Добавил:
Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:

Nafziger Economic Development (4th ed)

.pdf
Скачиваний:
1961
Добавлен:
22.08.2013
Размер:
11.95 Mб
Скачать

706Part Five. Development Strategies

softer, leakier, and less oppressive over time. Decentralization meant the decay of the party and state, and their roles in the economy. More sophisticated methods of control replaced the brutal, random, and indiscriminate repression of Stalinism. However, the Soviet leadership did not match this softness with institutional changes recognizing the greater autonomy of decentralized units. Indeed, as these units amassed greater control over their surpluses, they reduced the sequestering of these surpluses by the central government, eroding its system for revenue collection (McKinnon 1993:122–

123) (see Chapter 15).

Gorbachev and the reformers implementing perestroika overestimated the reformability of Soviet socialism, which after years of suppression of interest and voice, had little capacity for adaptation, redesign, or self-correction. Bartlomiej Kaminski (1992:18–37) argues that state socialism is nonreformable, as direct controls were essential for the party and state to defend its privileged position. Party officials and apparatchiks opposed, and even sabotaged, reform because it reduced their power and their ability to solicit kickbacks and other benefits. The large number of officials operating in the black market opposed the effect of market reform, which reduced the black market and officials’ incomes and profits. The party monopolized policy initiatives, channeling special interests into association with the party.

Pathologies endemic to the Soviet bureaucracy included secrecy, formalism, cumbersome procedures, rigidity, and the tendency to concentrate on control rather than performance. The party controlled the state by using the nomenklatura system (Kaminski 1992:18–37), the power to recommend and approve managers in administration and enterprises, of appointments and promotions to control access to government positions. James R. Millar (1994:5–6) argued that

the “party” is over, but the nomenklatura lives on. The old members of the nomenklatura still occupy the top positions in Russian society: in industry, government, educational and research establishments, [and] the Duma. . . . The [educated and successful] nomenklatura . . . forms a self-aware network that knows how to protect itself. . . . Meanwhile the nomenklatura is quietly repositioning itself to control the new private economy.

Reddaway and Glinski (2001) argue that President Yeltsin chose “in favor of the commercialized nomenklatura and of its sympathizers in the West, at the expense of the middle class and of the democrats, putting the new Russia on the road toward a kind of liberal market authoritarianism – or . . . market bolshevism.”

Decision making in the Soviet Union was highly centralized, with the Communist Party, its General Secretary (later the country’s president), the Politburo (the policysetting body appointed by the party), and Gosplan (the State Planning Committee, which reported directly to the Politburo) making the decisions. Centralized decision helped focus on particular sectors and provide resources for them. When Gorbachev removed Gosplan and central management, factories, cities, regions, and republics (independent states after 1991) were free to do what they thought best, resulting in new independently decision-making organizations, thus destabilizing the economy (Angresano 1992:385; Ellman and Kontorovich 1992:22).

19. Stabilization, Adjustment, Reform, and Privatization

707

According to Gary Krueger (1993:1–18), Gorbachev did not sequence perestroika (economic restructuring) correctly. He decentralized decision making to the enterprise without introducing the market mechanism and price reform. Although enterprises made more of their decisions and were self-financing, they still were obligated to make deliveries at set prices to state agencies; prices were not adjusted to reflect supply and demand.

State enterprise law, implemented after 1968, meant that Gosplan and Gosagroprom, the State Agro-Industrial Committee (replaced by Gossnab, the State Commission of Food and Procurement in 1989), substituted state orders for plan targets. Central intervention fell dramatically from 1987 and 1989, with the number of centrally distributed commodities declining from 13,000 to 618. The state order system still made production decisions at the highest level but no longer disaggregated these decisions at the enterprise level. Enterprises stopped producing low-profit items, increased their barter, and concentrated on potentially high-value commodities, failing to produce the wider assortment of goods under previous planning. So whereas enterprises increased overall output (and light industrial and food output), they reduced the amount of machinery, metals, chemicals, and wood produced (Krueger 1993:1–18). David Kotz (1992:14–34) criticizes Russian leaders for failing to create the essential capitalist institutions to replace socialist institutions that were abolished.

Jan Winiecki, President of the Adam Smith Research Center in Warsaw, Poland, contends (1992:271–295) that the ruling stratum in Soviet-type economies, who have controlled the means of production, maximized economic rents, or returns to a factor of production in excess of what was required to elicit the supply of the factor. Thus, they favored powerful groups (Communist Party officials and apparatchiks) in making decisions about wealth distribution. Party officials, from the center to the enterprise, used the principle of nomenklatura to achieve their goals. Officials made appointments on the basis of loyalty rather than managerial skill, extracting rent from side payments (access to goods in short supply) and kickbacks from firm managers. Marshall Goldman (2003) labels Russia’s economic system “nomenklatura piratization.” According to Goldman (2003:103, 123), Russia’s transfer of wealth from the state into the hands of so few oligarchs was unprecedented historically.11 Oligarchs were drawn from three categories: the nomenklatura, former factory managers or directors, and outsiders, those on the margin of society, who acted outside the law during the communist period. Afanasyev (1994:21–27) argues that, after 1991, central planning and distribution agencies in Russia have changed names but not functions, namely, the suppression of all market-oriented competition.

In reformist Russia, privatization was nomenklatura privatization, a process that transferred much of the country’s wealth into the hands of the Communist Party’s

11Schleifer and Treisman (2004:28–29) dissent, contending that “Oligarch-controlled companies have, in fact, performed extremely well. . . . Have the oligarchs stripped assets from the companies they acquired in privatization, rather than investing in them? The audited financial statements of these companies suggest that their assets have grown dramatically, especially since 1998.” Goldman (2003:73–74, 208–209) criticizes Schleifer and his colleagues’ policy advice and their rationale that, under rapid privatization, the new owners would “fight to put in place the institutions they found missing” (Goldman 2003:74).

708Part Five. Development Strategies

senior officials, although at odds with communist ideology. The process began with Mikhail Gorbachev in the late 1980s. The participants socialized under the Soviet nomenklatura system continued their dysfunctional behavior into the post-Soviet period, continuing the intolerance, incompetence and corruption of that system. This nomenklatura capitalism committed to inside privatization masqueraded as liberalism. The capitalist nomenklatura and their nouveau rich allies today are vociferous opponents of the Communist Party, which is committed to nationalization (Knab 1998; Yasmann 1998; Bernstein 1999).

CONTRADICTIONS UNDER DECONTROL

During the 1970s and early 1980s, the late period of Leonid Brezhnev’s rule, when corruption and rigidity among Soviet officials increased, the central administrative authority deteriorated. From 1960 to 1988, the Soviet shadow economy grew rapidly, according to Soviet economists. The 5 billion rubles of unrecorded sales in 1960 added only 6 percent to recorded sales, whereas the 90 billion rubles of unrecorded activity in 1988 added 23 percent (Flaherty 1992:1–14; Grossman 1993:15).

Gorbachev diagnosed the major determinant of stagnation in the late Brezhnev period as the “relaxation of discipline,” that is, less adherence to commands, such as output targets, technological rules, laws, and regulation. Instead of increasing investment and rationalizing the command system, Gorbachev undermined planning by envisaging an increase in machine building too abrupt to absorb, an antialcohol campaign that reduced turnover tax revenues and increased queues at liquor stores, a campaign against unearned income that hurt black-market activities that were essential to circumvent the rigidity of material balance planning, the reduced pressure of economic rewards and punishments, the removal of the Communist Party from economic planning, and the attack on middleand upper-level bureaucrats for their corruption. This attack, echoed by the media, demoralized the bureaucracy and increased the resistance of subordinates to carrying out the orders of superiors. The grip of the official ideology on the public mind was getting increasingly impotent, weakening economic incentives and the traditional command structure (Ellman and Kontorovich 1992:10–22).

Increasingly, perestroika and the collapse of socialism, accompanied by the relaxation of censorship and the emergence of independent media and political parties, contributed to a loss of legitimacy of the old social and political order. In the late 1980s and early 1990s, murders increased substantially, bribery and corruption were rampant, and other registered crime rose considerably (Ellman and Kontorovich 1992:2–5, 14). Jehu Eaves estimated that organized crime controlled 20 percent of new enterprises in the 1990s. In 1991, St. Petersburg mayor Anatoly Sobchak pointed out, “The country today is in fact out of control, because the old structures have been destroyed and the new ones have not emerged” (Eaves 1992:16–18, 21).

Decontrol of economic activity brought many activities out to the light of day, but also created new opportunities shielding illegal activity through sweetheart deals with SOEs, asset-stripping, and favorable buyouts under the rubric of privatization.

19. Stabilization, Adjustment, Reform, and Privatization

709

In 1993, Yeltsin, in what sounded like an admission of defeat, said that mafia activity was destroying the economy, destabilizing the political climate, and undermining public morale. The mafia is not monolithic yet is interwoven within the fabric of Russia’s bureaucracy and ruling elite. In the free-for-all struggle to grab Russia’s material wealth, the 3,000–4,000 mafia gangs, with their corruption, criminality, and violence, have major advantages, not the least of which is their connections to major sections of the government bureaucracy, including senior finance ministry (or department) officials who want to undercut private commercial banking. Moreover, party officials have used the opening of private commerce to siphon their illegal wealth accumulation. Although inflation wipes out substantial wealth, the numerous mafia organizations have accumulated large wealth, much in foreign currency, to control many of the new privatized assets. The mafia, which has substantial international ties, deters entry by some legitimate businesses, increases the cost of business for others, and has dampened the interest of Western firms and subjected many Western business people to violence, and, in some instances, murder, for failing to comply (Handelman 1994:83–96).

Gregory Grossman (1993:14–17) thinks the Russian government, by liberalizing, can contain the mafia and shadow economy. For Stephen Handelman (1994:83–96), however, the mafia undermines reform, spawns extraordinary violence in major cities, and helps fuel a growing ultranationalist backlash. However, the boundary between criminal and legal business activity is hazy, with police and politicians ascribing mafia connections to anyone with what seems an unreasonable amount of money. Indeed, Handelman contends that Russian entrepreneurs operating by the rules find it impossible to survive in the face of official and criminal competition, and that the mafia is the only institution that benefited from the collapse of the Soviet Union. He argues that Russia needs to construct a civil society, with an independent judiciary, before the market can safely operate.

DISTORTED INFORMATION

Starting in the late 1980s and culminating in 1991, rulers no longer collected information about economic opportunities, enforced their planning preferences, or received feedback on the performance of managers and their units. Subordinates withheld and distorted information used to evaluate them. To an even greater extent than before, officials in enterprises, farms, and ministries padded and politicized data to avoid sanctions and collect rewards. The planners’ system of outside evaluation broke down (Kaminski 1992:19–33) and contributed to the scarcity of information during the 1990s.

ENTERPRISE MONOPOLIES

Soviet firms were monopolies, inflating prices and disrupting supply after the collapse of central planning. In 1991, planners had organized industry into 7,664 product groups, in which 77 percent were produced by single firms. Seven percent of Soviet industrial enterprises produced 65 percent of aggregate industrial output and employed more than 50 percent of the industrial labor force.

710 Part Five. Development Strategies

To increase their control over supply that would otherwise be unreliable and to reduce turnover (or sales) taxes, Russian firms have been highly vertically integrated and plagued by gigantimania, encompassing steps from producing inputs and materials to selling the final output. In 1992, the average Russian firms employed about 800 workers, twice as many as the average Polish firm and 10 times as much as the average firm in the West. Half of 1992 industrial output was produced by 1,000 giant enterprises that averaged 8,500 employees.

Suppliers also were monopolists. Thus, the manager of a shoe factory enjoyed a monopoly but had to deal with producers of leather, nails, rubber, and other inputs who were also monopolists. But reform replaced material balance planning with the market, reallocating resources away from their usual sectors. The reduction of suppliers’ obligations to public enterprises resulted in price increases, output declines, excessive wage increases, and the deteriorating reliability of the supply system. Decentralization in input–output links meant supplies could reduce deliveries to increase their bargaining power and perhaps their prices. Firms stopped producing low-profit items and increased their barter. The result was that traders and speculators with monopolistic control over commodities enjoyed real price increases of several-fold in less than a year in 1991–92 (Eaves 1992:16–18, 21; Economist, September 13, 1992, p. S13; U.N. 1992:57; Ellman and Kontorovich 1992:22–30; Weisskopf 1992:29). To avoid price distortion by monopolists, a transitional economy should demonopolize (break up large industrial concentrations) before or at the same time as, not after, price decontrol. But these firms have been difficult to split up. Popov (1996:18) advocates foreign trade deregulation and currency convertibility as efficient ways to fight monopolistic pressure on prices in transitional economies. Russia, unlike Poland, lacked the ability and will to follow this advice, especially early in the transition.

THE LACK OF SCARCITY PRICES

(1) The Soviets allocated resources inefficiently, disregarding scarcity prices. Without an interest rate to ration capital, planners allocated funds bureaucratically, with little relationship between net worth and capital expansion. In certain sectors, enterprise managers overordered and invested, whereas other sectors were neglected.

In the late 1980s, Russia used 15 times the steel, 9 times the rubber, and 6 times the energy that the United States did per unit of GDP. For these inputs, industrial output was a value subtractor, meaning, for example, that factories using rubber produce tires whose world market prices were less than the value of the raw material embodied in them! Not surprisingly, Russia has not experienced a boom in manufactured exports with the breakup of the Soviet Union (Economist, September 16, 1992, p. S10; Economist, October 14, 1992, p. 333); indeed, industrial output fell through the mid-1990s, as firms unable to compete at world market prices contracted or collapsed. Russia, which underpriced materials and resources and overpriced finished goods relative to world prices faced greater adjustment problems during transition than East and Central Europe, where prices were closer to the world level (Popov 1996:8–11).

19. Stabilization, Adjustment, Reform, and Privatization

711

Firm negative value added, together with demands for hard budget accountability by some creditors, banks, and tax collectors, help explain widespread pre-1999 wage arrears (86 billion roubles by September 1998) to workers for months and sometimes for a year!12 Value-subtracting firms, many of which returned to barter, sometimes resorted to paying workers with final output such as lingerie, caskets, or bricks. At other times, private enterprises were forced into arrears because of nonpayment by their creditors or even government. Indeed, the Russian government had larger wage and payment arrears than any single firm did.

(2)Most prices were administered. Since the late 1920s, the Soviets’ goal was to turn the terms of trade against peasants to release funds for the state to invest in industry. Farm procurement prices were usually low yet two-tiered, with higher prices for sales in excess of the quota. Yet losing farms have received subsidies (Angresano 1992:393). Since 1991, state and collective farmers have resisted decollectivization and market pricing, with their loss of security.

(3)The Soviets, lacking an integrated price system, found it difficult to strike the “right” balance between carrot (reward) and stick (repression). Wrong wage and price signals do not motivate labor to increase productivity (Kaminski 1992:34).

State farms have paid their workers wages in a way similar to factories. However, state farms, which comprised a rising share (53 percent) of Russia’s sown hectares in the late 1980s, lacked incentives to increase productivity. Collective farms, with 44 percent of the sowings and which base income shares on labor day (trudoden), have provided little incentive for quality work, as there has been little immediate connection between effort and reward (Gregory and Stuart 1994:292–294).13

Yuri Afanasyev (1994:21–27) contends that the gigantic state monopoly, Agroprom, has been the major brake on agricultural output growth, private land ownership, and private farms or voluntary collectives. The powerful agricultural lobby has demanded incredible subsidies from the state, which go primarily to Agroprom.

OVERVALUED ROUBLE

In August 1998, in a matter of days, the rouble lost more than 60 percent of its value, triggering immediate inflation and reduction in real output. Pre-1998 Russia had suffered from a decline in export revenue, especially in manufacturing, from Dutch disease. Rising domestic costs and the fall in world oil prices contributed to capital flight and ultimately, the currency crisis. Russia’s debt default on August 17, 1998, was completely unnecessary, according to Manuel Montes and Vladimir Popov

12Padma Desai and Todd Idson (2000:5–6) explain wage arrears as an interconnected crisis of state power. Government, unable to collect taxes or accommodating nonpayment by permissive policies, failed to pay suppliers whom, in turn, withheld tax payments. Managers used cash for private enrichment, for essential financial transactions rather than for taxes and wages, or for conversion into foreign exchange to deposit abroad. But a major contributor to arrears was firms’ inability to be competitive at world prices.

Why don’t workers quit with lengthy arrears? Sometimes they retain present or future noncash benefits they do not wish to forfeit. But worker strikes were futile and uncoordinated.

13The private sector had the remaining 3 percent of the sowings.

712Part Five. Development Strategies

(1999:39–62). Prior exchange rate adjustment to prevent the real appreciation of the rouble would have avoided the crash.

NEGATIVE REAL INTEREST RATES

Real interest rates in the early 1990s were wildly negative, as inflation, which often exceeded 100 percent yearly, was in excess of the cost of borrowing. Positive real rates of interest would have raised the cost of financing stocks and inventories, making roubles worth more than goods, and would have encouraged the selling of stocks.

CONSUMER SECTORS AS BUFFERS

Under Soviet planning, food and other basic consumer goods comprised buffer sectors, which could be adjusted (usually downward) when inputs to higher priority sectors, such as steel and defense, were scarce. Prices set at less than market-clearing prices meant long lines, shortages, and low quality, dampening personal incentives and worker productivity. It may take years to recover from the Soviet lack of investment in food production.

DISTORTIONS FROM INFLATION

Inflation, repressed under communism, increased more than 112,000-fold from 1990 to 1994! (See Table 19-2.) This strong inflationary momentum resulted from excessive credit creation, driven by credits and subsidies to state enterprises. Subsidies comprised 24.5 percent (import subsidies 17.5 percent) of GDP in 1992. An additional 4.1–23.0 percent of GDP was directed credits by the Central Bank of Russia and the Ministry of Finance to government firms, granted at rates of about 10 percent annually, far below the real (inflation-adjusted) market rate of interest of several hundred percent (Angresano 1992:396–398; IMF 1993:89–91).

Blanchard et al. (1993:18–20) contend that before 1994 the Russian monetary authorities made no effort to stabilize prices, as they realized that the unemployment cost, especially in the military-industrial complex, would have been substantial. “Faced with a difficult choice of pursuing fiscal and monetary restrictions designed to bring inflation down further or saving the national payment system from collapse, the government” and the Central Bank of Russia in 1992–95 and in 1998–99, chose saving the payment system (Popov 1996:15–16). This hyperinflation created perverse incentives and numerous distortions, contributing to devastating effects on output, suppressing savings and investment (especially foreign investment), retarding capital-market development, and contributing to uncertainty (Popov 1996:18).

SOFT BUDGET CONSTRAINTS

During the early 1990s, under declining governmental institutional capacity (Popov 2001:39), firms operated under a soft budget constraint, lacking financial penalties when enterprises or projects fail. Although management and worker bonuses and investment expansion were theoretically linked to performance, virtually no firm was penalized for losses. New firm entry was restricted and inefficient firms were rarely closed down; firms lacked the market’s creative destruction, in which industry’s old,

19. Stabilization, Adjustment, Reform, and Privatization

713

high-cost producers are replaced by new, low-cost enterprises (Schumpeter 1947:81– 86). Firms did not fear bankruptcy, as banks continued to lend to losing firms, out of concern for the political power of their managers and professionals, who sometimes influenced planners through gifts and bribes, or were fellow nomenklatura. Indeed, politicized lending by Russia’s Central Bank to enterprises about to fail or default was the major contributor to inflation rates of about 1,000 percent yearly in 1992 and 1993. Harvard and Hungarian Academy of Sciences’ economist Janos Kornai (1990:23) contended that in Hungary during the early 1990s, firms entered and exited in no relationship to profitability or loss! Russian firms were similar.

Socialism and its legacy can soften the firm’s budget limitation in several ways. First, the national or local government grants soft subsidies in response to lobbying or bargaining by influential apparatchiks or officials (with virtually one rouble granted for each rouble lost). Second, the rules for taxation are not uniform, and tax payments, not rigorously enforced, can be reduced by pressure and pleading. Third, banks do not follow uniform principles, loaning to firms in trouble whose mangers complain or failing to insist on full adherence to credit contracts. Fourth, contracts between buyers and sellers are not free. Buyers bargain down administered prices or sellers persuade a ministry to authorize increased prices in response to rising costs, irrespective of production efficiency.

Firms face hard budget constraints where authorities recognize a unit will fail and exit the industry when it incurs continuing losses and financial catastrophe. “Hardness” means serious consequences from a deficit. “Softness” arises from external help to protect the firm from the loss of jobs and the inability to compete against foreign producers, the redistribution of resources to weak and poor enterprise, and guarantees of security and survival to influential enterprises and their managers (Kornai 1992:140–145).

INABILITY TO COLLECT TAXES

One important institutional capability is the capacity to raise revenue and provide basic services. During the Soviet period, the state raised revenue through a turnover taxes (state monopsony buying combined with low purchase prices, especially in agriculture) and foreign trade earning (from state monopolies). After the breakdown of the Union, the growing size of the shadow economy (perhaps one-third of GDP) and the refusal of many firms to pay taxes reduced the revenues essential to provide basic services and support the legitimacy of the state (Popov 1996: 21).

Russia’s tax revenue as a percentage of GDP declined substantially from the Soviet period (47.2 percent in 1990) and was low (26.1 percent) in 1995 compared to 49.3 percent in Hungary, 40.3 percent in Estonia, and 42.3 percent in Ukraine, and lower than all OECD countries. Russia joined the ranks of many developing countries lacking the funds to provide health services, law and order, science and technology, protection of the aged and destitute, and other state services. Social expenditure, the financing of health care and education, and defense spending were cut dramatically in the 1990s. But government programs and their cutbacks were not planned rationally, as most programs were kept half-alive, half-financed, and barely working (Popov 1996:21–24).

714Part Five. Development Strategies

THE TRON “SAFETY NET”

Enforcing hard budget constraints is difficult because of the Soviet legacy of the “company town.” Millar (1994:3–5) maintains that many Soviet/Russian employers provide workers with apartment space, land for a house and to raise vegetables, medical care in clinics and hospitals, schools and specialized advanced education, subsidized cafeterias and buffets, recreational facilities, travel, vacation sanatoria, and food, clothing, and hardware stores, in addition to a job. Russia’s welfare system is inextricably linked to the enterprise, which must divest itself of its welfare functions if it is to compete successfully in a market economy. Yet local owners are reluctant to dismiss employees. And enterprises purchased by workers are especially unlikely to divest themselves of these welfare and subsidiary functions.

Adjustment and reform programs are initially likely to hurt the poorest one-third of the population. Russia went from low income inequality under communism to a Gini index of income concentration of 45.6 in 2000 (World Bank 2003i:64–68), higher than the United States and all other high-income OECD countries. In Russia, wage earners, pensioners, and government officials without access to wealth in the newly formed private sector were hurt in the shift to the market, especially with early hyperinflation. To secure support from the poor and working class, adjusting and reforming countries need programs to protect the income and social services of the most vulnerable. In Russia, the decline of the “company town” without replacement institutions meant that many of the poorest, especially elderly on fixed pensions, experienced food shortages, crowded living conditions, and a collapse of health and medical services. Tuberculosis, typhoid fever, and cholera, which had been virtually eliminated, reappeared in the early 1990s for the first time in decades. A transitional country cannot abolish the all-encompassing “company town” without providing replacement institutions to provide a “safety net” for the poor.14

THE LACK OF MARKET INSTITUTIONS

Popov (2001:29) contends that the collapse of state and nonstate institutions in the late 1980s to the early 1990s, resulting in chaotic crisis management rather than an organized and manageable transition, was the cause of the magnitude of Russia’s contraction. He observes the collapse of institutions

in the dramatic increase in the share of the shadow economy, in the decline of government revenues as a proportion of GDP; in the inability of the state to deliver basic public goods and an appropriate regulatory framework; in the accumulation of tax, trade, wage, and bank arrears; in the demonetization, “dollarization,” and “barterization” of the economy as measured by high and growing money velocity, and in the decline of bank financing as a proportion of GDP; in the poor enforcement of property rights, bankruptcies, contracts, and law and order in general; in increased crime rates; etc. (Popov 2001:33)

14China’s state-owned enterprises (SOEs) also have served the function of “company town,” as indicated in note 17.

19. Stabilization, Adjustment, Reform, and Privatization

715

Throughout the 1990s and the first decade of the 21st century, Russia’s presidents have announced land reform enabling the privatization of farm land. However, people used to the security and wages of state and collective farms resisted privatization, and private farmers failed to receive services that collective farmers enjoyed. Russians can acquire use rights but suffer from imperfections in land property rights (Swinnen and Heinegg 2002:1029–1030) (see Chapters 4 and 7).

THE NEGLECT OF SERVICES

The Soviets, whose ideology denied that services were productive, overindustrialized while neglecting services (trade, finance, and housing). After the collapse of socialism, Russia had to expand the services essential for a modern economy.

THE LACK OF TECHNOLOGICAL PROGRESS

Chapter 3 argued that Soviet growth from the late 1920s through the 1950s from increased inputs such as higher capital formation and labor participation rates were one-time gains that could not be replicated after 1970. To continue growth, the Soviets needed to raise productivity per worker through increased technological change. The Soviets’ low total productivity growth was a consequence of the exhaustion of input growth. Extracting old mines was becoming more difficult, as the Soviets had exhausted many natural resources and lacked the improved technology to overcome diminishing returns (Ellman and Kontorovich 1992:8–9).

Motivating innovative activity in centrally managed economies like the Soviet Union is usually difficult. In 1959, Soviet Premier Nikita Khrushchev complained about an unsatisfactory rate of technological change. “In our country some bureaucrats are so used to the old nag that they do not want to change over to a good race horse, for he might tear away on the turn and even spill them out of the sleigh! Therefore, such people will hold on to the old nag’s tail with both hands and teeth” (Berliner 1971:585–586, citing Pravda, July 2, 1959).

Soviet managers resisted innovation, because effort and resources diverted to it might threaten plan fulfillment. Although kinks in the new technology were being ironed out, managers lost part of their take-home pay, which was often tied to plan targets, or they may have been demoted. When evaluating managers for bonuses and promotions, party officials gave little weight to innovation. Also the tightly planned system had little latitude for servicing and spares for new equipment or for acquiring new resources and suppliers. Furthermore, the prices of new products usually counted for less in computing plan fulfillment than older, standard goods. Finally, introducing new models required extensive testing and negotiations with research institutes as well as approval from official agencies before production is authorized (Berliner 1971:569–597). Managers are opposed to technical innovation. If potential productivity is increased, the firm’s continuous production will be interrupted and its future quotas raised. According to the Nobelist Lawrence Klein (2001:76): “Technical change warranted fresh prices that did not appear.” The bureaucratic maze hampered innovation and technical change.

Соседние файлы в предмете Экономика