Добавил:
Upload Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:

economics_of_money_banking__financial_markets

.pdf
Скачиваний:
143
Добавлен:
10.06.2015
Размер:
27.11 Mб
Скачать

C H A P T E R 2 6 Transmission Mechanisms of Monetary Policy: The Evidence 613

Output, Y

 

Peak

 

 

 

Peak

+

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

1

2

3

4

5

 

 

 

 

 

 

Years

 

 

 

Trough

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

(a) Aggregate output

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Money

 

Peak

 

 

 

Peak

 

 

 

 

Supply, M

 

 

 

 

+

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

1

2

3

4

5

 

 

 

 

 

 

Years

 

 

 

Trough

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

(b) Money supply

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Rate of Money

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Supply Growth,

 

Peak

 

 

Peak

 

 

M /M +

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

1

2

3

4

5

 

 

 

 

 

 

Years

Trough

(c) Rate of money supply growth

F I G U R E 2 Hypothetical Example in Which Money Growth Leads Output

Although neither M nor Y leads the other (that is, their peaks and troughs coincide), M/M has its peaks and troughs one year ahead of M and Y, thus leading both series. (Note that M and Y in the panels are drawn as movements around a positive average value; a plus sign indicates a value above the average, and a minus sign indicates a value below the average, not a negative value.)

Statistical

Evidence

find what we seek when looking for timing evidence. Perhaps the best way of describing this danger is to say that Òtiming evidence may be in the eyes of the beholder.Ó

Monetarist statistical evidence examines the correlations between money and aggregate output or aggregate spending by performing formal statistical tests. Again in

614 P A R T V I Monetary Theory

1963 (obviously a vintage year for the monetarists), Milton Friedman and David Meiselman published a paper that proposed the following test of a monetarist model against a Keynesian model.5 In the Keynesian framework, investment and government spending are sources of fluctuations in aggregate demand, so Friedman and Meiselman constructed a ÒKeynesianÓ autonomous expenditure variable A equal to investment spending plus government spending. They characterized the Keynesian model as saying that A should be highly correlated with aggregate spending Y, while the money supply M should not. In the monetarist model, the money supply is the source of fluctuations in aggregate spending, and M should be highly correlated with Y, while A should not.

A logical way to find out which model is better would be to see which is more highly correlated with Y: M or A. When Friedman and Meiselman conducted this test for many different periods of U.S. data, they discovered that the monetarist model wins! 6 They concluded that monetarist analysis gives a better description than Keynesian analysis of how aggregate spending is determined.

Several objections were raised against the Friedman-Meiselman evidence:

1.The standard criticisms of this reduced-form evidence are the ones we have already discussed: Reverse causation could occur, or an outside factor might drive both series.

2.The test may not be fair because the Keynesian model is characterized too simplistically. Keynesian structural models commonly include hundreds of equations. The one-equation Keynesian model that Friedman-Meiselman tested may not adequately capture the effects of autonomous expenditure. Furthermore, Keynesian models usually include the effects of other variables. By ignoring them, the effect of monetary policy might be overestimated and the effect of autonomous expenditure underestimated.

3.The Friedman-Meiselman measure of autonomous expenditure A might be constructed poorly, preventing the Keynesian model from performing well. For example, orders for military hardware affect aggregate demand before they appear as spending in the autonomous expenditure variable that Friedman and Meiselman used. A more careful construction of the autonomous expenditure variable should take account of the placing of orders for military hardware. When the autonomous expenditure variable was constructed more carefully by critics of the FriedmanMeiselman study, they found that the results were reversed: The Keynesian model won.7 A more recent postmortem on the appropriateness of various ways of determining autonomous expenditure does not give a clear-cut victory to either the Keynesian or the monetarist model.8

5Milton Friedman and David Meiselman, ÒThe Relative Stability of Monetary Velocity and the Investment Multiplier,Ó in Stabilization Policies, ed. Commission on Money and Credit (Upper Saddle River, N.J.: PrenticeHall, 1963), pp. 165Ð268.

6Friedman and Meiselman did not actually run their tests using the Y variable because they felt that this gave an unfair advantage to the Keynesian model in that A is included in Y. Instead, they subtracted A from Y and tested for the correlation of Y A with M or A.

7See, for example, Albert Ando and Franco Modigliani, ÒThe Relative Stability of Monetary Velocity and the Investment Multiplier,Ó American Economic Review 55 (1965): 693Ð728.

8See William Poole and Edith Kornblith, ÒThe Friedman-Meiselman CMC Paper: New Evidence on an Old Controversy,Ó American Economic Review 63 (1973): 908Ð917.

Historical

Evidence

C H A P T E R 2 6 Transmission Mechanisms of Monetary Policy: The Evidence 615

The monetarist historical evidence found in Friedman and SchwartzÕs A Monetary History, has been very influential in gaining support for the monetarist position. We have already seen that the book was extremely important as a criticism of early Keynesian thinking, showing as it did that the Great Depression was not a period of easy monetary policy and that the depression could be attributed to the sharp decline in the money supply from 1930 to 1933 resulting from bank panics. In addition, the book documents in great detail that the growth rate of money leads business cycles, because it declines before every recession. This timing evidence is, of course, subject to all the criticisms raised earlier.

The historical evidence contains one feature, however, that makes it different from other monetarist evidence we have discussed so far. Several episodes occur in which changes in the money supply appear to be exogenous events. These episodes are almost like controlled experiments, so the post hoc, ergo propter hoc principle is far more likely to be valid: If the decline in the growth rate of the money supply is soon followed by a decline in output in these episodes, much stronger evidence is presented that money growth is the driving force behind the business cycle.

One of the best examples of such an episode is the increase in reserve requirements in 1936Ð1937 (discussed in Chapter 18), which led to a sharp decline in the money supply and in its rate of growth. The increase in reserve requirements was implemented because the Federal Reserve wanted to improve its control of monetary policy; it was not implemented in response to economic conditions. We can thus rule out reverse causation from output to the money supply. Also, it is hard to think of an outside factor that could have driven the Fed to increase reserve requirements and that could also have directly affected output. Therefore, the decline in the money supply in this episode can probably be classified as an exogenous event with the characteristics of a controlled experiment. Soon after this experiment, the very severe recession of 1937Ð1938 occurred. We can conclude with confidence that in this episode, the change in the money supply due to the FedÕs increase in reserve requirements was indeed the source of the business cycle contraction that followed.

A Monetary History also documents other historical episodes, such as the bank panic of 1907 and other years in which the decline in money growth again appears to have been an exogenous event. The fact that recessions have frequently followed apparently exogenous declines in money growth is very strong evidence that changes in the growth rate of the money supply do have an impact on aggregate output. Recent work by Christina and David Romer, both of the University of California, Berkeley, applies the historical approach to more recent data using more sophisticated statistical techniques and also finds that monetary policy shifts have had an important impact on the aggregate economy.9

Overview of the Monetarist Evidence

Where does this discussion of the monetarist evidence leave us? We have seen that because of reverse causation and outside-factor possibilities, there are some serious doubts about the conclusions that can be drawn from timing and statistical evidence alone. However, some of the historical evidence in which exogenous declines in

9Christina Romer and David Romer, ÒDoes Monetary Policy Matter? A New Test in the Spirit of Friedman and Schwartz,Ó NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 1989, 4, ed. Stanley Fischer (Cambridge, Mass.: M.I.T. Press, 1989), 121Ð170.

616 P A R T V I Monetary Theory

Box 3

Real Business Cycle Theory and the Debate on Money and Economic Activity

New entrants to the debate on money and economic

dence they offer to support the reverse causation

activity are advocates of real business cycle theory,

argument is that almost none of the correlation

which states that real shocks to tastes and technology

between money and output comes from the monetary

(rather than monetary shocks) are the driving forces

base, which is controlled by the monetary authori-

behind business cycles. Proponents of this theory are

ties.* Instead, the moneyÐoutput correlation stems

critical of the monetarist view that money matters to

from other sources of money supply movements that,

business cycles because they believe that the correla-

as we saw in Chapters 15 and 16, are affected by the

tion of output with money reflects reverse causation;

actions of banks, depositors, and borrowers from

that is, the business cycle drives money, rather than

banks and are more likely to be influenced by the

the other way around. An important piece of evi-

business cycle.

*Robert King and Charles Plosser, ÒMoney, Credit and Prices in a Real Business Cycle,Ó American Economic Review 74 (1984): 363Ð380; Charles Plosser,

ÒUnderstanding Real Business Cycles,Ó Journal of Economic Perspectives 3 (Summer 1989): 51Ð78.

money growth are followed by business cycle contractions does provide stronger support for the monetarist position. When historical evidence is combined with timing and statistical evidence, the conclusion that money does matter seems warranted.

As you can imagine, the economics profession was quite shaken by the appearance of the monetarist evidence, as up to that time most economists believed that money does not matter at all. Monetarists had demonstrated that this early Keynesian position was probably wrong, and it won them a lot of converts. Recognizing the fallacy of the position that money does not matter does not necessarily mean that we must accept the position that money is all that matters. Many Keynesian economists shifted their views toward the monetarist position, but not all the way. Instead, they adopted an intermediate position compatible with the Keynesian aggregate supply and demand analysis described in Chapter 25: They allowed that money, fiscal policy, net exports, and Òanimal spiritsÓ all contributed to fluctuations in aggregate demand. The result has been a convergence of the Keynesian and monetarist views on the importance of money to economic activity. However, proponents of a new theory of aggregate fluctuations called real business cycle theory are more critical of the monetarist reduced-form evidence that money is important to business cycle fluctuations because they believe there is reverse causation from the business cycle to money (see Box 3).

Transmission Mechanisms of Monetary Policy

After the successful monetarist attack on the early Keynesian position, economic research went in two directions. One direction was to use more sophisticated monetarist reduced-form models to test for the importance of money to economic activity.10

10The most prominent example of more sophisticated reduced-form research is the so-called St. Louis model, which was developed at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis in the late 1960s and early 1970s. It provided support for the monetarist position, but is subject to the same criticisms of reduced-form evidence outlined in the text. The St. Louis model was first outlined in Leonall Andersen and Jerry Jordan, ÒMonetary and Fiscal Actions: A Test of Their Relative Importance in Economic Stabilization,Ó Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 50 (November 1968): 11Ð23.

Traditional

Interest-Rate

Channels

C H A P T E R 2 6 Transmission Mechanisms of Monetary Policy: The Evidence 617

The second direction was to pursue a structural model approach and to develop a better understanding of channels (other than interest-rate effects on investment) through which monetary policy affects aggregate demand. In this section we examine some of these channels, or transmission mechanisms, beginning with interest-rate channels, because they are the key monetary transmission mechanism in the Keynesian ISLM and AD/AS models you have seen in Chapters 23, 24, and 25.

The traditional Keynesian view of the monetary transmission mechanism can be characterized by the following schematic showing the effect of a monetary expansion:

M irI Y

(1)

where M↑ indicates an expansionary monetary policy leading to a fall in real interest rates (ir↓ ), which in turn lowers the cost of capital, causing a rise in investment spending (I↑ ), thereby leading to an increase in aggregate demand and a rise in output (Y↑ ).

Although Keynes originally emphasized this channel as operating through businessesÕ decisions about investment spending, the search for new monetary transmission mechanisms recognized that consumersÕ decisions about housing and consumer durable expenditure (spending by consumers on durable items such as automobiles and refrigerators) also are investment decisions. Thus the interest-rate channel of monetary transmission outlined in Equation 1 applies equally to consumer spending, in which I represents residential housing and consumer durable expenditure.

An important feature of the interest-rate transmission mechanism is its emphasis on the real rather than the nominal interest rate as the rate that affects consumer and business decisions. In addition, it is often the real long-term interest rate and not the short-term interest rate that is viewed as having the major impact on spending. How is it that changes in the short-term nominal interest rate induced by a central bank result in a corresponding change in the real interest rate on both shortand long-term bonds? The key is the phenomenon known as sticky prices, the fact that the aggregate price level adjusts slowly over time, meaning that expansionary monetary policy, which lowers the short-term nominal interest rate, also lowers the short-term real interest rate. The expectations hypothesis of the term structure described in Chapter 6, which states that the long-term interest rate is an average of expected future shortterm interest rates, suggests that the lower real short-term interest rate leads to a fall in the real long-term interest rate. These lower real interest rates then lead to rises in business fixed investment, residential housing investment, inventory investment, and consumer durable expenditure, all of which produce the rise in aggregate output.

The fact that it is the real interest rate rather than the nominal rate that affects spending provides an important mechanism for how monetary policy can stimulate the economy, even if nominal interest rates hit a floor of zero during a deflationary episode. With nominal interest rates at a floor of zero, an expansion in the money supply (M ↑ ) can raise the expected price level (P e↑ ) and hence expected inflation ( e↑ ), thereby lowering the real interest rate (ir [i e]↓ ) even when the nominal interest rate is fixed at zero and stimulating spending through the interest-rate channel:

M P e eirI Y

(2)

This mechanism thus indicates that monetary policy can still be effective even when nominal interest rates have already been driven down to zero by the monetary authorities. Indeed, this mechanism is a key element in monetarist discussions of why the U.S. economy was not stuck in a liquidity trap (in which increases in the money supply

618 P A R T V I

Monetary Theory

 

 

might be unable to lower interest rates, discussed in Chapter 22) during the Great

 

Depression and why expansionary monetary policy could have prevented the sharp

 

decline in output during that period.

 

 

Some economists, such as John Taylor of Stanford University, take the position

 

that there is strong empirical evidence for substantial interest-rate effects on consumer

 

and investment spending through the cost of capital, making the interest-rate mone-

 

tary transmission mechanism a strong one. His position is highly controversial, and

 

many researchers, including Ben Bernanke of Princeton University and Mark Gertler

 

of New York University, believe that the empirical evidence does not support strong

 

interest-rate effects operating through the cost of capital.11 Indeed, these researchers

 

see the empirical failure of traditional interest-rate monetary transmission mecha-

 

nisms as having provided the stimulus for the search for other transmission mecha-

 

nisms of monetary policy.

 

 

These other transmission mechanisms fall into two basic categories: those operat-

 

ing through asset prices other than interest rates and those operating through asym-

 

metric information effects on credit markets (the so-called credit view). (All these

 

mechanisms are summarized in the schematic diagram in Figure 3.)

 

Other Asset

As we have seen earlier in the chapter, a key monetarist objection to the Keynesian

Price Channels

analysis of monetary policy effects on the economy is that it focuses on only one asset

 

price, the interest rate, rather than on many asset prices. Monetarists envision a trans-

 

mission mechanism in which other relative asset prices and real wealth transmit mon-

 

etary effects onto the economy. In addition to bond prices, two other asset prices

 

receive substantial attention as channels for monetary policy effects: foreign exchange

 

and equities (stocks).

 

 

Exchange Rate Effects on Net Exports. With the growing internationalization of

 

economies throughout the world and the advent of flexible exchange rates, more

 

attention has been paid to how monetary policy affects exchange rates, which in turn

 

affect net exports and aggregate output.

 

 

This channel also involves interest-rate effects, because, as we have seen in

 

Chapter 19, when domestic real interest rates fall, domestic dollar deposits become

 

less attractive relative to deposits denominated in foreign currencies. As a result, the

 

value of dollar deposits relative to other currency deposits falls, and the dollar depre-

 

ciates (denoted by E ↓ ). The lower value of the domestic currency makes domestic

 

goods cheaper than foreign goods, thereby causing a rise in net exports (NX↑ ) and

 

hence in aggregate output (Y↑ ). The schematic for the monetary transmission mech-

 

anism that operates through the exchange rate is:

 

 

MirE NX Y

(3)

Recent research has found that this exchange rate channel plays an important role in how monetary policy affects the domestic economy.12

11See John Taylor, ÒThe Monetary Transmission Mechanism: An Empirical Framework,Ó Journal of Economic Perspectives 9 (Fall 1995): 11Ð26, and Ben Bernanke and Mark Gertler, ÒInside the Black Box: The Credit Channel of Monetary Policy Transmission,Ó Journal of Economic Perspectives 9 (Fall 1995): 27Ð48.

12For example, see Ralph Bryant, Peter Hooper, and Catherine Mann, Evaluating Policy Regimes: New Empirical Research in Empirical Macroeconomics (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1993), and John B. Taylor,

Macroeconomic Policy in a World Economy: From Econometric Design to Practical Operation (New York: Norton, 1993).

619

TRANSMISSION

MECHANISMS

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

MONETARY POLICY

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

OTHER ASSET PRICE EFFECTS

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

CREDIT VIEW

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

TRADITIONAL

EXCHANGE

 

TOBIN'Sq

WEALTH

BANK

 

BALANCE

 

CASH FLOW

 

UNANTICIPATED

 

HOUSEHOLD

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

INTEREST-

RATE

 

THEORY

EFFECTS

LENDING

 

SHEET

 

CHANNEL

 

PRICE LEVEL

 

LIQUIDITY

 

 

RATE

EFFECTS ON

 

 

 

 

 

 

CHANNEL

 

CHANNEL

 

 

 

 

 

CHANNEL

 

EFFECTS

 

 

EFFECTS

NET EXPORTS

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Monetary

Monetary

 

Monetary

Monetary

Monetary

 

Monetary

 

Monetary

 

Monetary

 

Monetary

 

 

policy

policy

 

policy

policy

policy

 

policy

 

policy

 

policy

 

policy

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Real

Real

 

Stock prices

Stock prices

Bank deposits

 

Stock prices

 

Nominal

 

Unanticipated

 

Stock prices

 

 

interest rates

interest rates

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

interest rates

 

price level

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Tobin’s q

Financial

Bank loans

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Financial

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Exchange

 

 

 

 

wealth

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Cash flow

 

 

 

 

 

wealth

 

 

 

 

rate

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Moral hazard,

 

 

 

 

 

Moral hazard,

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

adverse

 

Moral hazard,

 

adverse

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

selection

 

adverse

 

selection

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

selection

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Lending activity

 

 

 

 

 

Lending activity

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Lending activity

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Probability

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

of financial

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

distress

COMPONENTSOF

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

(GDP)SPENDING

INVESTMENT

 

 

 

 

INVESTMENT

 

 

INVESTMENT

 

INVESTMENT

 

INVESTMENT

 

INVESTMENT

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

RESIDENTIAL

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

RESIDENTIAL

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

RESIDENTIAL

 

 

HOUSING

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

HOUSING

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

HOUSING

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

CONSUMER

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

CONSUMPTION

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

CONSUMER

 

 

DURABLE

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

DURABLE

 

 

EXPENDITURE

NET EXPORTS

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

EXPENDITURE

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT

F I G U R E 3 The Link Between Monetary Policy and GDP: Monetary Transmission Mechanisms

620 P A R T V I Monetary Theory

Tobin’s q Theory. James Tobin developed a theory, referred to as TobinÕs q Theory, that explains how monetary policy can affect the economy through its effects on the valuation of equities (stock). Tobin defines q as the market value of firms divided by the replacement cost of capital. If q is high, the market price of firms is high relative to the replacement cost of capital, and new plant and equipment capital is cheap relative to the market value of firms. Companies can then issue stock and get a high price for it relative to the cost of the facilities and equipment they are buying. Investment spending will rise, because firms can buy a lot of new investment goods with only a small issue of stock.

Conversely, when q is low, firms will not purchase new investment goods because the market value of firms is low relative to the cost of capital. If companies want to acquire capital when q is low, they can buy another firm cheaply and acquire old capital instead. Investment spending, the purchase of new investment goods, will then be very low. TobinÕs q theory gives a good explanation for the extremely low rate of investment spending during the Great Depression. In that period, stock prices collapsed, and by 1933, stocks were worth only one-tenth of their value in late 1929; q fell to unprecedented low levels.

The crux of this discussion is that a link exists between TobinÕs q and investment spending. But how might monetary policy affect stock prices? Quite simply, when monetary policy is expansionary, the public finds that it has more money than it wants and so gets rid of it through spending. One place the public spends is in the stock market, increasing the demand for stocks and consequently raising their prices.13 Combining this with the fact that higher stock prices (Ps) will lead to a higher q and thus higher investment spending I leads to the following transmission mechanism of monetary policy:14

M PsqIY

(4)

Wealth Effects. In their search for new monetary transmission mechanisms, researchers also looked at how consumersÕ balance sheets might affect their spending decisions. Franco Modigliani was the first to take this tack, using his famous life cycle hypothesis of consumption. Consumption is spending by consumers on nondurable goods and services.15 It differs from consumer expenditure in that it does not include spending on consumer durables. The basic premise of ModiglianiÕs theory is that consumers smooth out their consumption over time. Therefore, what determines consumption spending is the lifetime resources of consumers, not just todayÕs income.

13See James Tobin, ÒA General Equilibrium Approach to Monetary Theory,Ó Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 1 (1969): 15Ð29. A somewhat more Keynesian story with the same outcome is that the increase in the money supply lowers interest rates on bonds so that the yields on alternatives to stocks fall. This makes stocks more attractive relative to bonds, so demand for them increases, raises their price, and thereby lowers their yield.

14An alternative way of looking at the link between stock prices and investment spending is that higher stock prices lower the yield on stocks and reduce the cost of financing investment spending through issuing equity. This way of looking at the link between stock prices and investment spending is formally equivalent to TobinÕs q approach; see Barry Bosworth, ÒThe Stock Market and the Economy,Ó Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2 (1975): 257Ð290.

15Consumption also includes another small component, the services that a consumer receives from the ownership of housing and consumer durables.

C H A P T E R 2 6 Transmission Mechanisms of Monetary Policy: The Evidence 621

An important component of consumersÕ lifetime resources is their financial wealth, a major component of which is common stocks. When stock prices rise, the value of financial wealth increases, thereby increasing the lifetime resources of consumers, and consumption should rise. Considering that, as we have seen, expansionary monetary policy can lead to a rise in stock prices, we now have another monetary transmission mechanism:

M Ps↑ wealth ↑ consumption ↑ Y

(5)

ModiglianiÕs research found this relationship to be an extremely powerful mechanism that adds substantially to the potency of monetary policy.16

The wealth and TobinÕs q channels allow for a general definition of equity, so the Tobin q framework can also be applied to the housing market, where housing is equity. An increase in house prices, which raises their prices relative to replacement cost, leads to a rise in TobinÕs q for housing, thereby stimulating its production. Similarly, housing and land prices are extremely important components of wealth, and so rises in these prices increase wealth, thereby raising consumption. Monetary expansion, which raises land and housing prices through the TobinÕs q and wealth mechanisms described here, thus leads to a rise in aggregate demand.

Credit View

Dissatisfaction with

the conventional stories that interest-rate

effects

explain the

 

impact of monetary policy on expenditures on durable assets has led to a new expla-

 

nation based on the problem of asymmetric information in financial markets (see

 

Chapter 8). This explanation, referred to as the credit view, proposes that two types of

 

monetary transmission channels arise as a result of information problems in credit

 

markets: those that operate through effects on bank lending and those that operate

 

through effects on firmsÕ and householdsÕ balance sheets.17

 

 

 

Bank Lending Channel. The bank lending channel is based on the analysis in Chapter

 

8, which demonstrated that banks play a special role in the financial system because

 

they are especially well suited to solve asymmetric information problems in credit

 

markets. Because of banksÕ special role, certain borrowers will not have access to the

 

credit markets unless they borrow from banks. As long as there is no perfect substi-

 

tutability of retail bank deposits with other sources of funds, the bank lending chan-

 

nel of monetary transmission operates as follows. Expansionary monetary policy,

 

which increases bank reserves and bank deposits, increases the quantity of bank loans

 

available. Because many borrowers are dependent on bank loans to finance their

 

activities, this increase in loans will cause investment (and possibly consumer) spend-

 

ing to rise. Schematically, the monetary policy effect is:

 

 

 

M

bank deposits ↑ bank loans ↑ I

Y

(6)

16See Franco Modigliani, ÒMonetary Policy and Consumption,Ó in Consumer Spending and Money Policy: The Linkages (Boston: Federal Reserve Bank, 1971), pp. 9Ð84.

17Surveys of the credit view can be found in Ben Bernanke, ÒCredit in the Macroeconomy,Ó Federal Reserve Bank of New York Quarterly Review, Spring 1993, pp. 50Ð70; Ben Bernanke and Mark Gertler, ÒInside the Black Box: The Credit Channel of Monetary Policy Transmission,Ó Journal of Economic Perspectives 9 (Fall 1995): 27Ð48; Stephen G. Cecchetti, ÒDistinguishing Theories of the Monetary Transmission Mechanism,Ó Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 77 (MayÐJune 1995): 83Ð97; and R. Glenn Hubbard, ÒIs There a ÔCredit ChannelÕ for Monetary Policy?Ó Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 77 (MayÐJune 1995): 63Ð74.

622 P A R T V I Monetary Theory

An important implication of the credit view is that monetary policy will have a greater effect on expenditure by smaller firms, which are more dependent on bank loans, than it will on large firms, which can access the credit markets directly through stock and bond markets (and not only through banks).

Though this result has been confirmed by researchers, doubts about the bank lending channel have been raised in the literature, and there are reasons to suspect that the bank lending channel in the United States may not be as powerful as it once was.18 The first reason this channel is not as powerful is that the current U.S. regulatory framework no longer imposes restrictions on banks that hinder their ability to raise funds (see Chapter 9). Prior to the mid-1980s, certificates of deposit (CDs) were subjected to reserve requirements and Regulation Q deposit rate ceilings, which made it hard for banks to replace deposits that flowed out of the banking system during a monetary contraction. With these regulatory restrictions abolished, banks can more easily respond to a decline in bank reserves and a loss of retail deposits by issuing CDs at market interest rates that do not have to be backed up by required reserves. Second, the worldwide decline of the traditional bank lending business (see Chapter 10) has rendered the bank lending channel less potent. Nonetheless, many economists believe that the bank lending channel played an important role in the slow recovery in the U.S. from the 1990Ð91 recession.

Balance Sheet Channel. Even though the bank lending channel may be declining in importance, it is by no means clear that this is the case for the other credit channel, the balance sheet channel. Like the bank lending channel, the balance sheet channel also arises from the presence of asymmetric information problems in credit markets. In Chapter 8, we saw that the lower the net worth of business firms, the more severe the adverse selection and moral hazard problems in lending to these firms. Lower net worth means that lenders in effect have less collateral for their loans, and so potential losses from adverse selection are higher. A decline in net worth, which raises the adverse selection problem, thus leads to decreased lending to finance investment spending. The lower net worth of businesses also increases the moral hazard problem because it means that owners have a lower equity stake in their firms, giving them more incentive to engage in risky investment projects. Since taking on riskier investment projects makes it more likely that lenders will not be paid back, a decrease in businessesÕ net worth leads to a decrease in lending and hence in investment spending.

Monetary policy can affect firmsÕ balance sheets in several ways. Expansionary monetary policy (M ↑ ), which causes a rise in stock prices (Ps↑ ) along lines described earlier, raises the net worth of firms and so leads to higher investment spending (I ↑ ) and aggregate demand (Y ↑ ) because of the decrease in adverse selection and moral hazard problems. This leads to the following schematic for one balance sheet channel of monetary transmission:

M Ps↑ adverse selection ↓, moral hazard ↓ lending ↑ I Y

(7)

Cash Flow Channel. Another balance sheet channel operates through its effects on cash flow, the difference between cash receipts and cash expenditures. Expansionary

18For example, see Valerie Ramey, ÒHow Important Is the Credit Channel in the Transmission of Monetary Policy?Ó Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 39 (1993): 1Ð45, and Allan H. Meltzer, ÒMonetary, Credit (and Other) Transmission Processes: A Monetarist Perspective,Ó Journal of Economic Perspectives 9 (Fall 1995): 49Ð72.

Соседние файлы в предмете [НЕСОРТИРОВАННОЕ]