
- •5.2 The ‘parallel’ markets
- •Introduction: the nancial system
- •Introduction: the nancial system
- •1.1 Financial institutions
- •1.1.2Financial institutions as ‘intermediaries’
- •1.1 Financial institutions
- •1.1.3The creation of assets and liabilities
- •1.1 Financial institutions
- •1.1 Financial institutions
- •1.1 Financial institutions
- •1.1 Financial institutions
- •1.1.4Portfolio equilibrium
- •1.2 Financial markets
- •1.2Financial markets
- •1.2.1Types of product
- •1.2.2The supply of nancial instruments
- •1.2.3The demand for nancial instruments
- •1.2.4Stocks and ows in nancial markets
- •1.3 Lenders and borrowers
- •1.3Lenders and borrowers
- •1.3.1Saving and lending
- •1.3 Lenders and borrowers
- •1.3.2Borrowing
- •1.3.3Lending, borrowing and wealth
- •1.4 Summary
- •1.4Summary
- •2.1Lending, borrowing and national income
- •2.1 Lending, borrowing and national income
- •2.1 Lending, borrowing and national income
- •2.1 Lending, borrowing and national income
- •2.2 Financial activity and the level of aggregate demand
- •2.2Financial activity and the level of aggregate demand
- •2.2 Financial activity and the level of aggregate demand
- •2.2.2Liquid assets and spending
- •2.2.3Financial wealth and spending
- •2.3 The composition of aggregate demand
- •2.3The composition of aggregate demand
- •2.4 The nancial system and resource allocation
- •2.4The nancial system and resource allocation
- •2.4 The nancial system and resource allocation
- •2.5 Summary
- •2.5Summary
- •3.1The Bank of England
- •3.1 The Bank of England
- •3.1.1The conduct of monetary policy
- •3.1 The Bank of England
- •3.1.2Banker to the commercial banking system
- •3.1 The Bank of England
- •3.1.3Banker to the government
- •3.1.4Supervisor of the banking system
- •3.1 The Bank of England
- •3.1.5Management of the national debt
- •3.1.6Manager of the foreign exchange reserves
- •3.1.7Currency issue
- •3.2 Banks
- •3.2Banks
- •3.2 Banks
- •3.2 Banks
- •3.3Banks and the creation of money
- •3.3 Banks and the creation of money
- •3.3.1Why banks create money
- •3.3 Banks and the creation of money
- •3.3.2How banks create money
- •3.3 Banks and the creation of money
- •3.4 Constraints on bank lending
- •3.4Constraints on bank lending
- •3.4.1The demand for bank lending
- •3.4.2The demand for money
- •3.4 Constraints on bank lending
- •3.4.3The monetary base
- •3.4 Constraints on bank lending
- •3.4 Constraints on bank lending
- •3.4 Constraints on bank lending
- •3.5Building societies
- •3.5 Building societies
- •3.6 Liability management
- •3.6Liability management
- •3.6 Liability management
- •4.1 Insurance companies
- •4.1Insurance companies
- •4.1 Insurance companies
- •4.1 Insurance companies
- •4.1 Insurance companies
- •4.2Pension funds
- •4.2 Pension funds
- •4.2 Pension funds
- •4.3Unit trusts
- •4.3 Unit trusts
- •4.3 Unit trusts
- •4.5NdtIs and the ow of funds
- •4.6Summary
- •Issuing house
- •5.1The discount market
- •5.1 The discount market
- •5.1 The discount market
- •5.1 The discount market
- •5.1 The discount market
- •5.2 The ‘parallel’ markets
- •5.2The ‘parallel’ markets
- •5.2.1The interbank market
- •5.2.2The market for certicates of deposit
- •5.2 The ‘parallel’ markets
- •5.2.3The commercial paper market
- •5.2 The ‘parallel’ markets
- •5.2.4The local authority market
- •5.2.5Repurchase agreements
- •5.2.6The euromarkets
- •5.2 The ‘parallel’ markets
- •5.2.7The signicance of the parallel markets
- •5.2 The ‘parallel’ markets
- •5.3Monetary policy and the money markets
- •5.3 Monetary policy and the money markets
- •5.3 Monetary policy and the money markets
- •5.3 Monetary policy and the money markets
- •5.4Summary
- •6.1The importance of capital markets
- •6.2 Characteristics of bonds and equities
- •6.2Characteristics of bonds and equities
- •6.2.1Bonds
- •6.2 Characteristics of bonds and equities
- •Index-linked bonds
- •6.2 Characteristics of bonds and equities
- •6.2.2Equities
- •6.2 Characteristics of bonds and equities
- •6.2.3The trading of bonds and equities
- •6.2 Characteristics of bonds and equities
- •6.2 Characteristics of bonds and equities
- •6.2 Characteristics of bonds and equities
- •6.3Bonds: supply, demand and price
- •6.3 Bonds: supply, demand and price
- •6.3 Bonds: supply, demand and price
- •6.3 Bonds: supply, demand and price
- •6.3 Bonds: supply, demand and price
- •6.3 Bonds: supply, demand and price
- •6.4Equities: supply, demand and price
- •6.4 Equities: supply, demand and price
- •6.4 Equities: supply, demand and price
- •6.4 Equities: supply, demand and price
- •6.4 Equities: supply, demand and price
- •6.5The behaviour of security prices
- •6.5 The behaviour of security prices
- •6.5 The behaviour of security prices
- •6.5 The behaviour of security prices
- •6.5 The behaviour of security prices
- •6.6 Reading the nancial press
- •6.6Reading the nancial press
- •Interest rate concerns biggest one-day decline
- •6.6 Reading the nancial press
- •6.6 Reading the nancial press
- •6.7Summary
- •Interest rates
- •7.1The rate of interest
- •7.1 The rate of interest
- •7.2The loanable funds theory of real interest rates
- •7.2 The loanable funds theory of real interest rates
- •7.2 The loanable funds theory of real interest rates
- •7.2.1Loanable funds and nominal interest rates
- •7.2 The loanable funds theory of real interest rates
- •7.2.2Problems with the loanable funds theory
- •7.3 Loanable funds in an uncertain economy
- •7.3Loanable funds in an uncertain economy
- •7.4 The liquidity preference theory of interest rates
- •7.4The liquidity preference theory of interest rates
- •7.6 The monetary authorities and the rate of interest
- •7.5Loanable funds and liquidity preference
- •7.6The monetary authorities and the rate of interest
- •7.6 The monetary authorities and the rate of interest
- •7.6 The monetary authorities and the rate of interest
- •7.7The structure of interest rates
- •7.7 The structure of interest rates
- •7.7.1The term structure of interest rates
- •7.7.2The pure expectations theory of interest rate structure
- •7.7 The structure of interest rates
- •7.7.3Term premiums
- •7.7 The structure of interest rates
- •7.7 The structure of interest rates
- •7.7.4Market segmentation
- •7.8 The signicance of term structure theories
- •7.7.5Preferred habitat
- •7.7.6A summary of views on maturity substitutability
- •7.8The signicance of term structure theories
- •7.8 The signicance of term structure theories
- •7.9Summary
- •8.1 The nature of forex markets
- •8.1The nature of forex markets
- •8.1 The nature of forex markets
- •Indirect quotation
- •8.1 The nature of forex markets
- •8.2 Interest rate parity
- •8.2Interest rate parity
- •8.2 Interest rate parity
- •8.3 Other foreign exchange market rules
- •8.3Other foreign exchange market rules
- •8.3.1Differences in interest rates among countries – the Fisher effect
- •8.3 Other foreign exchange market rules
- •8.3.3Equilibrium in the forex markets
- •8.4Alternative views of forex markets
- •8.4 Alternative views of forex markets
- •8.6Monetary union in Europe
- •8.6 Monetary union in Europe
- •8.6 Monetary union in Europe
- •8.6 Monetary union in Europe
- •8.6.2The uk and the euro
- •8.7Summary
- •9.1Forms of exposure to exchange rate risk
- •9.1 Forms of exposure to exchange rate risk
- •9.2Exchange rate risk management techniques
- •9.3.1Financial futures
- •9.3 Derivatives markets
- •9.3 Derivatives markets
- •9.3 Derivatives markets
- •9.3 Derivatives markets
- •9.3.2Options
- •9.3 Derivatives markets
- •9.3 Derivatives markets
- •9.3.3Exotic options
- •9.4 Comparing different types of derivatives
- •9.4.2Forward versus futures contracts
- •9.4.3Forward and futures contracts versus options
- •9.5 The use and abuse of derivatives
- •9.5The use and abuse of derivatives
- •9.5 The use and abuse of derivatives
- •9.6 Summary
- •9.6Summary
- •International capital markets
- •10.1 The world capital market
- •10.1The world capital market
- •10.2Eurocurrencies
- •10.2 Eurocurrencies
- •10.2 Eurocurrencies
- •10.2.2The nature of the market
- •10.2 Eurocurrencies
- •10.2.3Issues relating to eurocurrency markets
- •10.2 Eurocurrencies
- •10.3 Techniques and instruments in the eurobond and euronote markets
- •10.3 Techniques and instruments in the eurobond and euronote markets
- •10.3 Techniques and instruments in the eurobond and euronote markets
- •10.4 Summary
- •10.4Summary
- •11.1 The measurement of public decits and debt
- •11.1The measurement of public decits and debt
- •11.1 The measurement of public decits and debt
- •11.1 The measurement of public decits and debt
- •11.1 The measurement of public decits and debt
- •11.2 Financing the psncr
- •11.2Financing the psncr
- •11.2.1The psncr and interest rates
- •11.2 Financing the psncr
- •11.2.2The sale of bonds to banks
- •11.2.3The sale of bonds overseas
- •11.2.4Psncr, interest rates and the money supply – a conclusion
- •11.2 Financing the psncr
- •11.3 Attitudes to public debt in the European Union
- •11.4The public debt and open market operations
- •11.6Summary
- •12.1 Borrowing and lending problems in nancial intermediation
- •12.1.1The nancing needs of rms and attempted remedies
- •12.1 Borrowing and lending problems in nancial intermediation
- •12.1 Borrowing and lending problems in nancial intermediation
- •12.1.2Financial market exclusion
- •12.1 Borrowing and lending problems in nancial intermediation
- •12.1.3The nancial system and long-term saving
- •12.1 Borrowing and lending problems in nancial intermediation
- •12.1 Borrowing and lending problems in nancial intermediation
- •12.1 Borrowing and lending problems in nancial intermediation
- •12.1.4The nancial system and household indebtedness
- •12.2 Financial instability: bubbles and crises
- •12.2Financial instability: bubbles and crises
- •12.2 Financial instability: bubbles and crises
- •12.3 Fraudulent behaviour and scandals in nancial markets
- •12.3Fraudulent behaviour and scandals in nancial markets
- •12.3 Fraudulent behaviour and scandals in nancial markets
- •12.3 Fraudulent behaviour and scandals in nancial markets
- •12.4The damaging effects of international markets?
- •12.4 The damaging effects of international markets?
- •12.5Summary
- •13.1 The theory of regulation
- •13.1The theory of regulation
- •13.2 Financial regulation in the uk
- •13.2Financial regulation in the uk
- •13.2 Financial regulation in the uk
- •13.2.1Regulatory changes in the 1980s
- •13.2 Financial regulation in the uk
- •13.2 Financial regulation in the uk
- •13.2 Financial regulation in the uk
- •13.2.3The 1998 reforms
- •13.2 Financial regulation in the uk
- •13.2.4The Financial Services Authority (fsa)
- •13.2 Financial regulation in the uk
- •13.3 The European Union and nancial regulation
- •13.3The European Union and nancial regulation
- •13.3 The European Union and nancial regulation
- •13.3.1Regulation of the banking industry in the eu
- •13.3 The European Union and nancial regulation
- •13.3.2Regulation of the securities markets in the eu
- •13.3 The European Union and nancial regulation
- •13.3.3Regulation of insurance services in the eu
- •13.4 The problems of globalisation and the growing complexity of derivatives markets
- •13.4 The problems of globalisation and the growing complexity of derivatives markets
- •13.4 The problems of globalisation and the growing complexity of derivatives markets
- •13.4 The problems of globalisation and the growing complexity of derivatives markets
- •13.4 The problems of globalisation and the growing complexity of derivatives markets
- •13.5Summary
- •Interest rates (I%)
- •Interest rates (I%)
- •Interest rates (I%)
- •Interest rates (I%)
13.5Summary
The nancial services industry has always been heavily regulated. This has been
particularly true of banking because of the vulnerability of banks to a loss of public
condence. The collapse of a single bank arouses fears of contagion, causing prob-
lems for the banking industry as a whole and hence for the provision of the eco-
nomy’s medium of exchange. Important consumer protection issues also arise in the
failure of banks.
The general case for regulation is based upon the existence of various types of
market failure, notably the existence of asymmetric information; while strong argu-
ments against regulation are centred on the ideas of moral hazard, agency capture
and compliance costs. Regulation increases the costs of entry and exit for new rms
and thus may inhibit competition. In some circumstances, regulation may even
increase the instability of an industry. A compromise position is to support regula-
tion but to argue in favour of self-regulation on the grounds that practitioners have
an interest in maintaining the reputation of their industry and are in the best posi-
tion to understand the impact of regulation on the industry. Nonetheless, several
problems have emerged in self-regulatory schemes. Self-regulation was tried for
the nancial services industry in the UK from 1986 to 1997 but did not operate well
and the industry was beset by scandals. Consequently, there has been a move back
towards statutory regulation, with the establishment in June 1998 of the FSA. From
that time, the FSA has also become responsible for the supervision of banking under
the Bank of England Act 1998, which gave the Bank full control of UK monetary
policy.
The attempt to develop a single nancial market across the EU also presented
regulatory problems as the different regulatory regimes in member countries were a
major obstacle to the integration of the markets. The slow progress in the harmon-
isation of regulatory procedures led to the acceptance of the mutual recognition and
home country regulation principles. Extra problems were caused by the different
banking traditions in member countries.
Other serious difculties have arisen as a result of globalisation and the rapid
development of complex derivatives markets. A major outcome of concerns over these
issues has been the Basel Accord, which has led to the wide acceptance of capital
adequacy rules that at the time of writing are being modied to take account of off-
balance-sheet business and market risk.
-
398
..
..
FINM_C13.qxd 1/18/07 11:39 AM Page 399
Further reading
Questions for discussion
-
1
What have been the impacts on nancial markets of: (a) internationalisation of themarkets, and (b) technological change?
-
2
Consider the arguments for and against self-regulation of nancial markets asopposed to statutory regulation.
-
3
Discuss the extent to which consumers can be held to be responsible for their owndifculties in cases such as split capital investment trusts, endowment mortgagesand the Lloyd’s of London ‘names’.
-
4
How important is moral hazard as a determinant of people’s behaviour? Provideexamples of moral hazard related both to everyday life and to the nancial servicesindustry.
-
5
Under what circumstances might regulation decrease rather than increase the stabilityof an industry?
-
6
List the arguments in favour of host country regulation and discuss them. Why didthe European Commission favour home country regulation?
-
7
Explain the basis of the distinction between the types of capital in the BaselConcordat.
-
8
Why is it thought that simple capital adequacy ratios are insufcient as a basis forsupervising the activities of rms engaged in securities trading?
-
9
What aspects of the regulatory problem were highlighted by the collapse of Baring’s
Bank in 1995?
-
10
What is meant by systemic risk in connection with the banking industry?
11
Why is consumer protection such an important issue in insurance?
Further reading
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, Supervisory Recognition of Netting for Capital
Adequacy Purposes, Consultation Proposal (Geneva: Bank for International Settlements,
April 1993)
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, Risk Management Guidelines for Derivatives
(Geneva: Bank for International Settlements, July 1994)
R Dale, Risk and Regulation in Global Securities Markets (Chichester: John Wiley & Sons, 1996)
FSA, ‘Endowments – consumers act but FSA keeps close eye on complaints’, FSA Press
Release, FSA/PNO8I/2005, 15 July 2005, www.fsa.gov.uk/pages/Library/communication/
PR/2005
FSA, ‘Mortgage endowments – shortfalls and consumer action’, prepared for the FSA by IFF
Research Ltd, July 2005, www.fsa.gov.uk/pubs/consumer-research
399
....
FINM_C13.qxd 1/18/07 11:39 AM Page 400
Chapter 13 • The regulation of nancial markets
D Gowland, The Regulation of Financial Markets in the 1990s(Aldershot: Edward Elgar, 1990)
HS Houthakker and PJ Williamson, The Economics of Financial Markets(Oxford: Oxford
University Press, 1996) ch. 11
SA Rhoades, ‘Banking acquisitions’, in P Newman, M Milgate and J Eatwell (eds), The New
Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance(London: Macmillan, 1992)
Financial Services Authority at http://www.fsa.gov.uk
Financial Ombudsman Service at http://www.nancial-ombudsman.org.uk
http://www.ex.ac.uk/~Rdavies/arian/scandals for details of past nancial scandals
http://www.ft.com for up-to-date information on regulatory practices and problems
-
400
..
FINM_Z01.qxd 1/18/07 1:16 PM Page 401
APPENDIXI
Portfolio theory
..
FINM_Z01.qxd 1/18/07 1:16 PM Page 402
Appendix I • Portfolio theory
Objectives
What you will learn in this appendix:
-
l
How to nd the present value of a xed sum of money due for payment at a
future date
-
l
How to nd the present value of a future stream of payments
l
How to make allowance for risk in the valuing of these payments
l
How to calculate a price for risky and risk-free assets
In section 1.1.1 we noted that choosing a nancial product was rather different from
choosing everyday consumer goods because the benets from a nancial product
often stretch quite a long way into the future and, since the future is uncertain, those
benets would also have a degree of uncertainty attached to them. In this appendix
we set out some rules which enable us to make decisions about the value of assets
which yield futureand uncertainbenets.
Because the benets of most nancial assets are uncertain, the assets are said to
be risky: the return that we actually get may be different from the return that we
expect. In nancial analysis we assume that people are rational, risk-averse wealth
maximisers. ‘Risk-averse’ means that they prefer less risk to more. Other things
being equal, a high-risk asset is less attractive than a low-risk one. When it comes to
pricing assets, therefore, we would expect to nd, as a general rule, that in a range
of assets differentiated solely by risk, the higher the risk associated with an asset, the
lower its price is likely to be. This is an important piece of common sense that we
should keep close to hand throughout the following discussion.
Risk:The probability that a future outcome will differ from the expected outcome.
Notice that in practice ‘time’ and ‘risk’ go together. Outcomes are uncertain
(and may therefore differ from the expected) precisely because they lie in the future.
However, for the purposes of understanding how to value uncertain future income
payments, we shall proceed in a series of steps. In section A1.1 we deal with the
valuation of future payments (both lump sum and a series) as though the payments
were known with certainty. In section A1.2 we look at how risk affects the return that
we require from an asset and thus at how risk affects our valuation of assets.
Note that the techniques we are about to discuss can be applied to the valuation
of anyasset generating a future stream of benets. The nance director of a large
corporation, for example, who may be considering a major investment in new plant
and equipment, needs to put a value on the likely future earnings from that equip-
ment in order to compare those earnings with the present cost of the project. The
following techniques are entirely appropriate for that purpose. There is nothing
special about the techniques that restricts their use only to risky nancial assets.
402
....
FINM_Z01.qxd 1/18/07 1:16 PM Page 403
-
A1.1
Appendix I • Portfolio theory Discounting future payments
It is a fundamental principle of nance (and economics) that:
Any payment received at some point in the future is worth less than the same payment
received today.
A simple way of appreciating this from a personal point of view is to consider
the offer of a nancial gift from a generous aunt. Would we prefer to receive £1,000
now or wait until next birthday, which might involve waiting for 364 days? Most
people would opt for the gift now, but if we think it makes little difference, we
have only to think how we would feel if we had to wait ve years! If we agree that
we would rather have the payment now, we are in effect saying that we value the
payment less highly if we have to wait for it. This raises the crucial question of why
we prefer payment now, and it is crucial because the answer may give us some way of
quantifying the amount of ‘sacrice’ involved in waiting. What is it about ‘waiting’
that we do not like?
The fundamental reason is that having the payment nowgives us the use of it now.
For example, if we have the payment now, instead of in two years’ time, we can buy
goods (for example) which will give us two years of their benets, which we would not
otherwise have. The ‘sacrice’ involved in waiting is the two years’ worth of benets.
If we now think not about goods but about nancial assets, we can say that the reason
for wanting payment now is that we could use the payment nowto buy other nancial
assets which give us their advantages right away. Once again, the sacrice would be
the forgoing of those advantages, for two years in the present example.
If we understand this, we can begin to see how we might put a value upon the
cost or sacrice involved in waiting for further payment and thus how we might
adjust our valuation of a future payment to take account of the waiting. Consider
again the loss of benets in not being able to buy our nancial assets now if we
have to wait for payment in two years’ time. What are the benets forgone? Rather
obviously, it depends upon the assets which we would have bought. But let us con-
sider the very least that we would have lost.
If we had the use of the payment now, we could use the payment to buy interest-
earning assets. What is forgone, therefore, is the interest on those assets. So far, so
good, but there are many rates of interest. High rates are paid on risky assets while
lower rates are paid on less risky ones (remember that investors are assumed to be
risk-averse and so they need a higher reward to induce them to hold the riskier assets).
Which of these many interest rates should we use?
In the present case we are assuming that the future payments are known with
certainty. In effect, therefore, we are saying that the future payments are risk-free: it
is only the delay (not risk) that causes us to adjust their value downwards. If we want
to nd the cost of waiting for payments from any source, we have to ask what return
we could have had from investing the payment (if it were available now) in assets of
similar risk. In the present case, therefore, the appropriate rate of interest is that which
could be earned on some zero-risk asset. (Assets which have strictly zero risk are, in
403
....
FINM_Z01.qxd 1/18/07 1:16 PM Page 404
Appendix I • Portfolio theory
practice, hard to nd, but we might take something like a three-month treasury bill.
The interest payable on it is xed, the government is unlikely to default and, if the
bill is held to redemption, its maturity value is also certain.) If we are trying to put
a price on waiting for risk-free payments it makes no sense to assume that, if we had
the payment now, we could invest it at the very high rate of return which might be
available on very risky assets. This is just not comparing like with like. Let us assume
that the two-year risk-free rate of interest is 5 per cent. Then, if the payment were
available to us now, we could have earned 5 per cent on it over the next year and
then another 5 per cent on that (already larger) sum.
Notice how the benets forgone mount up over time. The loss in the second year
of waiting is bigger than the loss in the rst year because we calculate it not on
the original payment but on the original payment already increased by 5 per cent.
The effect is to make the losses increase quite sharply as the length of time increases.
Remember, though, that we are not concerned to calculate the losses as such; only
as a means of making a downward adjustment to our valuation of a payment if we
have to wait for it. Put like this, we can say that time and interest rates can have a
dramatic (downward) effect on our valuation of a future payment if it lies a long way
in the future. When we make this adjustment to the value of a future payment we
are said to be calculating its present value.
Present value:The value now of a sum of money due for payment at some point in
the future.
How do we do it? Remember that the cost of waiting involves two elements: a
rate of interest which we could have earned if we had the payment available now
andthe length of time which we have to wait. The simplest adjustment is required
when we wish to nd the present value of a single payment (a ‘lump sum’) due for
payment at a date in the future. If we let Astand for the amount, ifor the rate of
interest that could be earned, and nfor the number of periods for which we have to
wait, the present value of this amount can be found as follows:
-
A
PV
(A1.1)
(1 i)n
Notice how the rate of interest and the length of waiting combine to reduce the
present value of the future payment. Both appear in the denominator so that as they
get bigger, the denominator gets larger and present value is reduced. The value of
i)ncan be found from discount tables such as those in Appendix II. The table
A(1
assumes that A£1. Each row of gures gives us the present value of £1 paid at a
given time in future, for different interest rates; reading down a column gives us the
present value of £1 at a given rate of interest, but for different periods of waiting. The
table clearly shows how the present value diminishes both as interest rates increase and
as the waiting term increases. (To see the most dramatic effect, read along a diagonal
from top left to bottom right. The present value of £1 diminishes very quickly!)
Alternatively, we can nd the present value by using a calculator. Exercise A1.1 demon-
strates the effect of changing both the rate of interest and the term.
404
....
FINM_Z01.qxd 1/18/07 1:16 PM Page 405
Appendix I • Portfolio theory
-
Exercise A1.1
(a)Find the present value of £1,000 to be received in two years’ time if the current rate
of interest is 5 per cent.
-
(b)
Repeat the calculation for a rate of interest of 6 per cent.
-
(c)
Now calculate the present value if the rate of interest were still 5 per cent but the pay-ment were to be received in four years’ time.
Notice the effect of both the level of interest rates and time.
Answers at end of appendix
What we have just seen, then, is that any payment received in future is worth less
than the same payment received now. Furthermore, we can place a value on the cost
of waiting and we can use this cost to calculate the present value of the future payment.
This process is known as discountingand the rate, i, used in the calculation is known
as the rate of discountor discount rate. If we ignore any risk that might be attached
to the future payments we might discount them simply by using a risk-free rate of
interest currently available on assets whose life is similar to the period for which we
have to wait. The reason for choosing this rate is that it represents the return that
we could have had by investing the payment if it had been available to us now.
Discounting:The process of determining the present value of a sum of money promised
at some point in the future.
We have seen that the rate of discount which we use represents the cost of wait-
ing for the payment(s). The rate that we choose must be a reasonable approximation
of what we could have earned by investing the payment if it were available now in
an asset of similar risk. But consider this: if the discount rate is the rate we could have
earned by investing the payment if it were available now, then the discount rate
must also be the rate of return which we require from the asset that generates the
payment – otherwise we would not hold it. In other words, the rate at which we discount
future earnings from an asset is also the rate of return which we require from that asset to
make it worth holding. Consider Exercise A1.1 again. We assumed there that if the future
payment were available to us now, we could earn 5 per cent. The cost to us, in other
words, of holding the asset and waiting for payment reduces the present value of the
£1,000 payment to £907. In the circumstances, we are saying, we would be happy
to pay £907 to acquire an asset which would pay us £1,000 in two years’ time (or,
alternatively that we would be happy to hold that asset if we had already bought it).
This is because the return we could earn on £907 over two years would make its
future value equal to £1,000, the sum that we do expect to get in two years. Suppose,
however, that it became possible to earn 6 per cent interest on some other asset.
Then we could sell (or not buy) the rst asset and invest the £907 elsewhere to earn:
£907 1.06 1.06 £907 1.062£1,019
405
....
FINM_Z01.qxd 1/18/07 1:16 PM Page 406
Appendix I • Portfolio theory
We should be better off in two years’ time (by £19) if we were to sell (or not buy)
the rst asset for £907 and reinvest £907 at 6 per cent. In the circumstances, there
would be no demand at £907 for an asset yielding £1,000 in two years’ time (and
existing holders would want to sell). The consequence would be that the price would
fall. To what level would it fall?
The answer is that it would fall to the level such that its future value will be £1,000
when it is invested for two years at 6 per cent. The general formula for nding the
future value of a present sum is:
-
FVA(1 i)n
(A1.2)
where A, iand nall have the same meanings as before. The process of nding the
future value of a present sum is known as compounding. Exercise A1.2 gives us the answer.
Compounding:The process of nding the future value of a present sum beneting from
regular interest payments.
What we have now established is that we can nd the present value of a lump
sum payable to us at some time in the future. Furthermore, the present value will
always be less than the face value of the payment because if we had the sum avail-
able now we could reinvest it. The rate at which we could reinvest is the rate at
which we discount the future payment in order to nd its present value and because
the reinvestment and discount rates are the same thing it follows that the rate
requiredto induce us to hold the asset in question is also the rate at which we dis-
count the earnings from the asset.
-
Exercise A1.2
What sum of money, invested now, will yield £1,000 in two years’ time if the rate of return
is 6 per cent?
Hint: Rearrange eqn A1.2, remembering that the future value £1,000.
Answer at end of appendix
This equivalence between the rate of discount and the required rate of return on
assets is fundamental to understanding why an asset’s present value is also the price
which rational investors should be willing to pay for the asset – this is the main
theme of section A1.2 below.
Required rate of return:That rate of return on an asset which is just sufcient to
persuade investors to hold it.
Finding the present value of a future single payment is fairly straightforward. Finding
the present value of a streamof payments, made at regular intervals, is a little more
awkward since we have to apply the appropriate adjustment to each payment. Such
a series of payments is known as an annuity.
406
....
FINM_Z01.qxd 1/18/07 1:16 PM Page 407
Appendix I • Portfolio theory
Annuity:A series of xed payments received at set intervals.
Nonetheless, the principle remains the same. Each of the payments has to be
adjusted to take account of the level of interest rates and time. Imagine that we are
to receive four equal payments at one-yearly intervals. Then each must be adjusted
appropriately and the present value of the series of payments will be the sum of the
adjusted values. Thus:
-
AAAA
PV
(A1.3)
(1 (1 i)2(1 i)3(1 i)4
i)
Notice again how the effect of higher interest rates would be to bring down the
present value and notice too how the more distant payments are more severely
affected by the time spent waiting for them. Exercise A1.3 illustrates this.
-
Exercise A1.3
Find the present value of a series of four annual payments of £1,000, when interest ratesare 7 per cent.
Compare the present value of the rst and last payments and notice the effect of time.
Answer at end of appendix
With a long series of payments, eqn A1.3 becomes very cumbersome to write out.
Thus we often use an abbreviated form:
-
n
A
PV
t
(A1.4)
∑
t
(1 i)
t1
Equation A1.4 says that the present value is the sum of (∑means ‘summation of’)
anyseries of payments each made at time t(where ttakes values from 1 to n), each
payment adjusted to take account of the value of t. Writing eqn A1.3 in terms of
eqn A1.4 would simply involve changing nto 4.
Unfortunately, whether we use eqn A1.3 or eqn A1.4, nding the present value of
a series of payments can be tedious if we are doing it by calculation rather than using
discount tables. The rst step, dividing Aby (1 i), is quick and easy, but next we
have to square (1 i) before dividing it into A, and then we have to nd (1 i)3
before dividing and so on. Depending upon our calculator and the total number of
periods in the series, it could be a very slow job! The good news is that there is an
alternative method which enables us to nd the value of a series of payments with
fewer steps (especially if the series is long). Its disadvantage is that it looks complicated
and, except to mathematicians, it does not so obviously describe the adjustments
that we are making. In this version we nd the PVas follows:
-
AA
1D
PV1
(A1.5)
iC
(1 i)nF
The advantage here is that the term (1 i) has to be calculated only once, though
it has to be calculated for n, the total number of periods.
407
....
FINM_Z01.qxd 1/18/07 1:16 PM Page 408
Appendix I • Portfolio theory
-
Exercise A1.4
Using a calculator and eqn A1.5, nd the present value of a series of four annual pay-
ments of £1,000 when the rate of interest is 7 per cent p.a.
(The answer should be the same as in Exercise A1.3!)
A1.2Allowing for risk
In the last section, we saw that we can assign a present value to future payments
(lump sum or periodic) by the process of discounting. Discounting is necessary,
we said, because we have to wait for payment and this involves a cost which is the
income or benets that we could have earned from the payment if we had it avail-
able now. In all our examples we chose a risk-free interest rate as the rate of discount.
We chose this rate because we assumed that the onlyproblem associated with future
payments was the cost of waiting. We assumed that the payments were known with
certainty and thus that the asset producing those payments was a risk-free asset.
Since our discount rate has to represent the rate of return which could be earned
by having the payments now and investing them in an asset of similar risk, the
discount rate in this case must be the risk-free rate.
In practice, however, as we said at the beginning of this appendix, future pay-
ments are not likely to be risk-free. On the contrary, the very fact that they lie in the
future makes them uncertain and thus risky. This means that they will be subject to
a higher rate of discount. (Remember we said that people are risk-averse and there-
fore the value of a risky asset will be lower, and the return required on it will be
higher, than on a risk-free asset.) The question is, how do we nd a rate of discount
(or required rate of return) which takes account of this risk?
The simple answer is that we add a ‘risk premium’ to the risk-free rate. In practice,
we may not have to do much calculation. We might just look at the return generated
in the recent past by an asset of similar characteristics. If we are concerned about
the required return on a bond we may nd that one of the international risk-rating
agencies has placed the bond in one of its many categories, each of which has a risk
premium associated with it.
The theorybehind the risk premium, however, is usually derived from the capital
asset pricing model. This says:
the required rate of return on a risky asset is equal to the risk-free rate of return plus a
fraction (or multiple) of the market risk premium where the fraction (or multiple) is
represented by the asset’s -coefcient.
Formally, this is often written as:
-
A K rf (Km Krf )
(A1.6)
A
where Kis the required return on asset A, Kis the risk-free rate of return (what
Arf
we called i in our discussion above), is the ‘beta-coefcient’ of asset A, and Km is
A
the rate of return on a portfolio consisting of all risky assets.
408
....
FINM_Z01.qxd 1/18/07 1:16 PM Page 409
Appendix I • Portfolio theory
The basic idea is really very simple and quite easy to understand. Notice rstly
that the model says that the required return on a risky asset is equal to the risk-free
rate (K) plus some mark-up. That is exactly what we have been saying all along. The
rf
risk-free rate (ior K) must set a minimum threshold level of return. Since this can
rf
be earned on risk-free assets, it follows that the return on a risky asset must be equal
to this plus something further. The expression (Km Krf ) is the ‘something further’.
A
KKis sometimes called the market risk premium. This is the difference between
mrf
the rate of return on a risk-free asset and the return on the ‘whole market portfolio’,
a portfolio consisting of all the risky assets in the market. The return on ‘whole
market portfolio’ is a difcult idea (which we look at in a moment) but it may be
taken as representing a ‘benchmark’ return on risky assets in general. The market risk
premium therefore shows the compensation for risk required by the investment
community as a whole to persuade it to hold ‘representative’ risky assets compared
with risk-free ones. The market risk premium might therefore be said to measure the
investment community’s degree of risk aversion. is then an index of the asset’s
A
risk compared with that of the whole market portfolio. It enables us to say what pre-
mium should be paid on Aby comparing its risk with that of a whole market portfolio.
Depending on that comparison, the asset may need to earn less, the same, or even
more than the market risk premium. If, for example, the asset has the same risk as
the whole market portfolio, then 1 (and the required return on the asset will be
A
equal to K, the return on the whole market portfolio). If asset Ais less risky than
m
the whole market portfolio, then 1, and if it is riskier, then 1. Exercise A1.5
provides examples.
-
Exercise A1.5
Assume that the risk-free rate of interest is 5 per cent p.a. and that the return on a whole
market portfolio of risky assets is 15 per cent p.a. Find the required return on three assets
whose -coefcients are 0.8, 1.1 and 1.3 respectively.
Answers in Figure A1.1
The message of the capital asset pricing model can be shown in a simple diagram.
Figure A1.1 shows that if we know the risk-free rate and the return on the whole
market portfolio, the required return on a risky asset will depend upon its -coefcient.
The security market line (SML) is simply a visual representation of eqn A1.6. Figure A1.1
also shows the answers to Exercise A1.5.
The idea that we should compare the risk of an individual asset with some bench-
mark and then demand a premium based upon that comparison is sensible enough.
But why do we choose the ‘whole market portfolio of risky assets’ as the benchmark?
The answer is that rational risk-averse investors will never hold a risky asset in
isolation because they can eliminate a lot of risk by diversication, and the whole
market portfolio represents the extreme case of the most fully diversied portfolio.
In order to understand this, we need to look in more detail at the benets of
diversication.
409
....
FINM_Z01.qxd 1/18/07 1:16 PM Page 410
Appendix I • Portfolio theory
Figure A1.1
Consider an individual risky asset, A. We could take an ordinary company share
as an example. The essential characteristics of this asset, from an investor’s point of
view, can be described by its return and its risk. Unfortunately, we cannot know the
return on an asset in advance (if we did, there would be no risk!) and so we have
to form a judgement about the return that we expect. We cannot know exactly how
people form expectations in practice, but it seems reasonable perhaps to suggest that
people are guided by what they have observed to happen in particular circumstances
in the past, together with some assessment of the probability of those circumstances
occurring again. On this basis, the expected return on an asset, which we write as C,
can be calculated as follows:
-
C∑PK
(A1.7)
ii
where Pis the probability of a particular state of affairs and Kis the return
ii
expected in those circumstances.
To make an estimate of its riskiness, recall how we dened risk above. Risk, we
said, is the probability that an outcome (here the return on A) differs from what
we might expect. One obvious way of measuring the riskiness of an asset, therefore,
is to look at the variance or dispersion of possible returns around the value that we
expect. If all the possible outcomes are closely grouped around the expected value,
then the probability of being disappointed is low, while if the dispersion is large, the
probability of getting a result different from the expected is quite high. The formula
2
for calculating the variance, , is:
-
∑i (Ki C) 2P
(A1.8)
2
i
Box A1.1 shows how we can use eqn A1.7 and eqn A1.8 to calculate the expected
mean return and the variance. In Box A1.1, share Ais expected to produce annual
returns ranging from 8 to 20 per cent p.a. depending on the state of the economy.
The probability of the economy being in a state of ‘boom’, ‘normality’ or ‘slump’ in
410
....
FINM_Z01.qxd 1/18/07 1:16 PM Page 411
Appendix I • Portfolio theory
the next time period varies between 30 per cent, 50 per cent and 20 per cent respect-
ively. The expected return on the share is 14.6 per cent and its variance is 17.64.
Sometimes it is convenient to express the risk as the standard deviation rather than
the variance of returns. The standard deviation is merely the square root of the
variance (here the standard deviation, , is 4.2 per cent (17.7)).
Box A1.1Mean and variance
Share A
-
State
P
K%
PK
(KC)
P(KC)2
Boom
i
0.3
i
20.0
ii
6.0
i
5.4
ii
8.8
Average
0.5
14.0
7.0
0.6
0.2
Slump
0.2
8.0
1.6
C14.6
A
6.6
8.7
2
17.7
A
However, rational investors are not likely to be interested in holding a single
risky asset in isolation. This is because they are risk-averse and a great deal of risk
can be eliminated, very easily, by holding a diversied portfolio of assets. The risk-
reduction effect of diversication can be seen easily if we only diversify from holding
one asset to holding two. Imagine that we are presented with the possibility of
holding two assets, asset Awith the characteristics just described, and asset B, whose
characteristics have to be found by completing Exercise A1.6.
-
Exercise A1.6
Share B
-
P
K%
PK
(K
C)
P(K
C)2
State
Boom
i
0.3
i
12.0
ii
i
ii
AverageSlump
0.50.2
8.0
8.0
-
2
C
B
B
Answers in text below
If we have done the calculations correctly, then Cshould be 9.2 per cent, while
B
2
should be 3.36. Notice immediately that while asset A has a higher return than B,
B
it is also riskier than B(we should be familiar with this relationship by now). As
investors we now have a choice of putting all our wealth into Aor, if we feel Ais too
risky, putting all our wealth into B. But why put all our wealth into either? Clearly
we could put any proportion of our wealth into A(call the proportion X) and the
balance (1 X) into B. Suppose we opt for an equal balance of Aand B(X0.5 and
1 X0.5). What happens to the return and risk that we can expect?
411
....
FINM_Z01.qxd 1/18/07 1:16 PM Page 412
Appendix I • Portfolio theory
Consider rstly the effect on return. This is simply the weighted average of the
two asset returns, where the weights are a proportion of the asset allocated to Aand
to B. If we let pindicate values for our portfolio, then in general terms:
-
C∑wK
(A1.9)
pii
where wis the ‘weight’ or proportion of the portfolio allocated to each security
i
and Kis the return on each asset. In this particular case, where the weight in each
i
case is 0.5, then:
-
C0.5(14.6) 0.5(9.2) 11.9%
(A1.10)
p
Consider now the effect upon risk. This is more complicated and is not just the
weighted average of the two variances (though the variances of each asset and the
weight of each asset do play a part). Why is portfolio risk not just the weighted
average of the assets comprising it? We can get a partial answer if we imagine an
extreme case of two assets whose returns were variable (and therefore risky) but
whose returns varied in exactly the opposite direction. In practice, such an extreme
case is impossible, but we might play with the idea that the return on shares in an
umbrella company varies in direct opposition to the return on shares in a company
making sunglasses. Given such an extreme case, we could put together a portfolio
of the two shares in which the portfolio return never varied. Movements in the
return on umbrella shares would be exactly cancelled by movements in the return
on sunglasses shares. Although the individual assets might each have a very large
variance, the variance of returns on the portfolio would be zero!
This is an extreme case. A more realistic one might be the returns to shareholders
in an oil producing company and the returns to shareholders in an airline company.
The dramatic rise in oil prices in 2005 certainly suggested that these could move
in opposite directions. However, both the extreme and realistic cases show why
we cannot just add up the individual variances. In the extreme case, we supposed
here that movements in return are perfectly opposed – a movement in one is exactly
cancelled by the movement in the other. However, a similar, albeit smaller effect
will always operate provided only that movements in return are less than perfectly
correlated. Provided that there is some independence in the movements in returns,
there will be some risk-reduction effect from combining risky assets in a portfolio.
More formally:
Provided that the returns on assets are less than perfectly correlated, the risk attaching
to a portfolio of risky assets will be less than the weighted average of the risk of the com-
ponent assets.
Bearing this in mind, we can produce an illustration based on our two assets A
and B. Using standard deviation as the measure of risk, the general expression for a
two-asset portfolio is:
-
22 )
(A1.11)
( AB cov , AB
XX2XXKK
22
pAA
BB
The interesting part of eqn A1.11 comes at the end and features the ‘covariance
of returns’ between asset Aand asset B. The covariance itself is made up of the
412
....
FINM_Z01.qxd 1/18/07 1:16 PM Page 413
Appendix I • Portfolio theory
individual standard deviations and the correlation coefcient of returns between A
and B, .
AB
-
cov K A,K B · ·
(A1.12)
ABAB
It is this correlation coefcient that plays the crucial role in risk reduction. If this
has the value 1, then portfolio risk is simply the weighted average of the risks of
component assets. If it has the value 1, then we can construct a two-asset portfolio
of zero risk. For any value in between, there will be some risk-reduction effect from
diversication. Since the returns on most risky assets move together to some degree,
in practice we would expect values for ranging from 0 to 1.
AB
Looking at eqn A1.11 we can see that we have most of the information we need
in order to illustrate the risk-reduction effect of combining our two assets. What we
lack is the covariance of returns, and this we can nd as follows:
-
covK,K∑P(KC)(KC)
(A1.13)
ABiAABB
In our case:
CovK,K0.3(20 14.6)(12 9.2)
AB
0.5(14 14.6)(8 9.2)
0.2(8 14.6)(8 9.2)
4.53 0.36 1.584
6.47 ≈6.5
Putting everything together (including the variance of share B) we can now solve
eqn A1.11 and nd the standard deviation of our two-asset portfolio as follows:
517705336205
0.(.) .(.) (.)(.). 5 6 5 0
22
p
-
. . .
443084325
-
. .
852292
Let us now summarise our three investment possibilities: putting all our funds
into A, or all into B, or dividing them equally between Aand Bin a portfolio, C.
-
C
ABC
14.609.2011.90
4.201.832.92
Investing in A, we can expect a return of 14.6 per cent p.a. if we are prepared to
accept a level of risk (shown by standard deviation) of 4.2. If this seems too risky
we could opt for asset Band earn 9.2 per cent p.a. for a risk of 1.83. Alternatively we
could opt for the portfolio of two assets, C. This would give us a return halfway
between Aand B. But look at the risk. If combining the two assets Aand Bequally
were to give us half of the risk of each asset, we would expect our portfolio to have
a standard deviation of 3.015 (0.5(4.2) 0.5(1.83)). In fact, however, the risk is
only 2.92. This is what we promised earlier: provided that the correlation coefcient
of returns is less than 1, portfolio risk will be less than the weighted average of the
413
....
FINM_Z01.qxd 1/18/07 1:16 PM Page 414
Appendix I • Portfolio theory
Figure A1.2
risk of the component assets. Out of interest we could use eqn A1.12 to check just
what the correlation coefcient of returns is in this case. Since the risk-reduction
effect is not especially dramatic, we might anticipate a gure closer to 1 than to 0.
Rearranging eqn A1.12 we have:
AB cov K A,K B · 6.5 (4.2 1.83) 6.5 7.7 0.84
AB
The benet of diversifying from one to two assets is shown in Figure A1.2. It
shows the risk and return available on each of assets Aand B, held individually. It
also shows that combining the two assets equally gives us a rate of return (shown on
the vertical axis) which is halfway between the return on Aand the return on B,
while the risk (shown on the horizontal axis) is less than halfway between the risk
of Aand the risk of B. Cis a portfolio made up of equal proportions of Aand B.
But we could, of course, combine Aand Bin any proportions at all between 0 and
100 per cent. The smooth curve joining Aand Bin Figure A1.2 shows the risk–return
possibilities resulting from all those combinations. Notice that the curve is concave
to the horizontal axis, showing that every combination of Aand Bwill produce a
return which is the weighted average of the two assets, while the risk is less than the
weighted average.
But Aand Bare not the only assets available. We could combine Awith Dor D
with E. The results of these combinations are also shown – by the dotted curves in
the gure.
More importantly, however, the benets which we can get from combining two
assets are even greater if we combine three, and greater still if we combine four assets,
and so on. The dashed line, the ‘envelope curve’, in Figure A1.2 shows the possible
risk–return combinations available if we constructed a series of portfolios using
different combinations of allassets, Ato E.
Notice that as we combine increasing numbers of assets, the curve moves up and
to the left. What this means is that for any given level of risk, we can increase the
available return by diversifying into more assets or, alternatively, for any given level
414
....
FINM_Z01.qxd |
1/18/07 |
1:16 PM |
Page 415 |
|
|
|
|
|
Appendix I • Portfolio theory |
Figure A1.3
of return we can decreasethe level of risk by adding more assets. This obviously raises
the question of whether there is any limit to the benets of diversication.
There are two answers to this. Firstly, for most investors there is a practical limit
since the purchase and sale of each asset involves dealing costs. Although the total
benets of diversication increase with each asset, the increases are very small once
a portfolio contains fteen to twenty assets. This is shown in Figure A1.3. Beyond
this point, for most investors the additional benets do not match the additional
dealing costs.
Secondly, even if we ignore dealing costs, there is a theoretical limit which is
set by the total number of risky assets available – the whole market portfolio. If we
did construct a fully diversied portfolio, we should still nd that we had to face
some risk. (This can also be seen in Figure A1.3.) To understand why, we need to dis-
tinguish between specic risk and market risk.
We know that the reason why risk diminishes as we combine risky assets together
is that their variations in return are not perfectly correlated: the uctuations tend
to cancel. But the cancelling effect – the imperfect correlation – is due to the fact
that each individual asset is subject to events which affect only that asset. If we are
thinking of company shares, for example, returns on one company’s shares will
be affected by the launch of its latest product, while returns on another might be
affected by a major strike. These events, which have their effects only on individual
assets, are said to be specic eventsand give rise to what is called specic risk. It is the
effects of specic risks that tend to cancel when we combine assets. However, there
are some events which will affect allassets to some degree. A rise in interest rates,
for example, or the movement of the economy into recession will tend to depress
the returns on all assets. Returns will all move in the same direction as a result, albeit
to a greater or lesser extent, depending upon the nature of the asset. Such events,
affecting all risky assets, are said to be market eventsand give rise to what is called
market risk. Market risk cannot be eliminated by diversication. Even a fully diversied
portfolio will still contain market risk.
415
....
FINM_Z01.qxd 1/18/07 1:16 PM Page 416
Appendix I • Portfolio theory
Specic risk:The variation in return on an asset which results from events peculiar to
that asset alone.
Market risk:The variation in return on assets which results from (market-wide) events
which affect all assets.
We can now see why the whole market portfolio provides a benchmark return
against which we can establish the return required on an individual asset. The
reason is that rational risk-averse investors will never hold a risky asset in isolation
because they can eliminate a lot of risk (specic risk) by diversication. Since specic
risk can be avoided cheaply, there is no reason why investors should be rewarded for
experiencing it. The only risk for which people should expect a reward is unavoid-
able or market risk. A whole market portfolio exposes investors onlyto market risk
and thus the return on that portfolio puts a price on the risk for which investors can
expect to be rewarded.
Deciding on the return which should be earned on an individual asset is then
relatively simple. As we saw above, we look at each asset in order to see how much
risk it carries when compared with the whole market portfolio. Since the whole
market portfolio is subject only to market risk, looking at how the return on an
individual asset moves with the return on the whole market tells us how sensitive
the asset is to market risk, the only type of risk that is relevant when it comes to
being compensated by a risk premium. It is market risk (and only market risk) for
which we can expect to earn a reward.
Figure A1.4 shows how we make the comparison between individual assets
and the whole market. The return on the whole market portfolio is shown on the
horizontal axis and the return on the individual asset is shown on the vertical axis.
The gure contains observations for two assets. The lower group plots the return on
asset Bagainst the return on the whole market; the upper group does the same for
asset A. It can readily be seen that when the whole market return increases by one
-
Figure A1.4
416
....
FINM_Z01.qxd 1/18/07 1:16 PM Page 417
Appendix I • Portfolio theory
unit, the return on asset Balso increases, but by rather less, while for asset Aa unit
increase in the whole market return produces a larger increase in the return on A.
Fitting a line through the observations (either by eye or using standard regression
techniques) enables us to nd the slope coefcient which relates the change in the
market return to the return on the asset. For A, it can be seen that this coefcient
exceeds 1, while for Bthe coefcient is less than 1. The slope coefcient for each
asset is its -coefcient.
In section A1.1, we saw that the present value of the payment(s) produced by
an asset could be found by discounting the future payment(s) to take account of the
time for which we had to wait and the return which we could have earned had we
had use of the payment(s) immediately. We noted that the rate at which we dis-
counted was therefore the rate of return required to persuade us to go on holding
the asset. Since we assumed that the payment was due from a risk-free asset, the
discount rate which we chose was the risk-free rate of interest. Given that we now
know how to calculate a risk premium for the return required on a risky asset, we
can go ahead and use the pricing formulae in section A1.1, but using a risk-adjusted
rate of discount. Take, for example, eqn A1.1 (the formula for valuing a single, lump-
sum payment). Use this in Exercise A1.7 to see how the addition of a risk premium
to the discount rate affects the present value of an asset yielding a future lump sum
payment of £5,000.
-
Exercise A1.7
(a)What price would you be prepared to pay today for a non-interest-bearing asset
which matures for £5,000 in three years’ time if you are assured that the maturity
value is guaranteed, and the three-year risk-free interest rate is 7 per cent p.a.?
-
(b)
What price would you be prepared to pay for a similar asset where the payment in
three years’ time was expected to be £5,000 but where the asset’s past behaviour
relative to the market suggested a -coefcient of 0.7? Assume that the risk-free rate remains at 7 per cent p.a. while the return on a whole market portfolio is 17 percent p.a.
Answers in text below
In the rst part of Exercise A1.7, we are simply repeating what we did in
Exercise A1.1. We are nding the present value of a risk-free asset by discounting by
the risk-free rate of interest. We discount by the risk-free rate because this is the rate
of return which we require. And when we calculate the present value (£4,081.63),
we are saying that this is the price which we (and other rational investors) would be
prepared to pay. In equilibrium the asset will be priced at £4,081.63 in order to yield
the required return of 7 per cent p.a.
In the second part, we are doing the same, except that the discount rate incoporates
a risk premium. The CAPM tells us that the required return on this (risky) asset is
0.07 0.7(0.17 0.07) 0.07 0.07 0.14. The rate at which we discount the £5,000
is 14 per cent p.a. which tells us that the present value of this asset is £3,374.96. This
is the price which we (and others) would be prepared to pay. In equilibrium, the
417
....
FINM_Z01.qxd 1/18/07 1:16 PM Page 418
Appendix I • Portfolio theory
asset will be priced at £3,467.41 in order to yield 14 per cent p.a. which is the rate
of return which we require, given its risk. We can see now that if we are particularly
interested in the pricing of assets, we could modify our earlier statement of the CAPM
to read:
The market will price risky assets in such a way that the return on a risky asset will be
equal to the risk-free rate of return plus a fraction (or multiple) of the whole market risk
premium.
Notice the relationship between price and rate of return that is emerging here
and remember what we said right at the beginning of this Appendix about investors’
attitude to risk and its effect upon price. In Exercise A1.7 we have two assets which
are very similar except in their degree of risk. The rst (risk-free) asset has a price of
£4,081.63. The second, whose earnings are riskier, must yield a higher rate of return.
When we discount by this higher rate we nd the price is substantially lower at
£3,374.96.
Answers to exercises
A1.1£907.03; (b) £890; (c) £822.71.
A1.2£890.
A1.3£934.57; £873.44; £816.33; £763.36.
A1.4£3,387.70.
-
418
..
FINM_Z02.qxd 1/18/07 11:05 AM Page 419
APPENDIXII
Present and future value tables
..
FINM_Z02.qxd 1/18/07 11:05 AM Page 420
Appendix II • Present and future value tables
(1i)
n
£1
Table 1 Present value of a £1 lump sum, paid in n-years’ time, discounted at i. PV