
- •Intended Audience
- •1.1 Financing the Firm
- •1.2Public and Private Sources of Capital
- •1.3The Environment forRaising Capital in the United States
- •Investment Banks
- •1.4Raising Capital in International Markets
- •1.5MajorFinancial Markets outside the United States
- •1.6Trends in Raising Capital
- •Innovative Instruments
- •2.1Bank Loans
- •2.2Leases
- •2.3Commercial Paper
- •2.4Corporate Bonds
- •2.5More Exotic Securities
- •2.6Raising Debt Capital in the Euromarkets
- •2.7Primary and Secondary Markets forDebt
- •2.8Bond Prices, Yields to Maturity, and Bond Market Conventions
- •2.9Summary and Conclusions
- •3.1Types of Equity Securities
- •Volume of Financing with Different Equity Instruments
- •3.2Who Owns u.S. Equities?
- •3.3The Globalization of Equity Markets
- •3.4Secondary Markets forEquity
- •International Secondary Markets for Equity
- •3.5Equity Market Informational Efficiency and Capital Allocation
- •3.7The Decision to Issue Shares Publicly
- •3.8Stock Returns Associated with ipOs of Common Equity
- •Ipo Underpricing of u.S. Stocks
- •4.1Portfolio Weights
- •4.2Portfolio Returns
- •4.3Expected Portfolio Returns
- •4.4Variances and Standard Deviations
- •4.5Covariances and Correlations
- •4.6Variances of Portfolios and Covariances between Portfolios
- •Variances for Two-Stock Portfolios
- •4.7The Mean-Standard Deviation Diagram
- •4.8Interpreting the Covariance as a Marginal Variance
- •Increasing a Stock Position Financed by Reducing orSelling Short the Position in
- •Increasing a Stock Position Financed by Reducing orShorting a Position in a
- •4.9Finding the Minimum Variance Portfolio
- •Identifying the Minimum Variance Portfolio of Two Stocks
- •Identifying the Minimum Variance Portfolio of Many Stocks
- •Investment Applications of Mean-Variance Analysis and the capm
- •5.2The Essentials of Mean-Variance Analysis
- •5.3The Efficient Frontierand Two-Fund Separation
- •5.4The Tangency Portfolio and Optimal Investment
- •Identification of the Tangency Portfolio
- •5.5Finding the Efficient Frontierof Risky Assets
- •5.6How Useful Is Mean-Variance Analysis forFinding
- •5.8The Capital Asset Pricing Model
- •Implications for Optimal Investment
- •5.9Estimating Betas, Risk-Free Returns, Risk Premiums,
- •Improving the Beta Estimated from Regression
- •Identifying the Market Portfolio
- •5.10Empirical Tests of the Capital Asset Pricing Model
- •Is the Value-Weighted Market Index Mean-Variance Efficient?
- •Interpreting the capm’s Empirical Shortcomings
- •5.11 Summary and Conclusions
- •6.1The Market Model:The First FactorModel
- •6.2The Principle of Diversification
- •Insurance Analogies to Factor Risk and Firm-Specific Risk
- •6.3MultifactorModels
- •Interpreting Common Factors
- •6.5FactorBetas
- •6.6Using FactorModels to Compute Covariances and Variances
- •6.7FactorModels and Tracking Portfolios
- •6.8Pure FactorPortfolios
- •6.9Tracking and Arbitrage
- •6.10No Arbitrage and Pricing: The Arbitrage Pricing Theory
- •Verifying the Existence of Arbitrage
- •Violations of the aptEquation fora Small Set of Stocks Do Not Imply Arbitrage.
- •Violations of the aptEquation by Large Numbers of Stocks Imply Arbitrage.
- •6.11Estimating FactorRisk Premiums and FactorBetas
- •6.12Empirical Tests of the Arbitrage Pricing Theory
- •6.13 Summary and Conclusions
- •7.1Examples of Derivatives
- •7.2The Basics of Derivatives Pricing
- •7.3Binomial Pricing Models
- •7.4Multiperiod Binomial Valuation
- •7.5Valuation Techniques in the Financial Services Industry
- •7.6Market Frictions and Lessons from the Fate of Long-Term
- •7.7Summary and Conclusions
- •8.1ADescription of Options and Options Markets
- •8.2Option Expiration
- •8.3Put-Call Parity
- •Insured Portfolio
- •8.4Binomial Valuation of European Options
- •8.5Binomial Valuation of American Options
- •Valuing American Options on Dividend-Paying Stocks
- •8.6Black-Scholes Valuation
- •8.7Estimating Volatility
- •Volatility
- •8.8Black-Scholes Price Sensitivity to Stock Price, Volatility,
- •Interest Rates, and Expiration Time
- •8.9Valuing Options on More Complex Assets
- •Implied volatility
- •8.11 Summary and Conclusions
- •9.1 Cash Flows ofReal Assets
- •9.2Using Discount Rates to Obtain Present Values
- •Value Additivity and Present Values of Cash Flow Streams
- •Inflation
- •9.3Summary and Conclusions
- •10.1Cash Flows
- •10.2Net Present Value
- •Implications of Value Additivity When Evaluating Mutually Exclusive Projects.
- •10.3Economic Value Added (eva)
- •10.5Evaluating Real Investments with the Internal Rate of Return
- •Intuition for the irrMethod
- •10.7 Summary and Conclusions
- •10A.1Term Structure Varieties
- •10A.2Spot Rates, Annuity Rates, and ParRates
- •11.1Tracking Portfolios and Real Asset Valuation
- •Implementing the Tracking Portfolio Approach
- •11.2The Risk-Adjusted Discount Rate Method
- •11.3The Effect of Leverage on Comparisons
- •11.4Implementing the Risk-Adjusted Discount Rate Formula with
- •11.5Pitfalls in Using the Comparison Method
- •11.6Estimating Beta from Scenarios: The Certainty Equivalent Method
- •Identifying the Certainty Equivalent from Models of Risk and Return
- •11.7Obtaining Certainty Equivalents with Risk-Free Scenarios
- •Implementing the Risk-Free Scenario Method in a Multiperiod Setting
- •11.8Computing Certainty Equivalents from Prices in Financial Markets
- •11.9Summary and Conclusions
- •11A.1Estimation Errorand Denominator-Based Biases in Present Value
- •11A.2Geometric versus Arithmetic Means and the Compounding-Based Bias
- •12.2Valuing Strategic Options with the Real Options Methodology
- •Valuing a Mine with No Strategic Options
- •Valuing a Mine with an Abandonment Option
- •Valuing Vacant Land
- •Valuing the Option to Delay the Start of a Manufacturing Project
- •Valuing the Option to Expand Capacity
- •Valuing Flexibility in Production Technology: The Advantage of Being Different
- •12.3The Ratio Comparison Approach
- •12.4The Competitive Analysis Approach
- •12.5When to Use the Different Approaches
- •Valuing Asset Classes versus Specific Assets
- •12.6Summary and Conclusions
- •13.1Corporate Taxes and the Evaluation of Equity-Financed
- •Identifying the Unlevered Cost of Capital
- •13.2The Adjusted Present Value Method
- •Valuing a Business with the wacc Method When a Debt Tax Shield Exists
- •Investments
- •IsWrong
- •Valuing Cash Flow to Equity Holders
- •13.5Summary and Conclusions
- •14.1The Modigliani-MillerTheorem
- •IsFalse
- •14.2How an Individual InvestorCan “Undo” a Firm’s Capital
- •14.3How Risky Debt Affects the Modigliani-MillerTheorem
- •14.4How Corporate Taxes Affect the Capital Structure Choice
- •14.6Taxes and Preferred Stock
- •14.7Taxes and Municipal Bonds
- •14.8The Effect of Inflation on the Tax Gain from Leverage
- •14.10Are There Tax Advantages to Leasing?
- •14.11Summary and Conclusions
- •15.1How Much of u.S. Corporate Earnings Is Distributed to Shareholders?Aggregate Share Repurchases and Dividends
- •15.2Distribution Policy in Frictionless Markets
- •15.3The Effect of Taxes and Transaction Costs on Distribution Policy
- •15.4How Dividend Policy Affects Expected Stock Returns
- •15.5How Dividend Taxes Affect Financing and Investment Choices
- •15.6Personal Taxes, Payout Policy, and Capital Structure
- •15.7Summary and Conclusions
- •16.1Bankruptcy
- •16.3How Chapter11 Bankruptcy Mitigates Debt Holder–Equity HolderIncentive Problems
- •16.4How Can Firms Minimize Debt Holder–Equity Holder
- •Incentive Problems?
- •17.1The StakeholderTheory of Capital Structure
- •17.2The Benefits of Financial Distress with Committed Stakeholders
- •17.3Capital Structure and Competitive Strategy
- •17.4Dynamic Capital Structure Considerations
- •17.6 Summary and Conclusions
- •18.1The Separation of Ownership and Control
- •18.2Management Shareholdings and Market Value
- •18.3How Management Control Distorts Investment Decisions
- •18.4Capital Structure and Managerial Control
- •Investment Strategy?
- •18.5Executive Compensation
- •Is Executive Pay Closely Tied to Performance?
- •Is Executive Compensation Tied to Relative Performance?
- •19.1Management Incentives When Managers Have BetterInformation
- •19.2Earnings Manipulation
- •Incentives to Increase or Decrease Accounting Earnings
- •19.4The Information Content of Dividend and Share Repurchase
- •19.5The Information Content of the Debt-Equity Choice
- •19.6Empirical Evidence
- •19.7Summary and Conclusions
- •20.1AHistory of Mergers and Acquisitions
- •20.2Types of Mergers and Acquisitions
- •20.3 Recent Trends in TakeoverActivity
- •20.4Sources of TakeoverGains
- •Is an Acquisition Required to Realize Tax Gains, Operating Synergies,
- •Incentive Gains, or Diversification?
- •20.5The Disadvantages of Mergers and Acquisitions
- •20.7Empirical Evidence on the Gains from Leveraged Buyouts (lbOs)
- •20.8 Valuing Acquisitions
- •Valuing Synergies
- •20.9Financing Acquisitions
- •Information Effects from the Financing of a Merger or an Acquisition
- •20.10Bidding Strategies in Hostile Takeovers
- •20.11Management Defenses
- •20.12Summary and Conclusions
- •21.1Risk Management and the Modigliani-MillerTheorem
- •Implications of the Modigliani-Miller Theorem for Hedging
- •21.2Why Do Firms Hedge?
- •21.4How Should Companies Organize TheirHedging Activities?
- •21.8Foreign Exchange Risk Management
- •Indonesia
- •21.9Which Firms Hedge? The Empirical Evidence
- •21.10Summary and Conclusions
- •22.1Measuring Risk Exposure
- •Volatility as a Measure of Risk Exposure
- •Value at Risk as a Measure of Risk Exposure
- •22.2Hedging Short-Term Commitments with Maturity-Matched
- •Value at
- •22.3Hedging Short-Term Commitments with Maturity-Matched
- •22.4Hedging and Convenience Yields
- •22.5Hedging Long-Dated Commitments with Short-Maturing FuturesorForward Contracts
- •Intuition for Hedging with a Maturity Mismatch in the Presence of a Constant Convenience Yield
- •22.6Hedging with Swaps
- •22.7Hedging with Options
- •22.8Factor-Based Hedging
- •Instruments
- •22.10Minimum Variance Portfolios and Mean-Variance Analysis
- •22.11Summary and Conclusions
- •23Risk Management
- •23.2Duration
- •23.4Immunization
- •Immunization Using dv01
- •Immunization and Large Changes in Interest Rates
- •23.5Convexity
- •23.6Interest Rate Hedging When the Term Structure Is Not Flat
- •23.7Summary and Conclusions
- •Interest Rate
- •Interest Rate
5.11 Summary and Conclusions
This chapter analyzed various features of the mean-standard deviation diagram, developed a condition for de-riving optimal portfolios, and showed that this conditionhas important implications for valuing financial assets. Thechapter also showed that the beta used in this valuation re-lation, the relation between risk and expected return, is anempty concept unless it is possible to identify the tangencyportfolio. The Capital Asset Pricing Model is a theory thatidentifies the tangency portfolio as the market portfolio,making it a powerful tool for valuing financial assets. Aslater chapters will illustrate, it also is useful for valuing realassets.
Valuation plays a major role in corporate finance. PartIII will discuss that when firms evaluate capital investmentprojects, they need to come up with some estimate of theproject’s required rate of return. Moreover, valuation oftenplays a key role in determining how corporations financetheir new investments. Many firms are reluctant to issueequity when they believe their equity is undervalued. Tovalue their own equity, they need an estimate of the ex-pected rate of return on their stock; the Capital Asset Pric-ing Model is currently one of the most popular methodsused to determine this.
The empirical tests of the CAPM contradict its predic-tions. Indeed, the most recent evidence fails to find a posi-tive relation between the CAPM beta and average rates ofreturn on stocks from 1960 to 1990, finding instead thatstock characteristics, like firm size and market-to-bookratios, provide very good predictions of a stock’s return.Does this mean that the CAPM is a useless theory?
One response to the empirical rejection of the CAPM isthat there are additional aspects of risk not captured by themarket proxies used in the CAPM tests. If this is the case,then the CAPM should be used, but augmented with addi-tional factors that capture those aspects of risk. Chapter 6,which discusses multifactor models, considers this possi-bility. The other possibility is that the model is fundamen-tally unsound and that investors do not act nearly as ration-
ally as the theory suggests. If this is the case, however, in-vestors should find beta estimates even more valuable be-cause they can be used to construct portfolios that have rel-atively low risk without giving up anything in the way ofexpected return.
This chapter provides a unique treatment of the CAPMin its concentration on the more general proposition thatthe CAPM “works” as a useful financial tool if its marketproxy is a mean-variance efficient portfolio and does notwork if the proxy is a dominated portfolio. The empiricalevidence to date has suggested that the proxies used for theCAPM appear to be dominated. This does not preclude thepossibility that some modification of the proxy may ulti-mately prove to be useful. As you will see in Chapter 6, re-search along these lines currently appears to be makinggreat strides.
We also should stress that testing the CAPM requiresexamining data in the fairly distant past, to a period prior towhen Wall Street professionals, portfolio managers, andcorporations used the CAPM. However, corporations thatare interested in valuing either investment projects or theirown stocks have no interest in the historical relevance ofthe CAPM; they are interested only in whether the modelprovides good current estimates of required rates of return.As economists, we like to think that investors act as if theyare trained in the nuances of modern portfolio theory eventhough beta was a relatively unknown Greek letter to theWall Street of the 1960s. As educators, however, we like tobelieve that we do make a difference and that our teachingand research has made a difference. Given those beliefs,we at least want to entertain the possibility that current re-quired rates of return reflect the type of risk suggested bythe CAPM, even if rates of return did not reflect this typeof risk in the past. Some evidence of this is that the size ef-fect has greatly diminished, if it has not disappeared en-tirely, since the early 1980s, when practitioners began tofocus on the academic research in this subject. The same istrue of the market-to-book effect.
Key Concepts
Result 5.1:All portfolios on the mean-varianceResult 5.3:The ratio of the risk premium of every
efficient frontier can be formed as astock and portfolio to its covariance with
weighted average of any two portfoliosthe tangency portfolio is constant; that is,
(or funds) on the efficient frontier.denoting the return of the tangency
˜
Result 5.2:Under the assumptions of mean-varianceportfolio as R
T
analysis, and assuming the existence of a
rr
if
risk-free asset, all investors will select
cov(˜, R˜)
r
portfolios on the capital market line.iT
is identical for all stocks.
-
Grinblatt
360 Titman: FinancialII. Valuing Financial Assets
5. Mean
360 Variance Analysis© The McGraw
360 HillMarkets and Corporate
and the Capital Asset
Companies, 2002
Strategy, Second Edition
Pricing Model
170Part IIValuing Financial Assets
Result 5.4:The beta of a portfolio is a portfolio-Result 5.8:Betas estimated from standard regression
weighted average of the betas of itspackages may not provide the best
individual securities; that isestimates of a stock’s true beta. Better
beta estimates can be obtained by taking
N
into account the lead-lag effect in stock
x
p iireturns and the fact that relatively high
i 1
beta estimates tend to be overestimates
whereand relatively low beta estimates tend to
be underestimates.
cov(˜, R˜)
r
iT
Result 5.9:Testing the CAPM may be problematic
ivar(R˜)
Tbecause the market portfolio is notResult 5.5:If a stock and its tracking portfolio havedirectly observable. Applications of the
the same marginal variancewith respecttheories use various proxies for the
to the tangency portfolio, then the stockmarket. Although the results of empirical
and its tracking portfolio must have thetests of the CAPM that use these proxies
same expected return.cannot be considered conclusive, they
provide valuable insights about theResult 5.6:Under the assumptions of the CAPM, and
appropriateness of the theory as
if a risk-free asset exists, the market
implemented with the specific proxies
portfolio is the tangency portfolio and, by
used in the test.
equation (5.4), the expected returns of
financial assets are determined byResult 5.10:Research using historical data indicates
that cross-sectional differences in stock
rr (Rr)
fMf(5.5)returns are related to three characteristics:
where Ris the mean return of the marketmarket capitalization, market-to-book
M
portfolio, and is the beta computedratios, and momentum. Controlling for
against the return of the market portfolio.these factors, these studies find no relation
between the CAPM beta and returns overResult 5.7:Under the assumptions of the CAPM, if a
the historical time periods studied.
risk-free asset exists, every investor should
optimally hold a combination of the
market portfolio and a risk-free asset.
Key Terms
beta147 |
|
market portfolio152 |
|
Bloomberg adjustment157 |
|
market-to-book ratio158 |
|
Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) |
151 |
mean-variance efficient portfolios |
133 |
capital market line (CML)138 |
|
momentum158 |
|
cost of capital132 |
|
risk premium140 |
|
cross-sectional regression161 |
|
securities market line147 |
|
dominated portfolios134 |
|
self-financing143 |
|
efficient frontier135 |
|
tangency portfolio138 |
|
excess returns158 |
|
time-series regression160 |
|
feasible set133 |
|
track149 |
|
frictionless markets135 |
|
tracking portfolio149 |
|
homogeneous beliefs151 |
|
two-fund separation136 |
|
human capital167 |
|
value-weighted portfolio152 |
|
market capitalization152 |
|
|
|
Grinblatt |
II. Valuing Financial Assets |
5.
Mean |
©
The McGraw |
Markets and Corporate |
|
and the Capital Asset |
Companies, 2002 |
Strategy, Second Edition |
|
Pricing Model |
|
-
Chapter 5
Mean-Variance Analysis and the Capital Asset Pricing Model
171
Exercises
5.1.Here are some general questions and instructions tob.Then compute the beta of an equally weighted
test your understanding of the mean standardportfolio of the three stocks.
deviation diagram.5.8.Using the fact that the hyperbolic boundary of the
a.Draw a mean-standard deviation diagram tofeasible set of the three stocks is generated by any
illustrate combinations of a risky asset and thetwo portfolios:
risk-free asset.a.Find the boundary portfolio that is uncorrelated
b.Extend this concept to a diagram of the risk-freewith the tangency portfolio in exercise 5.2.
asset and all possible risky portfolios.b.What is the covariance with the tangency
c.Why does one line, the capital market line,portfolio of all inefficient portfolios that have
dominate all other possible portfoliothe same mean return as the portfolio found in
combinations?part a?
d.Label the capital market line and tangency5.9.What is the covariance of the return of the tangency
portfolio.portfolio from exercise 5.2 with the return of all
e.What condition must hold at the tangencyportfolios that have the same expected return as
portfolio?AOL?
Exercises 5.2–5.9 make use of the following information5.10.Using a spreadsheet, compute the minimumabout the mean returns and covariances for three stocks.variance and tangency portfolios for the universe ofThe numbers used are hypothetical.three stocks described below. Assume the risk-free
return is 5 percent. Hypothetical data necessary for
this calculation are provided in the table below. See
Covariance withexercise 5.6 for detailed instructions.
Mean
StockAOLMicrosoftIntelReturn
|
|
|
|
|
CorrelationCorrelation |
AOL |
.002 |
.001 |
0 |
15% |
|
|
|
|
|
|
StandardMeanwithwith |
Microsoft |
.001 |
.002 |
.001 |
12 |
StockDeviationReturnBell SouthCaterpillar |
Intel |
0 |
.001 |
.002 |
10 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Apple |
.20 |
.15 |
.8 |
.1 |
|
|
Bell South.30.101.0.2 |
5.2. |
Compute the tangency portfolio weights assuming a |
|
|
|
Caterpillar.25.12.21.0 |
|
risk-free asset yields 5 percent. |
|
5.3. |
How does your answer to exercise 5.2 change if the |
|
|
risk-free rate is 3 percent? 7 percent? |
5.11.The Alumina Corporation has the following |
5.4. |
Draw a mean-standard deviation diagram and plot |
simplified balance sheet (based on market values) |
|
AOL, Microsoft, and Intel on this diagram as well |
|
|
|
AssetsLiabilities and Equity |
|
as the three tangency portfolios found in exercises |
|
|
5.2 and 5.3. |
Debt |
5.5. |
Show that an equally weighted portfolio of AOL, |
$10 billion$6 billion |
|
Microsoft, and Intel can be improved upon with |
Common Stock |
|
marginal variance-marginal mean analysis. |
$4 billion |
5.6. |
Repeat exercises 5.2 and 5.3, but use a spreadsheet |
|
|
to solve for the tangency portfolio weights of AOL, |
a.The debt of Alumina, being risk-free, earns the |
|
Microsoft, and Intel in the three cases. The solution |
risk-free return of 6 percent per year. The equity |
|
of the system of equations requires you to invert the |
of Alumina has a mean return of 12 percent per |
|
matrix of covariances above, then post multiply the |
year, a standard deviation of 30 percent per year, |
|
inverted covariance matrix by the column of risk |
and a beta of .9. Compute the mean return, beta, |
|
premiums. The solution should be a column of |
and standard deviation of the assets of Alumina. |
|
cells, which needs to be rescaled so that the weights |
Hint:View the assets as a portfolio of the debt |
|
sum to 1. Hint:See footnote 11. |
and equity. |
5.7. |
a.Compute the betas of AOL, Microsoft, and Intel |
b.If the CAPM holds, what is the mean return of |
|
with respect to the tangency portfolio found in |
the market portfolio? |
|
exercise 5.2. |
|
-
Grinblatt
364 Titman: FinancialII. Valuing Financial Assets
5. Mean
364 Variance Analysis© The McGraw
364 HillMarkets and Corporate
and the Capital Asset
Companies, 2002
Strategy, Second Edition
Pricing Model
172Part IIValuing Financial Assets
c.How does your answer to part achange if the5.16.Using data only from 1991–1995, redo Example
debt is risky, has returns with a mean of 75.9. Which differs more from the answer given in
percent, has a standard deviation of 10 percent, aExample 5.9: the expected return estimated by
beta of .2, and has a correlation of .3 with theaveraging the quarterly returns or the expected
return of the common stock of Alumina?return obtained by estimating beta and employing5.12.The following are the returns for Exxon (whichthe risk-expected return equation? Why?
later merged with Mobil) and the corresponding5.17.Estimate the Bloomberg-adjusted betas for the
returns of the S&P500 market index for eachfollowing companies.
month in 1994.
Unadjusted Beta
|
Exxon |
S&P500 |
|
|
|
|
|
Delta Air Lines |
0.84 |
Month |
Return (%) |
Return (%) |
|
|
|
|
|
Procter & Gamble |
1.40 |
January |
5.35% |
3.35% |
|
|
|
|
|
Coca-Cola |
0.88 |
February |
1.36 |
2.70 |
|
|
|
|
|
Gillette |
0.90 |
March |
3.08 |
4.35 |
|
|
|
|
|
Citigroup |
1.32 |
April |
0.00 |
1.30 |
|
|
|
|
|
Caterpillar |
1.00 |
May |
1.64 |
1.63 |
|
|
|
|
|
ExxonMobil |
0.64 |
June |
7.16 |
2.47 |
|
|
July4.853.31
5.18.Compute the tangency and minimum variance
August1.214.07
portfolios assuming that there are only two stocks:
September3.362.41Nike and McDonald’s. The expected returns of
October9.352.29Nike and McDonald’s are .15 and .14, respectively.
The variances of their returns are .04 and .08,
November2.783.67
respectively. The covariance between the two is
December0.621.46
.02. Assume the risk-free rate is 6%.
5.19.There exists a portfolio P, whose expected return is
Using a spreadsheet, compute Exxon’s beta. Then11%. Stock I has a covariance with Pof .004, and
apply the Bloomberg adjustment to derive theStock II has a covariance with Pof .005. If the
adjusted beta.expected returns on Stocks I and II are 9% and 12%,5.13.What value must ACYOU Corporation’s expectedrespectively, and the risk-free rate is 5%, then is it
return be in Example 5.4 to prevent us frompossible for portfolio Pto be the tangency portfolio?
forming a combination of Henry’s portfolio,5.20.The expected return of the S&P500, which you can
ACME, ACYOU, and the risk-free asset that isassume is the tangency portfolio, is 16% and has a
mean-variance superior to Henry’s portfolio?standard deviation of 25% per year. The expected5.14.Assume that the tangency portfolio for stocksreturn of Microsoft is unknown, but it has a
allocates 80 percent to the S&P500 index and 20standard deviation of 20% per year and a
percent to the Nasdaq composite index. Thiscovariance with the S&P500 of 0.10. If the risk-
tangency portfolio has an expected return of 13free rate is 6 percent per year,
percent per year and a standard deviation of 8.8a.Compute Microsoft’s beta.
percent per year. The beta for the S&P500 index,b.What is Microsoft’s expected return given the
computed with respect to this tangency portfolio, isbeta computed in part a?
.54. Compute the expected return of the S&P500c.If Intel has half the expected return of Microsoft,
index, assuming that this 80%/20% mix really isthen what is Intel’s beta?
the tangency portfolio when the risk-free rate is 5d.What is the beta of the following portfolio?
percent..25 in Microsoft
5.15.Exercise 5.14 assumed that the tangency portfolio.10 in Intel
allocated 80 percent to the S&P500 index and 20.75 in the S&P500
percent to the Nasdaq composite index. The beta.20 in GM (where .80)
GM
for the S&P500 index with this tangency portfolio.10 in the risk-free asset
is .54. Compute the beta of a portfolio that is 50e.What is the expected return of the portfolio in
percent invested in the tangency portfolio and 50part d?
percent invested in the S&P500index.
Grinblatt |
II. Valuing Financial Assets |
5.
Mean |
©
The McGraw |
Markets and Corporate |
|
and the Capital Asset |
Companies, 2002 |
Strategy, Second Edition |
|
Pricing Model |
|
-
Chapter 5
Mean-Variance Analysis and the Capital Asset Pricing Model
173
References and Additional Readings
Banz, Rolf W. “The Relationship between Return and
Market Value of Common Stocks.” Journal of
Financial Economics9 (1981), pp. 3–18.
Basu, Sanjay. “The Relationship between Earnings Yield,
Market Value, and Return for NYSE Common
Stocks: Further Evidence.” Journal of Financial
Economics12 (1983), pp. 129–56.
Black, Fischer. “Capital Market Equilibrium with
Restricted Borrowing.” Journal of Business45
(1972), pp. 444–55.
Black, Fischer; Michael C. Jensen; and Myron Scholes.
“The Capital Asset Pricing Model: Some Empirical
Tests.” In Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets,
M. Jensen, ed. New York: Praeger, 1972.
Brennan, Michael. “Taxes, Market Valuation and
Corporate Financial Policy.” National Tax Journal
23, December (1970), pp. 417–27.
———. “Capital Market Equilibrium with Divergent
Lending and Borrowing Rates.” Journal of Financial
and Quantitative Analysis6 (1971), pp. 1197–1205.Brown, Philip; Allan Kleidon; and Terry Marsh. “New
Evidence on Size-Related Anomalies in Stock
Prices.” Journal of Financial Economics12, no. 1
(1983), pp. 33–56.
Chan, K. C., and Nai-fu Chen. “An Unconditional Asset
Pricing Test and the Role of Firm Size as an
Instrumental Variable for Risk.” Journal of Finance
43 (1988), pp. 309–25.
Chan, Louis K.; Yasushi Hamao; and Josef Lakonishok.
“Fundamentals and Stock Returns in Japan.” Journal
of Finance46 (1991), pp. 1739–89.
Constantinides, George, and A. G. Malliaris. “Portfolio
Theory.” Chapter 1 in Handbooks in Operations
Research and Management Science:Volume 9,
Finance.Robert Jarrow, V. Maksimovic, and W.
Ziemba, eds. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science
Publishers, 1995.
DeBondt, Werner, and Richard Thaler. “Does the Stock
Market Overreact?” Journal of Finance40 (1985),
pp. 793–805.
Dimson, Elroy. “Risk Measurement When Shares Are
Subject to Infrequent Trading.” Journal of Financial
Economics7, no. 2 (1979), pp. 197–226.
Fama, Eugene. Foundations of Finance.New York: Basic
Books, 1976.
Fama, Eugene, and Kenneth R. French. “The Cross-
Section of Expected Stock Returns.” Journal of
Finance47 (1992), pp. 427–65.
———. “The CAPM Is Wanted, Dead or Alive.” Journal
of Finance,51, no. 5 (1996), pp. 1947–58.
Fama, Eugene, and James MacBeth. “Risk, Return, and
Equilibrium: Empirical Tests.” Journal of Political
Economy81 (1973), pp. 607–36.
Handa, Puneet; S. P. Kothari; and Charles Wasley. “The
Relation between the Return Interval and Betas:
Implications for the Size Effect.” Journal of
Financial Economics23 (1989), pp. 79–100.
Hawawini, Gabriel, and Donald Keim. “On the
Predictability of Common Stock Returns: World
Wide Evidence.” Chapter 17 in Handbooks in
Operations Research and Management Science:
Volume 9,Finance,Robert Jarrow, V. Maksimovic,
and W. Ziemba, eds. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science
Publishers, 1995.
Hong, Harrison; Terence Lim; and Jeremy Stein. “Bad
News Travels Slowly: Size, Analyst Coverage, and
the Profitability of Momentum Strategies.” Journal
of Finance55 (2000), pp. 265–295.
Jagannathan, Ravi, and Zhenyu Wang. “The Conditional
CAPM and the Cross-Section of Expected Returns.”
Journal of Finance51, no. 1 (March 1996), pp.3–53.Jegadeesh, Narasimhan. “Evidence of Predictable
Behavior of Security Returns.” Journal of Finance
45, no. 3 (1990), pp. 881–98.
———. “Does Market Risk Really Explain the Size
Effect?” Journal of Financial and Quantitative
Analysis27 (1992), pp. 337–51.
Jegadeesh, Narasimhan, and Sheridan Titman. “Returns to
Buying Winners and Selling Losers: Implications for
Stock Market Efficiency.” Journal of Finance48
(1993), pp. 65–91.
Keim, Donald. “Size-Related Anomalies and Stock
Return Seasonality: Further Empirical Evidence.”
Journal of Financial Economics12 (1983),
pp.13–32.
———. “The CAPM and Equity Return Regularities.”
Financial Analysts Journal42, no. 3 (1986),
pp.19–34.
Kothari, S. P.; Jay Shanken; and Richard G. Sloan.
“Another Look at the Cross-Section of Expected
Stock Returns.” Journal of Finance50, no. 1 (1995),
pp. 185–224.
Lakonishok, Josef, and Alan C. Shapiro. “Systematic
Risk, Total Risk, and Size as Determinants of Stock
Market Returns.” Journal of Banking and Finance10
(1986), pp. 115–32.
Lakonishok, Josef; Andrei Shleifer; and Robert Vishny.
“Contrarian Investment, Extrapolation, and Risk.”
Journal of Finance49, no. 5 (Dec. 1994),
pp.1541–78.
Lee, Charles, and Bhaskaran Swaminathan. “Price
Momentum and Trading Volume.” Journal of
Finance55 (2000), pp. 2017–2070.
Lehmann, Bruce. “Fads, Martingales, and Market
Efficiency.” Quarterly Journal of Economics105
(1990), pp. 1–28.
-
Grinblatt
368 Titman: FinancialII. Valuing Financial Assets
5. Mean
368 Variance Analysis© The McGraw
368 HillMarkets and Corporate
and the Capital Asset
Companies, 2002
Strategy, Second Edition
Pricing Model
174Part IIValuing Financial Assets
Levis, M. “Are Small Firms Big Performers?” Investment
Analyst76 (1985), pp. 21–27.
Lintner, John. “Security Prices, Risk, and Maximal Gains
from Diversification.” Journal of Finance20 (1965),
pp. 587–615.
Litzenberger, Robert, and Krishna Ramaswamy. “The
Effect of Personal Taxes and Dividends on Capital
Asset Prices: Theory and Empirical Evidence.”
Journal of Financial Economics7 (1979),
pp. 163–95.
Markowitz, Harry. Portfolio Selection: Efficient
Diversification of Investments.New York: John
Wiley, 1959.
Mayers, David. “Nonmarketable Assets and Capital
Market Equilibrium under Uncertainty.” In Studies in
the Theory of Capital Markets,Michael Jensen, ed.
New York: Praeger, 1972.
Moskowitz, Tobias, and Mark Grinblatt. “Do Industries
Explain Momentum?” Journal of Finance54 (1999),
pp. 1249–1290.
Reinganum, Marc R. “AMisspecification of Capital Asset
Pricing: Empirical Anomalies Based on Earnings,
Yields, and Market Values.” Journal of Financial
Economics9 (1981), pp. 19–46.
———. “The Anomalous Stock Market Behavior of
Small Firms in January: Empirical Tests for Tax-Loss
Selling Effects.” Journal of Financial Economics12
(1983), pp. 89–104.
Roll, Richard W. “ACritique of the Asset Pricing
Theory’s Tests; Part I: On Past and Potential
Testability of the Theory.” Journal of Financial
Economics4, no. 2 (1977), pp. 129–76.
———. “Vas Ist Das?” Journal of Portfolio Management
9 (1982–1983), pp. 18–28.
Rosenberg, Barr; Kenneth Reid; and Ronald Lanstein.
“Persuasive Evidence of Market Inefficiency.”
Journal of Portfolio Management11 (1985),
pp. 9–17.
Scholes, Myron, and Joseph Williams. “Estimating Betas
from Nonsynchronous Data.” Journal of Financial
Economics5, no. 3 (1977), pp. 309–27.
Sharpe, William. “Capital Asset Prices: ATheory of
Market Equilibrium under Conditions of Risk.”
Journal of Finance19 (1964), pp. 425–42.
———. Portfolio Theory and Capital Markets.New
York: McGraw-Hill, 1970.
Stattman, Dennis. “Book Values and Stock Returns.”
Chicago MBA: AJournal of Selected Papers4
(1980), pp. 25–45.
Stocks, Bonds, Bills,and Inflation 2000 Yearbook.
Chicago, IL: Ibbotson Associates, 2000.
Ziemba, William. “Japanese Security Market Regularities:
Monthly, Turn-of-the-Month, and Year, Holiday and
Golden Week Effects.” Japan World Econ.3, no. 2
(1991), pp. 119–46.
Grinblatt |
II. Valuing Financial Assets |
6. Factor Models and the |
©
The McGraw |
Markets and Corporate |
|
Arbitrage Pricing Theory |
Companies, 2002 |
Strategy, Second Edition |
|
|
|
CHAPTER
Factor Models and the
6
Arbitrage Pricing Theory
Learning Objectives
After reading this chapter, you should be able to:
1.Decompose the variance of a security into market-related and nonmarket-related
components, as well as common factor and firm-specific components, and
comprehend why this variance decomposition is important for valuing financial
assets.
2.Identify the expected return, factor betas, factors, and firm-specific components of
a security from its factor equation.
3.Explain how the principle of diversification relates to firm-specific risk.
4.Compute the factor betas for a portfolio given the factor betas of its component
securities.
5.Design a portfolio with a specific configuration of factor betas in order to design
pure factor portfolios, as well as portfolios that perfectly hedge an investment’s
endowment of factor risk.
6.State what the arbitrage pricing theory (APT) equation means and what the
empirical evidence says about the APT. You also should be able to use your
understanding of the APTequation to form arbitrage portfolios when the equation
is violated.
From March 10, 2000, to January 2, 2001, the tech-heavy Nasdaq Composite Index
dropped from 5048.62 to 2291.86, a decline of nearly 55% in less than 10 months.
By contrast, while there were declines in other stock indexes, like the Standard and
Poor’s 500 and the Russell 2000 index, an index of stocks with smaller market
capitalizations, they were far less dramatic. The S&P500 decline was about 7% (a
decline that was partly cushioned by the dividends paid on these stocks), while the
Russell 2000 index dropped about 23%. The Dow-Jones Industrial Average
increased by 8% over this same period. Mutual funds that had concentrated their
positions in technology stocks suffered devastating losses. Many lost more than 75%
of their value, particularly those focused on the Internet sector. This is largely the
opposite of what had taken place over the previous five years.
175
-
Grinblatt
371 Titman: FinancialII. Valuing Financial Assets
6. Factor Models and the
© The McGraw
371 HillMarkets and Corporate
Arbitrage Pricing Theory
Companies, 2002
Strategy, Second Edition
176Part IIValuing Financial Assets
This chapter introduces factormodels, which are equations that break down the
returns of securities into two components. Afactor model specifies that the return
of each risky investment is determined by:
-
•
Arelatively small number of common factors, which are proxies for thoseevents in the economy that affect a large number of different investments.
•
Arisk component that is unique to the investment.
For example, changes in IBM’s stock price can be partly attributed to a set of
macroeconomic variables, such as changes in interest rates, inflation, and productiv-
ity, which are common factors because they affect the prices of most stocks. In addi-
tion, changes in IBM’s stock price are affected by the success of new product innova-
tions, cost-cutting efforts, a fire at a manufacturing plant, the discovery of an illegal
corporate act, a management change, and so forth. These components of IBM’s return
are considered firm-specific componentsbecause they affect only that firm and not
the returns of other investments.
In many important applications, it is possible to ignore the firm-specific compo-
nents of the returns of portfolios consisting of large numbers of stocks. The return vari-
ances of these portfolios are almost entirely determined by the common factors, and
are virtually unaffected by the firm-specific components. Since these are the kinds of
portfolios that most investors should and will hold, the risk of a security that is gener-
ated by these firm-specific components—firm-specific risk—does not affect the over-
all desirability or lack of desirability of these types of portfolios.
Although common factors affect the returns of numerous investments, the sensi-
tivities of an investment’s returns to the factors differ from investment to investment.
For example, the stock price of an electric utility may be much more sensitive to
changes in interest rates than that of a soft drink firm. These ,1
factorbetasor factor
sensitivitiesas they are sometimes called, are similar to the market betas discussed in
the last chapter, which also differ from stock to stock.
Factor models are useful tools for risk analysis, hedging, and portfolio management.
The chapter’s opening vignette illustrates why it is important to understand the multiple
sources of risk that can affect an investment’s return.2
Recall from the opening vignette
that many mutual funds, by acquiring large positions in technology stocks, suffered dis-
astrous losses in comparison with funds concentrated in S&P500 or Dow stocks.
If stocks were sensitive to only one common factor, the returns of most funds would
be highly correlated with one another. However, stocks are subject to multiple sources
of factorrisk, which is return variability generated by common factors. Some factors
tend to affect large and small firms differently. Some affect growth-oriented companies
differently from stocks in slower growth industries. This means that over any day, week,
month, or year, we may witness some funds doing well while others do poorly. Afund,
as well as a firm, should be very conscious of the factor risk it is exposed to.
Factor models not only describe how unexpected changes in various macroeco-
nomic variables affect an investment’s return, but they also can be used to provide esti-
mates of the expected rate of return of an investment. Section 6.10 uses factor models
to derive the arbitrage pricing theory (APT), developed by Ross (1976), which relates
the factor risk of an investment to its expected rate of return. It is termed the arbitrage
pricing theorybecause it is based on the principle of no arbitrage.3
1
Statisticians also refer to these as factor loadings.
2
Chapter 22 discusses risk analysis and hedging with factor models in greater depth.
3As noted in the introduction to Part II, an arbitrage opportunity, essentially a money tree, is a set of
trades that make money without risk.
Grinblatt |
II. Valuing Financial Assets |
6. Factor Models and the |
©
The McGraw |
Markets and Corporate |
|
Arbitrage Pricing Theory |
Companies, 2002 |
Strategy, Second Edition |
|
|
|
-
Chapter 6
Factor Models and the Arbitrage Pricing Theory
177
As a theory, the APTis applied in much the same way as the Capital Asset Pric-
ing Model (CAPM). However, it requires less restrictive assumptions about investor
behavior than the CAPM, is more amenable to empirical tests, and in many cases can
be applied more easily than the CAPM. The APThas recently become more popular
because of the empirical shortcomings of the CAPM described in Chapter 5. Specifi-
cally, the stocks of small capitalization firms and the stocks of companies with low
market-to-book ratios generally have much higher returns than the CAPM would pre-
dict. The hope is that, with APTfactors, additional aspects of risk beyond market risk
can be taken into account and the high average returns of both the smaller cap stocks
and the low market-to-book stocks can be explained.
Although investors often view the CAPM and the APTas competing theories, both
can benefit investors as well as corporate finance practitioners. For example, the empir-
ical evidence described at the end of Chapter 5 suggests that applications of the CAPM
that use traditional market proxies, such as the S&P500, fail to explain the cross-
sectional pattern of past stock returns. The analysis of factor models in this chapter
provides insights into why the CAPM failed along with an alternative that would have
worked much better in the past. However, the greater flexibility of the APT, which
allows it to explain pastaverage returns much better than the CAPM, comes at a cost.
Because the APTis less restrictive than the CAPM, it also provides less guidance about
how expected futurerates of return should be estimated.