Добавил:
Upload Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:

es2

.pdf
Скачиваний:
8
Добавлен:
02.06.2015
Размер:
2.28 Mб
Скачать

Allen /Costs of Economic Sanctions

935

 

 

Table

3

 

 

 

Incidence Rate Ratios

 

 

 

 

Demonstrations

Riots

Lagged

dependent variable

1.276

1.245

 

Polity score squared

Polity

score 1.031 1.035

 

0.990

0.989

 

Presence

of sanctions

1.745

1.306

 

Polity x

sanctions

1.043

1.072

 

Sanction

costs

0.975

1.001

 

ln(population)

1.356

1.568

 

ln(energy consumption)

1.122

1.018

 

Regime

durability

0.997

0.995

 

The

relationship between

regime type and

riots is similar to that estimated for

demonstrations. The

 

basic

shape of the relationship can be

seen inFigure 5. Again,

the

states

 

with

the

 

lowest

predicted

 

events

 

are

 

at

the

extremes?those

states

that

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

are most

autocratic

 

and

those

that

are

most

democratic.

This shape

is

slightly

more

symmetrical than

it is for demonstrations, which

suggests

that riots are

a

less

accepted means

of expressing political discontent inhighly democratic societies.

 

Focusing

 

on

the

results

related

 

to

sanctions,

marginal

effects

again

were

calcu

lated,

and

 

these

are

presented

 

in Figure

6. As

was

the case

with

demonstrations,

 

we

see that thepresence

of sanctions

increases

the likelihood of antigovernment activ

ityformost regime types. Sanctions

appear

to increase the likelihood of riots in a

statistically significantway

for stateswith regime scores greater than 1.The

lack of

statistical significance for the sanctions-indicator variable

reflects the fact that this

relationship is indistinguishable from0 for stateswith a Polity

score of 0. This

pro

vides

additional support for theAutocratic

Opportunity Hypothesis.

Sanctions do

not

appear

 

to affect

 

the

cost-benefit

 

calculations

 

of opposition

actors

in the most

autocratic

 

states

sufficiently

 

to create

incentives

 

for

rioting.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

In

this

analysis,

 

 

the

interaction

 

term

between

 

the

presence

of

sanctions

 

and

Polity

score also attains statistical significance for all of

themodels,

suggesting a

positive effecton

the likelihood of riots.16Again,

the effect is strongest for import

and export sanctions and weakest

 

forfinancial sanctions, but the strengtheffects is

similar.17

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Ifdifferenttypes of sanctions aremore

likely to alter behavior

of different types

of regimes (Brooks 2002),

thisdifference does not appear

tobe a result of domestic

political

 

costs.

Under

 

sanctions,

as states

become

more

democratic,

 

they are

more

likely to experience

riots. This

finding is somewhat

surprising since less violent

formsof political

action are typically associated with democratic

societies. In times

of

external

 

stress,

such

as

sanctions,

 

democratic

 

publics

may

feel

that their

institu

tionalized

tools are insufficientforexpressing political

discontent.

 

 

 

This content downloaded from 92.242.58.12 on Mon, 8 Dec 2014 04:36:01 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

936 Journal of Conflict Resolution

 

 

 

 

 

Table

4

 

 

 

 

Negative Binomial Analysis: Political Riots, 1948-1999

 

Variable

 

(Std. Err.)

 

All Sanctions

Financial Sanctions

Import Sanctions

Export Sanctions

Lagged

dependent

variable

0.219***

 

0 217***

0.220***

0.218***

 

 

 

 

(0.035)

 

(0.035)

(0.034)

(0.033)

Polity

score

 

0.034***

 

0.041***

0.039***

0.038***

 

 

 

 

(0.010)

 

(0.010)

(0.010)

(0.010)

Polity

squared

 

-0.011***

 

-0.011***

-0.012***

-0.012***

 

 

 

 

(0.002)

 

(0.002)

(0.002)

(0.002)

Polity

x

sanctions

 

0.070***

 

0.061**

0.087***

0.088***

 

 

 

 

(0.022)

 

(0.027)

(0.029)

(0.028)

Presence

of sanctions

0.266

 

0.488**

0.454

0.323

 

 

 

 

(0.168)

 

(0.196)

(0.279)

(0.272)

Sanction

costs

 

0.001

 

-0.033

-0.043

-0.017

 

 

 

 

(0.025)

 

(0.025)

(0.039)

(0.035)

Regime

durability

 

-0.005**

 

-0.005*

-0.005**

-0.005**

 

 

 

 

(0.002)

 

(0.003)

(0.002)

(0.002)

ln(energy consumption)

0.018

 

0.013

0.019

0.024

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

(0.032)

 

(0.031)

(0.031)

(0.044)

ln(population)

 

0.450***

 

0.0452***

0.456***

0.454***

 

 

 

 

(0.054)

 

(0.055)

(0.054)

(0.053)

Intercept

 

?4.796***

 

-4.806***

?4.794***

-4.815***

 

 

 

 

(0.452)

 

(0.473)

(0.459)

(0.452)

Disperson

parameter

 

 

 

 

 

ln(a)

 

 

 

1,174***

 

1.176***

1.168***

1.169***

 

 

 

 

(0.100)

 

(0.102)

(0.101)

(0.099)

N

 

 

 

5,107

5,107

5,107

5,107

Wald

x2

 

 

289.76

 

292.16

317.56

327.25

Prob >

x"

 

0.00

 

0.00

0.00

0.00

Log-likelihood

 

-4,000.82

-4,016.66

-4,010.98

-4,014.62

Note:

Significance

levels:

* < 10%; ** < 5%;

*** <

\c,

 

 

Autocratic

governments do not face a

large increase in theprobability of politi

cal

costs

that

result

from

antigovernment

demonstrations

when

sanctions

are in

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

place.

As

result,

the decision

to resist

sanctions

is

less costly

in

these states.

When

predicted

events

were

generated

for violent

acts

of

antigovernment

behavior,

sanc

tioned autocracies

had

fewer

riots

than

nonsanctioned

autocracies.

 

 

Under

sanctions, the relationship between

regime

type and political

activity is

not

a

simple

one.

The

empirical

evidence

presented

here

supports

the

political

 

opportunity idea thatpatterns of violence

under sanctions differ by regime type.

This

pattern holds

for both nonviolent and

violent

actions?the

latter of which

should

be

more

costly

for

targeted

governments.

The

economic

deprivation

created

 

by

sanctionsmight

slightly increase the likelihood of antigovernmental activity?

both

 

violent and nonviolent.

That

increase,

however,

is much

more

pronounced

in

This content downloaded from 92.242.58.12 on Mon, 8 Dec 2014 04:36:01 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Allen /Costs of Economic Sanctions

937

Figure 5

Effect ofRegime Type on Predicted Number ofRiots

Figure 6

Marginal Effect of Sanctions on Antigovernment Riots

This content downloaded from 92.242.58.12 on Mon, 8 Dec 2014 04:36:01 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

938

 

Journal of Conflict Resolution

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

open

societies

 

than

in

closed

 

ones.

Sanctions

 

appear

 

to

encourage

publics

to

use

their

political

 

opportunities

 

for

antigovernment

 

 

action,

 

rather

than

create

them.

These

resultsmost

closely

support thePolitical Opportunity Hypothesis.

 

 

 

 

These

results also

help us

to understand why

democracies

are more

likely to

concede

 

to

sanctions

 

pressure.

 

Only

these

leaders

 

are

likely

to face

domestic

politi

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

cal

costs

because

of

domestic

 

antigovernment

 

activity.

Sanctions

 

are

not costly

to

autocratic

leaders

in thisway.

In fact, violent antigovernment activity is less likely

under

sanctions

in

these

 

states,

suggesting

 

that

sanctioned

 

autocrats

may

use

the

sanctions

as

an

excuse

for

further

curtailment

 

of

opposition

 

activities.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Discussion

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

One

possibility not considered

in the initial discussion

 

of thedomestic

political

effects of sanctions

is the idea that sanctions might

lead

to an

increase

in political

cohesion within the target state.Group

cohesion

can be

enhanced by conflictwith

an

external

group

 

(Simmel

 

1955; Coser

1956),

and

thismodel

of

in-group/out

group behavior

has been

applied

to state leaders throughgame-theoretic, principal

agent models

(Downs

and Rocke

1994;

Smith

1996).

 

International events

are

thought

to

spark

a

rise

 

in

popularity

for

the

government,

or

a

so-called

"rally

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

'round theflag" effect (Mueller

1970,

1973; Ostrom

and Job 1986). The

possibility

that sanctions will

cause

a rally effect ishypothesized

byGaltung

(1967).

 

 

 

 

The

imposition of sanctions enables

targeted leaders topinpoint a clear external

threat,which

can be used

as a focal point for a

leader tounify the state (Miyagawa

1992). Leaders

can also place

theblame

foreconomic

hardship on the sender state

rather than on

their own

economic policies,

leading

some to posit

the idea

that

rather than rally

'round the flag,

sanctioned

populations

might

rally against

the

enemy or sender state (Stein 2003).

 

 

 

create a rally is appealing. In the early

 

Anecdotally,

the idea

that sanctions will

1960s, Robert Hurwich,

 

the State Department's

 

officer overseeing Cuban

affairs,

noted that thedesired effectof the embargo on

theCuban

economy

"might trans

late itself into open

active opposition

to the regime"

(quoted

inKaplowitz

1998).

Instead,

during

the past

forty

years,

the U.S.

sanctions

 

have

been

used

as

a

rallying

point by theCuban

regime. Saddam Hussein

used the decade-long U.N.

sanctions

as a

scapegoat

for the economic

devastation wrought on

 

the Iraqi economy by his

own

excesses

and

penchant

 

for war-making.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

The

results presented here indicate that ifdomestic

populations are rallying that

does not curb theirdesire to take antigovernment action. These findings do not rule out the possibility of rallies in response to sanctions, but determining whether or not political rallying is also occurring is beyond the scope of thisarticle. Sanctions do appear to increase thedomestic political costs for targeted leaders, particularly

This content downloaded from 92.242.58.12 on Mon, 8 Dec 2014 04:36:01 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Allen /Costs of Economic Sanctions

939

in states in which

the political

opportunity exists

for antigovernment

action

to

potentially be effective.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Where

 

leaders

possess

strong

repressive

tools, sanctions

will

not

have

the

effect

of increasing thedomestic political

costs

these leaders face. If sanctions are going

to alter

the

behavior

 

of such

leaders,

the costs

must

come

from

outside

the targeted

state.

Rather

than

creating

sizeable

 

domestic

costs,

in

these

cases,

itmay

be

neces

 

sary

for

senders to create

international

economic

costs

that

are

larger

than

would

be

required in states where

accompanying

domestic

political

pressure

could

create

additional

leverage

to change

theproscribed policy.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Conclusion

Sanctioners often impose sanctions with the expectation (or perhaps simple

hope)

 

that sanctions will

lead to increased political

fragmentationwithin

the target.

This assumption suggests thatdomestic political

costs are an importantpredictor of

sanctions

outcomes,

but

the

 

linkage

 

has

not

been

clearly

understood.

 

From

this

analysis,

 

it is apparent

 

that

 

sanctions

can

lead

to an

increase

in mass

political

action, but that increase seems tobe

limited in autocratic

states.Only

in stateswith

some degree

of political openness

and opportunity do

sanctions

increase thewill

ingness

of

the public

 

to

take

antigovernment

 

action.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

The

empirical analysis presented here does not clearly support a simple relation

ship of economic

pain

to political

change. While

the presence

of

sanctions may

lead to an

increase inpolitical

activity, the impact ismitigated

by thepolitical

insti

tutions in the target state. Sanctions

do not provide

an

impetus for local opposition

actors

 

to take

action

against

their

leaders,

particularly

 

in

states

where

political

free

doms

are

limited.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

If sanctions are not creating domestic

political

costs for autocratic leaders, it is

imperative

for sanctions

senders

to find ways

 

to

create

external

 

international

costs

for autocrats

who

refuse

to

comply

with

sanctions

pressure.

Without

facing

some

political cost associated

with

sanctions, these leaders will

have

littleor no incentive

to alter

their behavior.

Freezing

the

personal

assets

of

leaders,

curtailing

travel,

and

limiting exposure

to the international community can focus the hardship of sanc

tions

more

directly

on

these

 

leaders

 

themselves.

This

may

be

necessary,

as

these

results suggest that sanctions themselves will

not

lead

to domestic

costs in these

states,

 

at

least

not via

political

 

pressure

from

the

general

 

public.

 

 

 

 

 

These

resultshelp

sortout and test thenumerous ad hoc explanations of thepoli

tical

consequences

of

sanctions

in the

target

state and

give

increased

leverage

over

the question

of when

sanctions will

be

useful

tools for bringing about political

change.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Just as significantly, this article

suggests

several

important avenues

for future

research.

The

most

obvious

and

important

 

extension

would

be

to explore

whether

This content downloaded from 92.242.58.12 on Mon, 8 Dec 2014 04:36:01 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

940 Journal of Conflict Resolution

or not thepolitical costs raised by this type of antigovernment behavior affect the

decisions

made

by

leaders

about whether

and

when

to

concede

to economic

sanc

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

tions. Does

antigovernment

activity have

any

impact

on

the actions

of targeted

gov

ernments? Punishment-based theories of coercion (and particularly of economic sanctions) suggest that they should, but empirical testingof this causal mechanism

has largely been absent.

Another interestingprospect, but one thatis challenging froma data point of view, would be todeterminewhether groups most negatively affected by sanctions are the

ones whose

antigovernment

 

behavior

 

increases.

Several

well-known

sanctions

 

cases,

such as South Africa

and Rhodesia,

 

suggest thepossibility thatgroups privileged by

sanctions (or at

least, those protected by

the sanctioned government) might

rally,

while

the groups

thatare hurt by

sanctionsmight respond with violence. A

cross

national studyof these dynamics would

add significantlytoour understanding of the

domestic political dynamics

incountries targetedby sanctions.

of the target state are

To

crafteffective sanctions policy,

thepolitical dynamics

a critical

element

of

the mechanisms

 

 

that underlie

sanctions

effectiveness.

 

Sanc

tions

response

is not

uniform

across

target

states.

The

expectation

that

sanctions

in

all target stateswill

lead to an outpouring ofmass

political action

thatwill,

in turn,

create

a

sense

of

duty on

the part

of

the targeted

government

is not

supported.

 

Dif

ferences

in response

are

largely

because

 

of

the

impact

that

sanctions

have

 

on

the

political

processes

within

these

states.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Efforts

to

implement

targeted

 

sanctions

may

improve

the

effectiveness

of

sanc

tions

against

autocratic

regimes.

While

comprehensive

 

sanctions

affect the

entire

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

targetedpopulation, targeted sanctions are directed toward theheart of the interests of those inpower. The sanctions levied against South Africa included general limita tionsnot only on tradebut also on the tradeof diamonds (which affected thepurses of thebusiness elite) as well as a ban on participation in internationalsportingcom petitions (whichwas viewed bywhite South Africans as a tragicpunishment).

Notes

1While.

signaling may

also be

an important function of sanctions,

senders

typically describe their

intentions in terms of

imposing costs of targets.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

2. For example, Marinov

(2005)

explores

the idea that sanctions may

also

be

imposed

to strengthen

the bargaining

position of the sender vis-?-vis

the target state. Senders may

use

the stick of

sanctions to

offer the carrot of

lifting the sanctions,

but even

under these circumstances,

domestic

politics

in the tar

get state are still likely to heighten the desirability

of having the sanctions

lifted.

 

 

 

 

efforts to

3. Rowe

(2001)

posits

that this increase

in support

resulted

from theRF

government's

make white economic

elites dependent

on the government.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

4. Sanctions

alone

did

not cause

this inflationary pressure.

Poor economic

policy

by

the Cedras

regime created

the economic

conditions

for inflation to rise, and

sanctions

heightened

the increase.

5. This concept was

originally advanced

by Eisinger

(1973)

to explain

urban violence

by city politi

cal structure.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

This content downloaded from 92.242.58.12 on Mon, 8 Dec 2014 04:36:01 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Allen

/Costs

of Economic

Sanctions

 

941

 

6. The

idea

of

institutions as

a moderating

variable

has

been

discussed

in the political-violence

literature, particularly

by Schock

(1996).

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

to control

 

 

 

7. Niblock

 

(2001)

also points

out

that the economic

power

of the government

goods

within

the sanctioned

state can

increase dependence

 

by the population

on

the regime, as government-run

rationing programs may

be

the only regular

source of essentials

available.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

8. This

echoes

Goemans's

 

(2000)

sentiments about wars

thatmay

hurt states but not

the leaders in

power.

In the case

of sanctions,

thedifference

in the interests facing

leaders and statesmay

be

even greater

since

leaders often control

 

lucrative smuggling networks. In these cases, not only

are

leaders not hurting as

much

under sanctions

as the average

citizen,

theymay

actually be profiting from the sanctions.

 

 

 

 

9. Of

 

course, the possibility

also

exists thatantigovernment activitymay

 

occur during a sanctions epi

sode

that is completely

unrelated, and I recognize that I am

taking a risk of comparing

some

apples

(unre

lated events)

to theoranges

(sanctions-related

actions)

that I am truly interested in.One

potential

extension

for this research would

be

tomachine-code

 

events

data

specifically

about

 

sanctions-related violence. As

these data

 

are not available

 

at present, I use

these data with

the belief

that they are a good

proxy.

 

 

 

10. Stata

also

allows

for both

cluster and

robust to be

specified, which

 

allows

for nonindependence

within

clusters of observations.

This

option was

specified for this analysis

 

to furthercompensate

for corre

lation between

observations.

Results

produced by -xtnbreg- with

random

effects

 

are

similar

to those

included here. For ease

of

 

interpretation, the simplermodel

is presented. The

 

results produced

by

-xtnbreg

with

fixed effects are

slightly different,but

thismay

be

an artifact resulting from lack of variation

of the

reduction

 

in countries

included

in the analysis. Losing

twenty countries makes

thismodel

 

unappealing.

 

 

11. This

graph

and

the others presented

in this article were

 

created

using Clarify

(King, Tomz,

and

Wittenberg

2000).

In this case,

with

the other variables

held

at theirmean

 

 

(ormedian,

ifmore

appropri

ate),

the two polity

termswere

allowed

to vary together, and expected

counts were estimated.

 

 

 

 

12. Because

 

the size

and

the direction

of

the coefficients

for all

types of sanctions

are

 

similar, these

marginal

 

effects were

calculated

for themodel

with

the indicator for all

sanctions.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

13.As

with

the predicted

numbers

of events, Figure 6 was

 

generated

 

using

Clarify. First, predicted

numbers

 

of

events

(and

associated

confidence

intervals) were

 

calculated

 

varying

 

only

the Polity

and

Polity

Squared

variables,

 

leaving

other predictors

constant at theirmeans

 

 

(ormedians).

 

To

examine

the

impact of sanctions

on

these predictions,

the second

set of predictions was

 

generated

by setting the sanc

tions variable

to

1 and

varying

thepolity variables

as well

as

the interaction term.

hardship are the trig

 

14. For

this type of explanation,

perceptions

of deprivation

rather than absolute

gers

forpolitical

action.

ratios were

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

results were

 

15. These

incidence

created

using

the inclusive

sanctions

 

variable.

 

Similar

obtained

using

each

sanctions

variable

type.

 

 

 

 

an

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

termwith

 

 

 

 

 

 

16. This

effect

is constrained

to be

linear. Adding

additional

interaction

 

sanctions

and

the squared

polity term leads

to extensive multicollinearity.

To

examine

the robustness

of the curvilinear

effect, I also

split the sample

and found strong statistical significance

forboth polity

 

terms.

 

 

 

 

 

17. Incidence-rate

ratios

for the riots variable

also

appear

inTable

3

for comparison

of substantive

impact across

variables

of differing scales.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

References

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Allen,

Susan Hannah.

2005.

The

determinants

of economic

sanctions

success

and

failure. International

 

Interactions

31:117-38.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

-.

 

 

2008.

Economic

 

sanctions

and political

constraints. Foreign

Policy

Analysis

4:255-74.

 

 

 

Baldwin,

 

David.

1985. Economic

statecraft. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University

Press.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Banks,

Arthur.

2003.

Cross-national

time-series

 

archive.

Binghamton,

 

NY:

Databanks

 

International

[distributor].

This content downloaded from 92.242.58.12 on Mon, 8 Dec 2014 04:36:01 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

-.

-.

942

Journal of Conflict

Resolution

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Blanchard,

 

Jean-Marc,

and Norrin

Ripsman.

 

1999/2000. Asking

the right question: When

 

do

economic

sanctions work best? Security Studies

9:219-53.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Bond, Doug,

 

J.Craig

Jenkins, Charles

L. Taylor,

and Kurt

Schock.

1997. Mapping

 

mass

political

con

flict and

civil

society. Journal

of Conflict Resolution

41:553-79.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Brambor,

Thomas, William

Roberts

Clark,

and Matt

Golder.

2006.

Understanding

 

interaction models:

Improving

empirical

 

analysis. Political

Analysis

14:63-82.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Brooks,

 

Risa.

2002.

Sanctions

 

and

regime

type:What

 

works,

and when?

Security

Studies

11:1-50.

 

 

Carter, April.

1971. Direct

action

and

liberal democracy.

New

York: Harper.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Cortright, David,

and George

 

Lopez,

 

eds. 2000. The sanctions decade:

 

Assessing

UN

strategies

in the

1990s.

Boulder,

CO:

 

Lynne Rienner.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Cortright, David,

George

Lopez,

and Elizabeth

Rogers.

2002.

Targeted

 

financial

sanctions:

Smart

sanc

tions

that do

work.

 

In Smart Sanctions,

ed. David

Cortright

and George

Lopez.

 

Lanham,

MD:

Rowman & Littlefield, 23-40.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Coser,

Lewis.

1956. The

function of social

 

conflict.New

York:

Free Press.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Crawford,

Neta.

1999. Trump

card or theater? InHow

sanctions

work: Lessons

from

South Africa,

ed.

Neta

Crawford

and Audie

 

Klotz. New

York:

St.Martin's,

 

3-24.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Dashti-Gibson,

Jalen, Patricia

Davis,

 

and Benjamin

Radcliff.

1997. On

the determinants

of

the success

of economic

sanctions: An

empirical

analysis. American

Journal

of Political

Science

 

41:608-18.

 

 

Dollard,

J.,Leonard

 

Doob,

Neal Miller,

O. Mowrer,

 

and Robert

Sears.

1971. Frustration

and aggression:

Definitions. InWhen

men

 

revolt?And

why, ed. James C. Davies.

New

 

York:

Free

Press,

173-180.

 

Douhet,

 

Guilio.

1921.

Command

of

the air,

trans. Dino

Ferrari. Washington,

DC:

Office

of Air

Force

History.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Downs,

 

George,

and David

Rocke.

 

1994. Conflict,

agency,

and gambling

for resurrection: The

principal

agent problem goes

 

towar. American

Journal

ofPolitical

Science

38:362-80.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Drury,

 

A.

 

Cooper.

 

1998.

Revisiting

 

economic

 

sanctions

reconsidered.

Journal

 

of Peace

Research

35:497-509.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Edgar,

Robert

E.

1990.

Sanctioning

apartheid.

Trenton, NJ: Africa World

 

Press.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Eisinger,

Peter.

1973. The

conditions

of protest behavior

inAmerican

cities. American

Political Science

Review

67:11-28.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Freedman,

Lawrence,

ed.

1998. Strategic

 

coercion:

Concepts

and

cases. New

York:

Oxford

University

Press.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Galtung,

Johan.

1967. On

the effects of international economic

sanctions with

examples

 

from the case

of

Rhodesia.

World

Politics

 

19:378-416.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Gelpi,

 

Christopher.

 

1997.

Democratic

diversions:

Governmental

 

structure and

the externalization

of

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

domestic

conflict. Journal

of Conflict Resolution

 

41:255-82.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Gibbons,

Elizabeth.

 

1999.

Sanctions

 

inHaiti:

Human

rights and

democracy

under

assault. New

York:

Praeger.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

causes

of war

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Goemans,

Hein.

2000.

War

and punishment:

The

termination and

theFirst World

War.

Princeton, NJ: Princeton

University

Press.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Greene, William.

 

1997. Econometric

 

analysis.

3rd ed. Upper

Saddle

River, NJ: Prentice Hall.

 

 

 

Gurr, Ted

R.

1970. Why men

 

rebel. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University

Press.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

1986. The

 

political

 

origins

 

of

state violence

and

 

terror:A

theoretical

analysis.

In Government

violence

and

repression: An agenda for research,

ed. Michael

 

Stohl

and George

Lopez.

Westport,

CT: Greenwood.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

1989. Protest

and

rebellion

 

in the 1960s: The United

States

inworld

perspective.

In Violence

in

America,

ed. T. R. Gurr. Newbury

Park, CA:

Sage,

572-625.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Hart, Robert

A.,

Jr.2000.

Democracy

 

and

the successful

use

of economic

sanctions. Political

Research

Quarterly

53:267-84.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Hibbs,

 

Douglas.

1973. Mass

political

violence. New

York:

 

JohnWiley

&

 

Sons.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

This content downloaded from 92.242.58.12 on Mon, 8 Dec 2014 04:36:01 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Allen

 

/Costs

of Economic

Sanctions

 

943

Hufbauer,

Gary,

JeffreySchott, and Kimberly

Elliott. 1990. Economic

 

sanctions

revisited: Supplemental

case histories. Washington,

DC:

 

 

Institute for International Economics.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Huntington,

Samuel.

1968. The

thirdwave:

 

Democratization

in the late twentieth century. Norman,

OK:

University

of Oklahoma

Press.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Jackman, Robert.

 

1973. On

the relation of economic

development

 

to democratic

performance. American

Journal

ofPolitical

Science

17:611-21.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Jenkins, J.Craig,

 

and Kurt Schock.

 

1992. Global

structures and political

processes

in the study of domes

tic political

conflict. Annual Review

of Sociology

18:161-85.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Jentleson, Bruce.

 

2000. Economic

 

sanctions

and post-Cold War

conflict. In International

conflict resolu

tion after

theCold

War,

ed. Paul

Stern

and Daniel

Druckman. Washington,

DC:

National

Academy

Press,

123-177.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Jing,Chao, William

Kaempfer,

and Anton

D.

Lowenberg.

2003.

 

Instrument choice

and the effectiveness

of international sanctions: A

simultaneous equations approach. Journal ofPeace

Research

 

40:519-35.

Kaplowitz,

 

Donna.

1998. Anatomy

 

of a failed

embargo:

U.S.

 

sanctions

against

Cuba.

 

Boulder,

CO:

Lynne Rienner.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

King,

Gary.

 

1989. Event

count models

 

for

international

relations: Generalizations

and

 

applications.

International

 

Studies

Quarterly

 

33:123-47.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

King,

Gary, Michael

 

Tomz,

and

 

Jason Wittenberg.

2000.

Making

 

the most

of

statistical

analyses:

Improving

interpretation and presentation. American

Journal

 

ofPolitical

 

Science

44 (2): 341-55.

 

Kirshner,

Jonathan.

1997. The microfoundations

of economic

sanctions. Security Studies

6:32-64.

 

 

-.

2002.

Economic

sanctions:

 

State

of the art. Security

Studies

11:160-79.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Krain,

Matthew.

 

2000.

Repression

 

and

 

accommodation

in post-revolutionary

 

states. New

York:

St.Martin's.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Lektzian,

David,

 

and Christopher

Sprecher.

2007.

Sanctions,

signals,

and militarized

conflict. American

Journal

ofPolitical

Science

51:415-31.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Liao,

Tim

Futing.

1994.

Interpreting probability

models:

Logit,

probit,

and

other

generalized

 

linear

models.

Thousand

Oaks,

CA:

Sage.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Lichbach,

Mark,

 

and Ted

Robert Gurr.

1981. The

conflict process: A

 

formal model.

Journal

of Conflict

Resolution

25:3-29.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Licht,

Sonja.

1995. The

use

of

sanctions

 

in former Yugoslavia:

 

Can

 

they assist

in conflict resolution?

In Economic

 

sanctions:

Panacea

 

or peacebuilding

in a post-Cold

War

world?

ed. David

Cortright

and George

Lopez.

Boulder,

CO: Westview.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Lindsay,

James.

1986. Trade

sanctions

as

policy

instruments: A

re-examination.

International

Studies

Quarterly 30 (2): 153-73.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Lopez,

George

A.

1999.

Economic

 

 

sanctions and

failed

states: Too

 

little, too

late, and

sometimes too

much?

 

Presented

at thePurdue

Conference

on Failed

States, La

Fayette,

IN,March.

 

 

 

 

 

 

Lopez,

George

A.,

and David

Cortright.

 

1995.

Economic

sanctions

 

in contemporary

global

relations.

In Economic

 

sanctions:

Panacea

 

or peacebuilding

 

in a post-Cold

War

world?

ed. David

Cortright

and George

Lopez.

Boulder,

CO: Westview.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

cases

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Losman,

Donald.

 

1979.

International

economic

sanctions:

The

 

of Cuba,

Israel,

and

Rhodesia.

Albuquerque:

 

University

ofNew

Mexico

 

Press.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Mahoney-Norris,

 

Kathleen.

 

2000.

 

Political

repression: Threat,

 

perception,

and

transnational

solidarity

groups.

In Paths

 

to state

repression,

ed. Christian

Davenport.

 

Lanham,

 

MD:

Rowman

 

&

Littlefield,

71-108.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Mansfield,

 

Edward

D.,

and

Jack Snyder.

 

1995. Democratization

 

 

and

 

the danger

of war.

 

International

Security 20 (1): 5-38.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Marinov,

Nikolay.

2005.

Do

sanctions

destabilize

country

leaders?

American

Journal

of Political

Science

49:564-76.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Marshall,

Monty

G.,

and Keith

Jaggers.

2006.

Polity

IV project:

Political

regime

characteristics

and

transitions,

 

1800-2006.

Dataset

 

users'

manual.

College

Park, MD:

 

Center for Systemic

Peace.

 

 

This content downloaded from 92.242.58.12 on Mon, 8 Dec 2014 04:36:01 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

944

Journal of Conflict

Resolution

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Miyagawa,

Makio.

 

1992. Do

 

economic

sanctions

work?

New

York:

St.Martin's.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Morgan,

T. Cliff,

and Valerie

 

Schwebach.

1996. Economic

sanctions

as an

instrument of foreign policy:

The

role of domestic

politics.

International

Interactions

21:247-63.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Mueller,

 

John.

1970.

Presidential

 

popularity

from Johnson

to Truman.

American

Political

 

Science

Review

63:1197-212.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

-.

 

 

1973. War,

presidents,

and public

opinion. New

York: Wiley.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

M?ller,

 

Edward,

and

Erich

Weede.

 

 

1990.

Cross-national

variation

 

in political

violence.

 

Journal

of

Conflict Resolution

34:624-51.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Niblock,

Tim.

 

2001.

Pariah

 

states

and

sanctions

in theMiddle

 

East:

 

Iraq,

Libya,

Sudan.

Boulder,

CO:

Lynne

Rienner.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Nossal,

Kim

Richard.

1989.

International

sanctions

as

international punishment.

International

Organiza

tion43

(2):

 

301

-22.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Ostrom,

Charles,

and Brian

 

Job.

1986. The

president

and the political

use

of force. American

Political

Science Review 80:541-63.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Pape,

Robert.

 

1996. Bombing

to win: Air power

and

coercion

in war.

Ithaca, NY:

Cornell

University

Press.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Renwick,

 

Robin.

1981. Economic

sanctions. London:

Croom

Helm.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Rowe,

David.

2001. Manipulating

 

themarket. Ann Arbor, MI:

University

ofMichigan

 

Press.

 

 

 

 

 

Schock,

Kurt.

 

1996. A

conjunctural

model

of political

conflict: The

impact of political

opportunities

on

the

relationship

between

economic

inequality

and

violent

political

 

conflict. Journal

 

of Conflict

Resolution

 

40(1):

98-133.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Seiden,

Zachary.

1999. Economic

 

sanctions

 

as

instruments of American

foreign

policy. Westport,

CT:

Praeger.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Simmel,

Georg.

 

1955. Conflict, trans.Kurt H. Wolff.

Glencoe,

IL: Free

Press.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Simons,

Geoffrey.

1999.

Imposing

economic

 

sanctions:

Legal

remedy or genocidal

tool? London:

Pluto.

Singer,

J.David,

and Melvin

 

Small.

1996. National

material

capabilities

data,

1816-1985.

 

Ann

Arbor,

MI:

Inter-university Consortium

forPolitical

and Social

Research

 

[distributor].

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Smith, Alastair.

1996.

The

 

success

and

use

 

of

economic

sanctions.

International Interactions

21

(3):

229-45.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Snyder,

 

Jack.

 

2000. From

 

voting

to violence:

Democratization

 

and

nationalist

conflict. New

 

York:

Norton.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Stein, Elizabeth.

2003.

Embargoes

and the "rally-against-the-enemy

effect": Sustaining

pariah

leaders.

Presented

at the annual meeting

of theMidwest

Political

Science

Association,

 

Chicago,

 

IL, April.

 

Tarrow,

 

Sidney.

 

1994.

Power

 

in movement:

Social

movements,

collective

action,

 

and

politics.

New

 

York: Cambridge

University

Press.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Tilly,

Charles.

 

1978. From

mobilization

to revolution. Reading,

MA:

 

Addison Wesley.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Woodward,

Susan.

1995. The

use

of

sanctions in formerYugoslavia:

 

Misunderstanding

 

political

 

realities.

InEconomic

sanctions: Panacea

 

or peacebuilding

ina post-Cold

War

world?

ed. David

 

Cortright and

George

Lopez.

Boulder,

 

CO: Westview.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Zorn,

Christopher

J. Forthcoming.

Event

count models

for political

 

science:

Theory

and

 

application.

Cambridge:

Cambridge

 

University

Press.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

This content downloaded from 92.242.58.12 on Mon, 8 Dec 2014 04:36:01 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Соседние файлы в предмете [НЕСОРТИРОВАННОЕ]