Добавил:
Upload Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:

economics_of_money_banking__financial_markets

.pdf
Скачиваний:
143
Добавлен:
10.06.2015
Размер:
27.11 Mб
Скачать

Measuring Interest-Rate Risk: Duration 3

Table 1 Calculating Duration on a $1,000 Ten-Year 10% Coupon Bond When Its Interest Rate Is 10%

(1)

(2)

(3)

 

(4)

 

(5)

 

 

 

 

Present

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Cash Payments

 

Value (PV)

 

Weights

Weighted

 

(Zero-Coupon

of Cash Payments

(% of total

Maturity

 

Bonds)

 

(i 10%)

PV PV/$1,000)

(1 4)/100

Year

($)

($)

 

(%)

 

 

(years)

1

100

90.91

9.091

0.09091

2

100

82.64

8.264

0.16528

3

100

75.13

7.513

0.22539

4

100

68.30

6.830

0.27320

5

100

62.09

6.209

0.31045

6

100

56.44

5.644

0.33864

7

100

51.32

5.132

0.35924

8

100

46.65

4.665

0.37320

9

100

42.41

4.241

0.38169

10

100

38.55

3.855

0.38550

10

1,000

 

385.54

38.554

3.85500

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Total

 

 

1,000.00

100.000

6.75850

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

To get the effective maturity of the set of zero-coupon bonds, we add up the weighted maturities in column (5) and obtain the figure of 6.76 years. This figure for the effective maturity of the set of zero-coupon bonds is the duration of the 10% tenyear coupon bond because the bond is equivalent to this set of zero-coupon bonds. In short, we see that duration is a weighted average of the maturities of the cash payments.

The duration calculation done in Table 1 can be written as follows:

n

 

CPt

 

n

CPt

 

 

DUR t

 

 

 

 

(1)

(1

i )

t

(1 i )

t

t 1

 

t 1

 

 

where DUR duration

t years until cash payment is made

CPt cash payment (interest plus principal) at time t i interest rate

n years to maturity of the security

This formula is not as intuitive as the calculation done in Table 1, but it does have the advantage that it can easily be programmed into a calculator or computer, making duration calculations very easy.

If we calculate the duration for an 11-year 10% coupon bond when the interest rate is again 10%, we find that it equals 7.14 years, which is greater than the 6.76 years for the ten-year bond. Thus we have reached the expected conclusion: All else being equal, the longer the term to maturity of a bond, the longer its duration.

4 Appendix to Chapter 4

You might think that knowing the maturity of a coupon bond is enough to tell you what its duration is. However, that is not the case. To see this and to give you more practice in calculating duration, in Table 2 we again calculate the duration for the ten-year 10% coupon bond, but when the current interest rate is 20%, rather than 10% as in Table 1. The calculation in Table 2 reveals that the duration of the coupon bond at this higher interest rate has fallen from 6.76 years to 5.72 years. The explanation is fairly straightforward. When the interest rate is higher, the cash payments in the future are discounted more heavily and become less important in present-value terms relative to the total present value of all the payments. The relative weight for these cash payments drops as we see in Table 2, and so the effective maturity of the bond falls. We have come to an important conclusion: All else being equal, when interest rates rise, the duration of a coupon bond falls.

The duration of a coupon bond is also affected by its coupon rate. For example, consider a ten-year 20% coupon bond when the interest rate is 10%. Using the same procedure, we find that its duration at the higher 20% coupon rate is 5.98 years versus 6.76 years when the coupon rate is 10%. The explanation is that a higher coupon rate means that a relatively greater amount of the cash payments are made earlier in the life of the bond, and so the effective maturity of the bond must fall. We have thus established a third fact about duration: All else being equal, the higher the coupon rate on the bond, the shorter the bond’s duration.

Table 2 Calculating Duration on a $1,000 Ten-Year 10% Coupon Bond When Its Interest Rate Is 20%

(1)

(2)

(3)

 

(4)

 

(5)

 

 

 

 

Present

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Cash Payments

Value (PV)

 

Weights

Weighted

 

(Zero-Coupon

of Cash Payments

(% of total

Maturity

 

Bonds)

(i 20%)

PV PV/$580.76)

(1 4)/100

Year

($)

($)

 

(%)

 

 

(years)

1

100

83.33

14.348

0.14348

2

100

69.44

11.957

0.23914

3

100

57.87

9.965

0.29895

4

100

48.23

8.305

0.33220

5

100

40.19

6.920

0.34600

6

100

33.49

5.767

0.34602

7

100

27.91

4.806

0.33642

8

100

23.26

4.005

0.32040

9

100

19.38

3.337

0.30033

10

100

16.15

2.781

0.27810

10

$1,000

 

161.51

27.808

2.78100

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Total

 

 

580.76

100.000

5.72204

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Measuring Interest-Rate Risk: Duration 5

 

 

Study Guide

To make certain that you understand how to calculate duration, practice doing the

 

 

 

 

 

calculations in Tables 1 and 2. Try to produce the tables for calculating duration in

 

 

 

the case of an 11-year 10% coupon bond and also for the 10-year 20% coupon bond

 

 

 

mentioned in the text when the current interest rate is 10%. Make sure your calcula-

 

 

 

tions produce the same results found in this appendix.

 

 

 

One additional fact about duration makes this concept useful when applied to a

 

 

 

 

 

 

portfolio of securities. Our examples have shown that duration is equal to the

 

 

 

weighted average of the durations of the cash payments (the effective maturities of the

 

 

 

corresponding zero-coupon bonds). So if we calculate the duration for two different

 

 

 

securities, it should be easy to see that the duration of a portfolio of the two securi-

 

 

 

ties is just the weighted average of the durations of the two securities, with the

 

 

 

weights reflecting the proportion of the portfolio invested in each.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

EXAMPLE 2: Duration

 

 

 

A manager of a financial institution is holding 25% of a portfolio in a bond with a five-

 

 

 

year duration and 75% in a bond with a ten-year duration. What is the duration of the

 

 

 

portfolio?

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Solution

 

 

 

The duration of the portfolio is 8.75 years.

 

 

 

(0.25 5) (0.75 10) 1.25 7.5 8.75 years

 

 

 

 

 

 

We now see that the duration of a portfolio of securities is the weighted average of the durations of the individual securities, with the weights reflecting the proportion of the portfolio invested in each. This fact about duration is often referred to as the additive property of duration, and it is extremely useful, because it means that the duration of a portfolio of securities is easy to calculate from the durations of the individual securities.

To summarize, our calculations of duration for coupon bonds have revealed four facts:

1.The longer the term to maturity of a bond, everything else being equal, the greater its duration.

2.When interest rates rise, everything else being equal, the duration of a coupon bond falls.

3.The higher the coupon rate on the bond, everything else being equal, the shorter the bondÕs duration.

4.Duration is additive: The duration of a portfolio of securities is the weighted average of the durations of the individual securities, with the weights reflecting the proportion of the portfolio invested in each.

6 Appendix to Chapter 4

Duration and

Interest-Rate Risk

Now that we understand how duration is calculated, we want to see how it can be used by the practicing financial institution manager to measure interest-rate risk. Duration is a particularly useful concept, because it provides a good approximation, particularly when interest-rate changes are small, for how much the security price changes for a given change in interest rates, as the following formula indicates:

% P DUR

i

(2)

1 i

where

% P (Pt 1 Pt)/Pt percent change in the price of the security

 

from t to t 1 rate of capital gain

 

DUR duration

 

i interest rate

EXAMPLE 3: Duration and Interest-Rate Risk

A pension fund manager is holding a ten-year 10% coupon bond in the fund’s portfolio and the interest rate is currently 10%. What loss would the fund be exposed to if the interest rate rises to 11% tomorrow?

Solution

The approximate percentage change in the price of the bond is 6.15%.

As the calculation in Table 1 shows, the duration of a ten-year 10% coupon bond is 6.76 years.

% P DUR

i

1 i

 

where

 

 

 

 

 

 

DUR duration

 

6.76

 

 

i change in interest rate

0.11 0.10 0.01

i current interest rate

 

0.10

 

 

Thus:

 

 

0.01

 

 

% P 6.76

 

 

1 0.10

 

% P 0.0615 6.15%

EXAMPLE 4: Duration and Interest-Rate Risk

Now the pension manager has the option to hold a ten-year coupon bond with a coupon rate of 20% instead of 10%. As mentioned earlier, the duration for this 20% coupon bond is 5.98 years when the interest rate is 10%. Find the approximate change in the bond price when the interest rate increases from 10% to 11%.

Solution

This time the approximate change in bond price is 5.4%. This change in bond price is much smaller than for the higher-duration coupon bond:

i

% P DUR 1 i

Measuring Interest-Rate Risk: Duration

7

where

 

 

DUR duration

5.98

 

i change in interest rate

0.11 0.10 0.01

 

i current interest rate

0.10

 

Thus:

0.01 % P 5.98 1 0.10

% P 0.054 5.4%

The pension fund manager realizes that the interest-rate risk on the 20% coupon bond is less than on the 10% coupon, so he switches the fund out of the 10% coupon bond and into the 20% coupon bond.

Examples 3 and 4 have led the pension fund manager to an important conclusion about the relationship of duration and interest-rate risk: The greater the duration of a security, the greater the percentage change in the market value of the security for a given change in interest rates. Therefore, the greater the duration of a security, the greater its interest-rate risk.

This reasoning applies equally to a portfolio of securities. So by calculating the duration of the fundÕs portfolio of securities using the methods outlined here, a pension fund manager can easily ascertain the amount of interest-rate risk the entire fund is exposed to. As we will see in Chapter 9, duration is a highly useful concept for the management of interest-rate risk that is widely used by managers of banks and other financial institutions.

C h a p t e r

5 The Behavior of Interest Rates

PREVIEW

In the early 1950s, nominal interest rates on three-month Treasury bills were about 1% at an annual rate; by 1981, they had reached over 15%, then fell to 3% in 1993, rose to above 5% by the mid-1990s, and fell below 2% in the early 2000s. What explains these substantial fluctuations in interest rates? One reason why we study money, banking, and financial markets is to provide some answers to this question.

In this chapter, we examine how the overall level of nominal interest rates (which we refer to as simply Òinterest ratesÓ) is determined and which factors influence their behavior. We learned in Chapter 4 that interest rates are negatively related to the price of bonds, so if we can explain why bond prices change, we can also explain why interest rates fluctuate. To do this, we make use of supply and demand analysis for bond markets and money markets to examine how interest rates change.

In order to derive a demand curve for assets like money or bonds, the first step in our analysis, we must first understand what determines the demand for these assets. We do this by examining an economic theory known as the theory of asset demand, which outlines criteria that are important when deciding how much of an asset to buy. Armed with this theory, we can then go on to derive the demand curve for bonds or money. After deriving supply curves for these assets, we develop the concept of market equilibrium, the point at which the quantity supplied equals the quantity demanded. Then we use this model to explain changes in equilibrium interest rates.

Because interest rates on different securities tend to move together, in this chapter we will proceed as if there were only one type of security and a single interest rate in the entire economy. In the following chapter, we expand our analysis to look at why interest rates on different types of securities differ.

Determinants of Asset Demand

Before going on to our supply and demand analysis of the bond market and the market for money, we must first understand what determines the quantity demanded of an asset. Recall that an asset is a piece of property that is a store of value. Items such as money, bonds, stocks, art, land, houses, farm equipment, and manufacturing machinery are all assets. Facing the question of whether to buy and hold an asset or

85

86 P A R T I I

Financial Markets

 

whether to buy one asset rather than another, an individual must consider the fol-

 

lowing factors:

 

1.

Wealth, the total resources owned by the individual, including all assets

 

2.

Expected return (the return expected over the next period) on one asset relative

 

 

to alternative assets

 

3.

Risk (the degree of uncertainty associated with the return) on one asset relative

 

 

to alternative assets

 

4.

Liquidity (the ease and speed with which an asset can be turned into cash) rela-

 

 

tive to alternative assets

Study Guide

As we discuss each factor that influences asset demand, remember that we are always

 

holding all the other factors constant. Also, think of additional examples of how

 

changes in each factor would influence your decision to purchase a particular asset:

say, a house or a share of common stock. This intuitive approach will help you understand how the theory works in practice.

Wealth

Expected Returns

When we find that our wealth has increased, we have more resources available with which to purchase assets, and so, not surprisingly, the quantity of assets we demand increases. Therefore, the effect of changes in wealth on the quantity demanded of an asset can be summarized as follows: Holding everything else constant, an increase in wealth raises the quantity demanded of an asset.

In Chapter 4, we saw that the return on an asset (such as a bond) measures how much we gain from holding that asset. When we make a decision to buy an asset, we are influenced by what we expect the return on that asset to be. If a Mobil Oil Corporation bond, for example, has a return of 15% half the time and 5% the other half of the time, its expected return (which you can think of as the average return) is 10% ( 0.5 15% 0.5 5%).1 If the expected return on the Mobil Oil bond rises relative to expected returns on alternative assets, holding everything else constant, then it becomes more desirable to purchase it, and the quantity demanded increases. This can occur in either of two ways: (1) when the expected return on the Mobil Oil bond rises while the return on an alternative assetÑsay, stock in IBMÑremains unchanged or (2) when the return on the alternative asset, the IBM stock, falls while the return on the Mobil Oil bond remains unchanged. To summarize, an increase in an assetÕs expected return relative to that of an alternative asset, holding everything else unchanged, raises the quantity demanded of the asset.

1If you are interested in finding out more information on how to calculate expected returns, as well as standard deviations of returns that measure risk, you can look at an appendix to this chapter describing models of asset pricing that is on this bookÕs web site at www.aw.com/mishkin. This appendix also describes how diversification lowers the overall risk of a portfolio and has a discussion of systematic risk and basic asset pricing models such as the capital asset pricing model and arbitrage pricing theory.

Risk

Liquidity

Theory of

Asset Demand

C H A P T E R 5 The Behavior of Interest Rates

87

The degree of risk or uncertainty of an assetÕs returns also affects the demand for the asset. Consider two assets, stock in Fly-by-Night Airlines and stock in Feet-on-the- Ground Bus Company. Suppose that Fly-by-Night stock has a return of 15% half the time and 5% the other half of the time, making its expected return 10%, while stock in Feet-on-the-Ground has a fixed return of 10%. Fly-by-Night stock has uncertainty associated with its returns and so has greater risk than stock in Feet-on-the-Ground, whose return is a sure thing.

A risk-averse person prefers stock in Feet-on-the-Ground (the sure thing) to Fly- by-Night stock (the riskier asset), even though the stocks have the same expected return, 10%. By contrast, a person who prefers risk is a risk preferrer or risk lover. Most people are risk-averse, especially in their financial decisions: Everything else being equal, they prefer to hold the less risky asset. Hence, holding everything else constant, if an assetÕs risk rises relative to that of alternative assets, its quantity demanded will fall.

Another factor that affects the demand for an asset is how quickly it can be converted into cash at low costsÑits liquidity. An asset is liquid if the market in which it is traded has depth and breadth; that is, if the market has many buyers and sellers. A house is not a very liquid asset, because it may be hard to find a buyer quickly; if a house must be sold to pay off bills, it might have to be sold for a much lower price. And the transaction costs in selling a house (brokerÕs commissions, lawyerÕs fees, and so on) are substantial. A U.S. Treasury bill, by contrast, is a highly liquid asset. It can be sold in a well-organized market where there are many buyers, so it can be sold quickly at low cost. The more liquid an asset is relative to alternative assets, holding everything else unchanged, the more desirable it is, and the greater will be the quantity demanded.

All the determining factors we have just discussed can be assembled into the theory of asset demand, which states that, holding all of the other factors constant:

1.The quantity demanded of an asset is positively related to wealth.

2.The quantity demanded of an asset is positively related to its expected return relative to alternative assets.

3.The quantity demanded of an asset is negatively related to the risk of its returns relative to alternative assets.

4.The quantity demanded of an asset is positively related to its liquidity relative to alternative assets.

These results are summarized in Table 1.

Supply and Demand in the Bond Market

Our first approach to the analysis of interest-rate determination looks at supply and demand in the bond market. The first step in the analysis is to obtain a bond demand curve, which shows the relationship between the quantity demanded and the price when all other economic variables are held constant (that is, values of other variables are taken as given). You may recall from previous economics courses that the

88 P A R T I I Financial Markets

S U M M A R Y

Demanded to Changes in Wealth,

Expected Returns, Risk, and Liquidity

 

 

Change in

Variable

Change in Variable

Quantity Demanded

Wealth

Expected return relative to other assets

Risk relative to other assets

Liquidity relative to other assets

Note: Only increases in the variables are shown. The effect of decreases in the variables on the change in demand would be the opposite of those indicated in the rightmost column.

Demand Curve

assumption that all other economic variables are held constant is called ceteris paribus, which means Òother things being equalÓ in Latin.

To clarify our analysis, let us consider the demand for one-year discount bonds, which make no coupon payments but pay the owner the $1,000 face value in a year. If the holding period is one year, then as we have seen in Chapter 4, the return on the bonds is known absolutely and is equal to the interest rate as measured by the yield to maturity. This means that the expected return on this bond is equal to the interest rate i, which, using Equation 6 in Chapter 4, is:

 

i RETe

F P

 

 

P

 

 

where

i interest rate yield to maturity

 

RET e expected return

 

F face value of the discount bond

 

P initial purchase price of the discount bond

This formula shows that a particular value of the interest rate corresponds to each bond price. If the bond sells for $950, the interest rate and expected return is:

$1,000 $950 0.053 5.3% $950

At this 5.3% interest rate and expected return corresponding to a bond price of $950, let us assume that the quantity of bonds demanded is $100 billion, which is plotted as point A in Figure 1. To display both the bond price and the corresponding interest rate, Figure 1 has two vertical axes. The left vertical axis shows the bond price, with the price of bonds increasing from $750 near the bottom of the axis toward $1,000 at the top. The right vertical axis shows the interest rate, which increases in the opposite direction from 0% at the top of the axis to 33% near the bottom. The right and left vertical axes run in opposite directions because, as we learned in Chapter 4, bond

F I G U R E 1 Supply and Demand for Bonds

Equilibrium in the bond market occurs at point C, the intersection of the demand curve B d and the bond supply curve B s. The equilibrium price is P * $850, and the equilibrium interest rate is i * 17.6%. (Note: P and i increase in opposite directions. P on the left vertical axis increases as we go up the axis from $750 near the bottom to $1,000 at the top, while i on the right vertical axis increases as we go down the axis from 0% at the top to 33% near the bottom.)

 

C H A P T E R

5

The Behavior of Interest Rates

89

Price of Bonds, P ($)

 

 

 

 

Interest Rate, i

(%)

 

(P increases )

 

 

 

 

(i increases

↑ )

 

1,000

 

 

 

 

0.0

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

B s

 

 

950

 

 

 

 

5.3

 

 

A

 

 

 

 

I

 

 

900

B

 

 

 

11.1

 

 

 

 

 

H

 

 

 

P * = 850

 

C

 

 

17.6 = i *

 

 

 

 

 

 

800

G

 

 

D

25.0

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

750

 

 

 

 

33.0

 

 

F

 

 

 

 

E

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

B d

 

 

100

200

300

 

400

500

 

 

Quantity of Bonds, B

($ billions)

price and interest rate are always negatively related: As the price of the bond rises, the interest rate on the bond necessarily falls.

At a price of $900, the interest rate and expected return equals:

$1,000 $900 0.111 11.1% $900

Because the expected return on these bonds is higher, with all other economic variables (such as income, expected returns on other assets, risk, and liquidity) held constant, the quantity demanded of bonds will be higher as predicted by the theory of asset demand. Point B in Figure 1 shows that the quantity of bonds demanded at the price of $900 has risen to $200 billion. Continuing with this reasoning, if the bond price is $850 (interest rate and expected return 17.6%), the quantity of bonds demanded (point C) will be greater than at point B. Similarly, at the lower prices of $800 (interest rate 25%) and $750 (interest rate 33.3%), the quantity of bonds demanded will be even higher (points D and E). The curve Bd, which connects these points, is the demand curve for bonds. It has the usual downward slope, indicating that at lower prices of the bond (everything else being equal), the quantity demanded is higher.2

2Note that although our analysis indicates that the demand curve is downward-sloping, it does not imply that the curve is a straight line. For ease of exposition, however, we will draw demand curves and supply curves as straight lines.

Соседние файлы в предмете [НЕСОРТИРОВАННОЕ]