European Monetary System

GDP (around 20%) and world exports (around 15%).

and the euro in 1999, the U.S. dollar may face a chal-

If the European Central Bank can make sure that

lenge to its position as the key reserve currency in

inflation remains low so that the euro becomes a

international financial transactions. Adoption of the

sound currency, this should bode well for the euro.

euro increases integration of EuropeÕs financial mar-

However, for the euro to eat into the dollarÕs posi-

kets, which could help them rival those in the United

tion as a reserve currency, the European Union must

States. The resulting increase in the use of euros in

function as a cohesive political entity that is able to

financial markets will make it more likely that inter-

exert its influence on the world stage. There are seri-

national transactions are carried out in the euro. The

ous doubts on this score, and most analysts think it

economic clout of the European Union rivals that of

will be a long time before the euro beats out the dol-

the United States: Both have a similar share of world

lar in international financial transactions.

Exchange rate, Et (foreign currency/ domestic currency)

Epar

E1

 

R2

RD

 

1

RF

 

 

1

 

2

1

 

i D

i D

1

2

Expected Return ( in domestic currency terms )

Exchange rate, Et

RD2

 

( foreign currency/

 

RD

domestic currency )

 

 

1

 

 

RF

 

 

1

E1

 

1

Epar

2

 

 

 

 

i D

i D

 

2

1

Expected Return ( in domestic currency terms )

(a)Intervention in the case of an overvalued exchange rate

( b ) Intervention in the case of an undervalued exchange rate

F I G U R E 2 Intervention in the Foreign Exchange Market Under a Fixed Exchange Rate Regime

In panel (a), the exchange rate at Epar is overvalued. To keep the exchange rate at Epar (point 2), the central bank must purchase domestic currency to shift the schedule for the expected return on domestic deposits to RD2 . In panel (b), the exchange rate at Epar is undervalued, so a central bank sale of domestic currency is needed to shift RD to RD2 to keep the exchange rate at Epar (point 2).

the money supply decline. Because the exchange rate will continue to be fixed at Epar, the expected future exchange rate remains unchanged, and so the schedule for the expected return on foreign deposits remains at RF1. However, the purchase of domestic

Соседние файлы в предмете [НЕСОРТИРОВАННОЕ]