Добавил:
Upload Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:
Trade theories and economic development_L2.docx
Скачиваний:
5
Добавлен:
08.08.2019
Размер:
1.96 Mб
Скачать

Factor endowment theory

The principles of absolute and relative advantage provide a primary basis for trade to occur, but the usefulness of these principles is limited by their assumptions. One basic assumption is that the advantage, whether absolute or relative, is deter- mined solely by labor in terms of time and cost. Labor then determines comparative production costs and subsequent product prices for the same commodity.

If labor is indeed the only factor of production or even a major determinant of product content, countries with high labor cost should be in serious trouble. An interesting fact is that Japan and Germany, in spite of their very high labor costs, have remained competitive and have performed well in trade. It thus suggests that absolute labor cost is only

Figure 2.2 Absolute advantage without relative

advantage (identical domestic exchange ratios)

one of several competitive inputs that determine product value. Tables 2.2 and 2.3 show incomes, working hours, and vacation days across major cities.

It is misleading to analyze labor costs without also considering the quality of that labor. A country may have high labor cost on an absolute basis; yet this cost can be relatively low if productivity is high. Countries with low wages tend to have low pro- ductivity. Any subsequent productivity gains usually result in higher wages and currency appreciation.

Furthermore, the price of a product is not necessarily determined by the amount of labor it embodies, regardless of whether or not the effi- ciency of labor is an issue. Since product price is not determined by labor efficiency alone, other factors of production must be taken into considera- tion, including land and capital (i.e., equipment). Together, all of these production factors contribute significantly to the creation of value within a particular product.

One reason for the importance of identifying other factors of production is that different com- modities require different factor inputs and that no country is well endowed in all production factors. The varying proportion of these factors embodied in various goods has a great deal of impact on what a country should produce. Corn, for instance, is best produced where there is an abundance of land (rel- ative to labor and capital), even though corn can be grown in most places in the world. Oil refining, in contrast, requires relatively more capital and

Table 2.2 Wage levels around the globe

City Gross, Net, City

Zurich = 100 Zurich = 100

Gross,

Zurich = 100

Net,

Zurich = 100

Zurich

100.0

100.0

Singapore

26.8

28.3

Copenhagen

98.9

74.8

Dubai

26.4

35.2

Basel

97.7

95.8

Lisbon

23.6

25.1

Oslo

94.9

87.0

Manama

22.8

29.4

Geneva

91.1

88.5

Ljubljana

21.2

17.6

New York

84.7

78.6

Johannesburg

19.1

20.0

Lugano

84.3

85.1

Istanbul

17.9

16.7

Chicago

82.5

81.0

Budapest

16.6

15.6

Los Angeles

72.2

72.9

Kuala Lumpur

14.5

16.3

Frankfurt

70.0

59.9

Warsaw

13.0

11.4

Luxembourg

69.4

75.4

Shanghai

12.8

12.5

Tokyo

68.3

70.5

Santiago de Chile

12.7

14.4

Brussels

67.9

56.0

Riga

12.6

12.2

London

65.6

63.9

Tallinn

12.4

11.9

Amsterdam

64.7

57.0

Prague

11.8

12.4

Stockholm

64.7

56.5

Vilnius

11.2

10.1

Berlin

63.9

54.5

Moscow

11.1

13.4

Dublin

63.5

66.1

Sao Paulo

10.4

11.9

Miami

62.4

63.1

Lima

9.9

11.3

Helsinki

58.2

56.6

Bratislava

9.7

9.8

Vienna

55.8

52.3

Caracas

9.2

11.0

Paris

53.4

52.2

Mexico City

9.2

10.7

Toronto

52.6

48.8

Rio de Janeiro

8.4

9.2

Montreal

50.1

48.0

Bogotá

8.3

10.0

Milan

44.5

40.3

Buenos Aires

7.9

8.7

Sydney

40.2

40.7

Bucarest

7.2

11.9

Barcelona

38.0

41.1

Bangkok

6.9

8.6

Rome

37.1

33.4

Jakarta

6.5

7.8

Madrid

35.3

39.2

Manila

5.4

6.0

Athens

34.6

37.3

Sofia

5.3

5.6

Auckland

34.5

35.3

Kiev

5.0

5.8

Tel Aviv

32.8

33.2

Lagos

5.0

6.5

Taipei

32.3

35.5

Nairobi

4.2

4.8

Hong Kong

31.1

36.4

Karachi

3.5

4.1

Seoul

30.6

30.7

Mumbai

3.1

3.6

Source: Prices and Earnings (Zurich: UBS AG, 2003), 7.

Table 2.3 Working hours and vacation days around the globe

City

Working hours per year

Vacation days per year

City

Working hours per year

Vacation days per year

Hong Kong

2398

8

Zurich

1872

23

Mumbai

2347

25

Basel

1868

23

Taipei

2327

13

Tokyo

1864

16

Karachi

2302

27

Riga

1862

20

Manila

2301

14

Chicago

1858

15

Mexico City

2281

14

Miami

1856

20

Seoul

2270

20

New York

1843

10

Dubai

2233

26

Vilnius

1833

26

Santiago de Chile

2195

15

Ljubljana

1830

22

Bangkok

2184

10

Montreal

1829

19

Jakarta

2175

11

Tallinn

1826

21

Nairobi

2165

25

Sofia

1824

21

Istanbul

2154

16

Rome

1810

23

Lima

2152

30

Lisbon

1804

22

Kuala Lumpur

2152

17

Rio de Janeiro

1802

30

Singapore

2056

14

London

1787

21

Buenos Aires

2044

17

Moscow

1784

24

Manama

2034

22

Madrid

1782

25

Los Angeles

2022

11

Dublin

1779

22

Auckland

2022

21

Stockholm

1775

25

Budapest

2012

23

Luxembourg

1768

25

Bucharest

1992

20

Sydney

1757

21

Caracas

1989

16

Athens

1744

30

Bogotá

1987

15

Barcelona

1743

30

Tel Aviv

1977

11

Amsterdam

1741

29

Kiev

1958

22

Lagos

1723

31

Shanghai

1958

13

Brussels

1722

22

Prague

1946

22

Milan

1718

23

Sao Paulo

1936

30

Helsinki

1714

28

Lugano

1921

22

Oslo

1703

25

Johannesburg

1910

18

Vienna

1696

26

Toronto

1909

14

Frankfurt

1682

30

Warsaw

1901

26

Berlin

1666

28

Geneva

895

23

Copenhagen

1658

28

Bratislava

1881

19

Paris

1561

26

Source: Prices and Earnings (Zurich: UBS AG, 2003), 23.

relatively less labor and land because of expensive equipment and specialized personnel. In clothing production the most important input factor is that the economy is labor-intensive.

The varying factor inputs and proportions for different commodities, together with the uneven distribution of such factors of production in differ- ent regions of the world, are the basis of the Heckscher–Ohlin theory of factor endow- ment.5 This theory holds that the inequality of relative prices is a function of regional factor endowments and that comparative advantage is determined by the relative abundance of such endowments. According to Ohlin, there is a mutual interdependence among production factors, factor movements, income, prices, and trade. A change in one affects the rest. Prices of factors and subsequent product prices in each region depend on supply and demand, which in turn are affected by the desires

of consumers, income levels, quantity of various factors, and physical conditions of production.

Since countries have different factor endow- ments, a country would have a relative advantage in a commodity that embodies in some degree that country’s comparatively abundant factors. A country should thus export that commodity which is rela- tively plentiful (i.e., in comparison to other com- modities) within the relatively abundant factor (i.e., in comparison to other countries). This exported item may then be exchanged for goods that would use large quantities of the country’s scarce factors if domestically produced. Figure 2.3 lists the Netherland’s well-endowed factors, for example. Table 2.4 shows countries with capital scarcity.6

Therefore, a country that is relatively abundant in labor but relatively scarce in capital is likely to have a comparative advantage in the production of labor-intensive goods and to have deficiencies in the

Table 2.4 Capital scarcity. Capital endowments and output per capita are much lower in the Central and Eastern European countries than in Western Europe, implying large potential capital inflows into the region.

GDP per worker1 Relative marginal Potential inflows3

product of capital2

Bulgaria

22.9

19.1

753

Czech Republic

53.6

3.5

275

Estonia

31.1

10.3

543

Hungary

55.7

3.2

259

Latvia

20.9

22.9

825

Lithuania

28.5

12.3

596

Poland

38.6

6.7

425

Romania

26.9

13.8

634

Slovak Republic

42.2

5.6

381

Slovenia

72.8

1.9

147

Median

34.9

8.5

484

Minimum

20.9

1.9

147

Maximum

72.8

22.9

825

Notes

1 In percent of German GDP per worker (purchasing-power-parity basis).

2 Cobb-Douglas production function.

3 In percent of initial (Pre-flow) GDP.

Source: Leslie Lipschitz, Timothy Lane, and Alex Mourmouras, “The Tosovksy Dilemma,” Finance & Development, September 2002, 32.

Figure 2.3 WordPerfect and the Netherlands’ relatively well-endowed factors

Source: Courtesy of the Netherlands Investment Agency and Ogilvy Adams & Rinehart.

production of capital-intensive goods. This concept explains why China, a formidable competitor in textile products, has to depend on US and European firms for oil exploration within China itself.

Each nation possesses factors of production that may be grouped into these broad categories: human resources, physical resources, knowledge resources, capital resources, and infrastructure. Interestingly or surprisingly, a nation’s abundance of a particu- lar production factor may sometimes undermine

Соседние файлы в предмете [НЕСОРТИРОВАННОЕ]