Добавил:
Upload Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:
wd4_cost_en.pdf
Скачиваний:
3
Добавлен:
26.03.2016
Размер:
98.77 Кб
Скачать

For instance, under a “shadow tolling” model, users pay no fees. Instead, the public body (owner) pays “tolls” to the private partner (operator) for a given concession period. Using a consolidated financial analysis for the determination of the funding gap ensures that the “tolls” are not considered in this case, consistent with the provisions of Article 55(1). Indeed, the revenue for the operator corresponds to the cost borne by the owner, so that in the consolidated analysis the two cancel each other out and do not affect the project’s net cash flows.

5. CONCLUDING REMARKS

Member States are responsible for applying the provisions laid down in the regulations with regard to cost-benefit analysis and revenue generating projects. For ERDF and Cohesion Fund major projects, the Commission takes the decision and in it sets the contribution from the funds in the light of the information contained in the application and further appraisals if necessary.

In order to ensure consistency within a Member State, it is proposed that Member States develop their own guidance frameworks taking account of specific institutional settings, particularly for the transport and environment sectors. The Commission will continue to assist Member States in their task, with the aid of JASPERS, in order to ensure proper application of EU guidance to national contexts.

This approach will bring substantial benefits in terms of simplification both for the Commission and the Member States, and thereby contribute to speeding up decision procedures for large projects. It will also have an important capacity building effect with a view to the programming period 2007-13.

17

6.

GLOSSARY

 

 

 

Discounting:

the process of adjusting the future value of cost and benefits to the

 

 

present by a discount rate.

 

 

Discount rate:

the rate at which future values are discounted to the present.

 

 

Internal rate of

the discount rate at which a stream of costs and benefits has a net

return :

present value of zero. The internal rate of return is compared with

 

 

a benchmark in order to evaluate the performance of the proposed

 

 

project.

 

 

Investment cost:

capital cost incurred in the construction of the project.

 

 

Operating costs:

cost incurred in the operation of an investment, including cost of

 

 

routine and extraordinary maintenance but excluding depreciation

 

 

or capital costs.

 

 

 

Net

Present Value

the sum that results when the expected costs of the investment are

(NPV):

deducted from the discounted value of the expected benefits.

 

 

Project:

an operation comprising a series of works, activities or services

 

 

intended in itself to accomplish an indivisible task of a precise

 

 

economic or technical nature, which has clearly identified goals

 

 

Reference period:

the number of years for which forecasts are provided in the cost

 

 

benefit analysis.

 

 

Residual value:

the net present value of assets at the final year of the reference

 

 

period selected for evaluation analysis.

 

 

Revenue

any operation involving an investment in infrastructure, the use of

generating project:

which is subject to charges borne directly by users, and any

 

 

operation involving the sale or rent of land or buildings or the

 

 

provision of services against payment.

 

 

Revenues:

income to be expected from an investment through pricing or

 

 

charges.

 

 

 

18

7. REFERENCES

Commissariat général du Plan, Révision du taux d’actualisation des investissements publics, 2005. http://www.plan.gouv.fr/intranet/upload/actualite/Rapport%20Lebegue%20Taux%20actualisatio n%2024-01-05.pdf

European Commission, DG Regional Policy, Guide to cost-benefit analysis of investment projects, 2002. http://europa.eu.int/comm/regional_policy/sources/docgener/guides/cost/guide02_en.pdf

European Commission, DG Regional Policy, Guidelines for Successful Public–Private Partnerships, 2003. http://europa.eu.int/comm/regional_policy/sources/docgener/guides/ppp_en.pdf

European Commission, HEATCO - Developing Harmonised European Approaches for Transport Costing and Project Assessment, project funded under the 6th Framework Programme, coordinated by the University of Stuttgart, 2006. http://heatco.ier.uni-stuttgart.de/

European Investment Bank and European Commission, RAILPAG – Railway Project Appraisal Guidelines, 2005.

http://www.railpag.com

Fankhauser S. and Tepic S., Can poor consumers pay for energy and water? An affordability analysis for transition countries, EBRD Working Paper n. 92, 2005. http://www.ebrd.com/pubs/econo/wp0092.pdf

HM Treasury, Appraisal and evaluation in Central Government. The Green Book,

HMSO, London, 2003. http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/economic_data_and_tools/greenbook/data_greenbook_index.cfm

Pearce D., Atkinson G. and Mourato S., Cost Benefit Analysis and the Environment: Recent Developments. OECD / Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, 2005.

19

ANNEX I:

PUBLIC PRIVATE PARTNERSHIP (PPP)

PPPs can present a number of advantages if they will achieve demonstrable additional value compared to other approaches, if there is an effective implementation structure and if the objectives of all parties can be met within the partnership.

The Commission has identified four principal roles for the private sector in PPP schemes:

to provide additional capital;

to provide alternative management and implementation skills;

to provide value added to the consumer and the public at large;

to provide better identification of needs and optimal use of resources.

It must be remembered however, that PPP schemes are also complex to design, implement and manage. They are by no means the only or the preferred option.

The Guidelines for Successful Public–Private Partnerships (http://europa.eu.int/comm/regional_policy/sources/docgener/guides/ppp_en.pdf)

were designed as a practical tool for PPP practitioners in the public sector faced with the opportunity of structuring a PPP scheme and of integrating grant financing. They focus on four key topics:

ensuring open market access and fair competition;

protecting the public interest and maximising value added;

defining the optimal level of grant financing both to realize a viable and sustainable project, but also to avoid any opportunity for windfall profits from grants;

assessing the most effective type of PPP for a given project.

Types of PPP:

Traditional Public Service procurement – involves service contracting for well defined tasks with ownership of assets and management of financing remaining in the public hands.

BOT projects – the feature of this type of PPP is that, while ownership of assets and responsibility for funding management remains with a public body, the assets have a private operator who derives financial returns from their operation and hence (direct or indirect) charges on users.

Concession agreements – the public sector entrusts operation to a private party but the financing responsibility is shared and the private concessionaire brings equity participation. Asset ownership remains (ultimately) with the public sector.

20

ANNEX II:

EQUITY (AFFORDABILITY)

The tables below report current affordability ratios for the Central-Eastern Europe Cohesion Member States. Affordability ratios are provided for both average and bottom decile income household. It should be noted that these indicators refer to the actual current expenditure for given utility services which do not necessarily reflects the maximum potentially affordable tariffs’ level. These tables are provided for illustrative purpose only.

Table 1 - Current affordability of utility services, average household (% of total household expenditure)

 

Electricity

Heating

Water

Czech Republic

4.2

3.4

1.2

 

 

 

 

Estonia

3.2

5.4

1.0

 

 

 

 

Hungary

5.3

1.9

4.1

 

 

 

 

Latvia

2.2

3.2

0.8

 

 

 

 

Lithuania

2.8

3.7

1.1

 

 

 

 

Poland

4.5

2.7

2.0

 

 

 

 

Slovak Republic

3.5

7.9

1.3

 

 

 

 

Slovenia

4.5

1.2

1.3

 

 

 

 

Average affordability

3.8

3.7

1.6

 

 

 

 

Source: EBRD

 

 

 

Table 2 - Current affordability of utility services, bottom decile (% of total household expenditure)

 

Electricity

Heating

Water

Czech Republic

5.5

3.3

1.5

 

 

 

 

Estonia

8.2

15.4

2.4

 

 

 

 

Hungary

6.3

1.3

4.0

 

 

 

 

Latvia

2.2

2.8

0.9

 

 

 

 

Lithuania

3.1

0.7

0.7

Poland

5.7

1.2

1.8

 

 

 

 

Slovak Republic

11.4

18.6

4.3

 

 

 

 

Slovenia

9.4

1.9

2.6

Average affordability

6.5

5.7

2.3

 

 

 

 

Source: EBRD

 

 

 

21

ANNEX III:

DETERMINATION OF THE EU GRANT: A NUMERICAL EXAMPLE

Let us assume that the assistance of the Funds is requested for a major project under a priority axis for which the co-financing rate (CRpa) is 75%. A 5% discount rate in real terms is used for the financial analysis. The project has the following cash-flow profile:

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

M€ - 2007 constant prices

 

 

Year

Investment

Operatin

Revenue

Residua

 

Net

 

 

 

 

 

cash

 

 

costs

g costs

s

l value

 

 

 

 

 

flow

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

2007

25

-

-

 

-

-

25

 

 

2008

25

-

-

 

-

-

25

 

 

2009

25

-

-

 

-

-

25

 

 

2010

25

-

-

 

-

-

25

 

 

2011

-

2

4

 

-

 

2

 

 

2012

-

2

4

 

-

 

2

 

 

2013

-

2

4

 

-

 

2

 

 

2014

-

2

4

 

-

 

2

 

 

2015

-

2

4

 

-

 

2

 

 

2016

-

2

4

 

-

 

2

 

 

2017

-

2

4

 

-

 

2

 

 

2018

-

2

4

 

-

 

2

 

 

2019

-

2

4

 

-

 

2

 

 

2020

-

2

4

 

-

 

2

 

 

2021

-

2

4

 

-

 

2

 

 

2022

-

2

4

 

-

 

2

 

 

2023

-

2

4

 

-

 

2

 

 

2024

-

2

4

 

-

 

2

 

 

2025

-

2

4

 

-

 

2

 

 

2026

-

2

4

 

5

 

7

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Total

100

32

64

 

5

 

 

 

 

 

 

Total

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

(Discounted

89

18

36

 

2

-68,93

 

 

 

)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Discounted

 

Undiscounte

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

values

 

d values

Total investment cost

 

 

 

 

 

 

100

 

 

of which eligible cost (EC), say,

 

 

 

 

 

80

 

 

Discounted investment cost (DIC)

 

 

 

89

 

 

 

 

Discounted net revenue (DNR) = 36+2-18

 

 

20

 

 

 

 

22

Step 1) Find the funding-gap rate (R):

We first need to determine the “eligible expenditure” (EE) in accordance with Art. 55.2: EE = DIC-DNR

EE = 89 – 20 = 69

Then, the funding-gap rate (R) is found as: R = EE/DIC

R = 69/89 = 78%

Step 2) Find the “decision amount” (DA), i.e. “the amount to which the co-financing rate for the priority axis applies” (Art. 41.2):

DA = EC*R where

EC is the eligible cost DA = 80*78% = 62

Step 3) Find the (maximum) EU grant

EU grant = DA*CRpa where

CRpa is the maximum co-funding rate fixed for the priority axis in the Commission’s decision adopting the operational programme (Art. 53.6).

EU grant = 62*75% = 47

23

Соседние файлы в предмете [НЕСОРТИРОВАННОЕ]