
- •Intended Audience
- •1.1 Financing the Firm
- •1.2Public and Private Sources of Capital
- •1.3The Environment forRaising Capital in the United States
- •Investment Banks
- •1.4Raising Capital in International Markets
- •1.5MajorFinancial Markets outside the United States
- •1.6Trends in Raising Capital
- •Innovative Instruments
- •2.1Bank Loans
- •2.2Leases
- •2.3Commercial Paper
- •2.4Corporate Bonds
- •2.5More Exotic Securities
- •2.6Raising Debt Capital in the Euromarkets
- •2.7Primary and Secondary Markets forDebt
- •2.8Bond Prices, Yields to Maturity, and Bond Market Conventions
- •2.9Summary and Conclusions
- •3.1Types of Equity Securities
- •Volume of Financing with Different Equity Instruments
- •3.2Who Owns u.S. Equities?
- •3.3The Globalization of Equity Markets
- •3.4Secondary Markets forEquity
- •International Secondary Markets for Equity
- •3.5Equity Market Informational Efficiency and Capital Allocation
- •3.7The Decision to Issue Shares Publicly
- •3.8Stock Returns Associated with ipOs of Common Equity
- •Ipo Underpricing of u.S. Stocks
- •4.1Portfolio Weights
- •4.2Portfolio Returns
- •4.3Expected Portfolio Returns
- •4.4Variances and Standard Deviations
- •4.5Covariances and Correlations
- •4.6Variances of Portfolios and Covariances between Portfolios
- •Variances for Two-Stock Portfolios
- •4.7The Mean-Standard Deviation Diagram
- •4.8Interpreting the Covariance as a Marginal Variance
- •Increasing a Stock Position Financed by Reducing orSelling Short the Position in
- •Increasing a Stock Position Financed by Reducing orShorting a Position in a
- •4.9Finding the Minimum Variance Portfolio
- •Identifying the Minimum Variance Portfolio of Two Stocks
- •Identifying the Minimum Variance Portfolio of Many Stocks
- •Investment Applications of Mean-Variance Analysis and the capm
- •5.2The Essentials of Mean-Variance Analysis
- •5.3The Efficient Frontierand Two-Fund Separation
- •5.4The Tangency Portfolio and Optimal Investment
- •Identification of the Tangency Portfolio
- •5.5Finding the Efficient Frontierof Risky Assets
- •5.6How Useful Is Mean-Variance Analysis forFinding
- •5.8The Capital Asset Pricing Model
- •Implications for Optimal Investment
- •5.9Estimating Betas, Risk-Free Returns, Risk Premiums,
- •Improving the Beta Estimated from Regression
- •Identifying the Market Portfolio
- •5.10Empirical Tests of the Capital Asset Pricing Model
- •Is the Value-Weighted Market Index Mean-Variance Efficient?
- •Interpreting the capm’s Empirical Shortcomings
- •5.11 Summary and Conclusions
- •6.1The Market Model:The First FactorModel
- •6.2The Principle of Diversification
- •Insurance Analogies to Factor Risk and Firm-Specific Risk
- •6.3MultifactorModels
- •Interpreting Common Factors
- •6.5FactorBetas
- •6.6Using FactorModels to Compute Covariances and Variances
- •6.7FactorModels and Tracking Portfolios
- •6.8Pure FactorPortfolios
- •6.9Tracking and Arbitrage
- •6.10No Arbitrage and Pricing: The Arbitrage Pricing Theory
- •Verifying the Existence of Arbitrage
- •Violations of the aptEquation fora Small Set of Stocks Do Not Imply Arbitrage.
- •Violations of the aptEquation by Large Numbers of Stocks Imply Arbitrage.
- •6.11Estimating FactorRisk Premiums and FactorBetas
- •6.12Empirical Tests of the Arbitrage Pricing Theory
- •6.13 Summary and Conclusions
- •7.1Examples of Derivatives
- •7.2The Basics of Derivatives Pricing
- •7.3Binomial Pricing Models
- •7.4Multiperiod Binomial Valuation
- •7.5Valuation Techniques in the Financial Services Industry
- •7.6Market Frictions and Lessons from the Fate of Long-Term
- •7.7Summary and Conclusions
- •8.1ADescription of Options and Options Markets
- •8.2Option Expiration
- •8.3Put-Call Parity
- •Insured Portfolio
- •8.4Binomial Valuation of European Options
- •8.5Binomial Valuation of American Options
- •Valuing American Options on Dividend-Paying Stocks
- •8.6Black-Scholes Valuation
- •8.7Estimating Volatility
- •Volatility
- •8.8Black-Scholes Price Sensitivity to Stock Price, Volatility,
- •Interest Rates, and Expiration Time
- •8.9Valuing Options on More Complex Assets
- •Implied volatility
- •8.11 Summary and Conclusions
- •9.1 Cash Flows ofReal Assets
- •9.2Using Discount Rates to Obtain Present Values
- •Value Additivity and Present Values of Cash Flow Streams
- •Inflation
- •9.3Summary and Conclusions
- •10.1Cash Flows
- •10.2Net Present Value
- •Implications of Value Additivity When Evaluating Mutually Exclusive Projects.
- •10.3Economic Value Added (eva)
- •10.5Evaluating Real Investments with the Internal Rate of Return
- •Intuition for the irrMethod
- •10.7 Summary and Conclusions
- •10A.1Term Structure Varieties
- •10A.2Spot Rates, Annuity Rates, and ParRates
- •11.1Tracking Portfolios and Real Asset Valuation
- •Implementing the Tracking Portfolio Approach
- •11.2The Risk-Adjusted Discount Rate Method
- •11.3The Effect of Leverage on Comparisons
- •11.4Implementing the Risk-Adjusted Discount Rate Formula with
- •11.5Pitfalls in Using the Comparison Method
- •11.6Estimating Beta from Scenarios: The Certainty Equivalent Method
- •Identifying the Certainty Equivalent from Models of Risk and Return
- •11.7Obtaining Certainty Equivalents with Risk-Free Scenarios
- •Implementing the Risk-Free Scenario Method in a Multiperiod Setting
- •11.8Computing Certainty Equivalents from Prices in Financial Markets
- •11.9Summary and Conclusions
- •11A.1Estimation Errorand Denominator-Based Biases in Present Value
- •11A.2Geometric versus Arithmetic Means and the Compounding-Based Bias
- •12.2Valuing Strategic Options with the Real Options Methodology
- •Valuing a Mine with No Strategic Options
- •Valuing a Mine with an Abandonment Option
- •Valuing Vacant Land
- •Valuing the Option to Delay the Start of a Manufacturing Project
- •Valuing the Option to Expand Capacity
- •Valuing Flexibility in Production Technology: The Advantage of Being Different
- •12.3The Ratio Comparison Approach
- •12.4The Competitive Analysis Approach
- •12.5When to Use the Different Approaches
- •Valuing Asset Classes versus Specific Assets
- •12.6Summary and Conclusions
- •13.1Corporate Taxes and the Evaluation of Equity-Financed
- •Identifying the Unlevered Cost of Capital
- •13.2The Adjusted Present Value Method
- •Valuing a Business with the wacc Method When a Debt Tax Shield Exists
- •Investments
- •IsWrong
- •Valuing Cash Flow to Equity Holders
- •13.5Summary and Conclusions
- •14.1The Modigliani-MillerTheorem
- •IsFalse
- •14.2How an Individual InvestorCan “Undo” a Firm’s Capital
- •14.3How Risky Debt Affects the Modigliani-MillerTheorem
- •14.4How Corporate Taxes Affect the Capital Structure Choice
- •14.6Taxes and Preferred Stock
- •14.7Taxes and Municipal Bonds
- •14.8The Effect of Inflation on the Tax Gain from Leverage
- •14.10Are There Tax Advantages to Leasing?
- •14.11Summary and Conclusions
- •15.1How Much of u.S. Corporate Earnings Is Distributed to Shareholders?Aggregate Share Repurchases and Dividends
- •15.2Distribution Policy in Frictionless Markets
- •15.3The Effect of Taxes and Transaction Costs on Distribution Policy
- •15.4How Dividend Policy Affects Expected Stock Returns
- •15.5How Dividend Taxes Affect Financing and Investment Choices
- •15.6Personal Taxes, Payout Policy, and Capital Structure
- •15.7Summary and Conclusions
- •16.1Bankruptcy
- •16.3How Chapter11 Bankruptcy Mitigates Debt Holder–Equity HolderIncentive Problems
- •16.4How Can Firms Minimize Debt Holder–Equity Holder
- •Incentive Problems?
- •17.1The StakeholderTheory of Capital Structure
- •17.2The Benefits of Financial Distress with Committed Stakeholders
- •17.3Capital Structure and Competitive Strategy
- •17.4Dynamic Capital Structure Considerations
- •17.6 Summary and Conclusions
- •18.1The Separation of Ownership and Control
- •18.2Management Shareholdings and Market Value
- •18.3How Management Control Distorts Investment Decisions
- •18.4Capital Structure and Managerial Control
- •Investment Strategy?
- •18.5Executive Compensation
- •Is Executive Pay Closely Tied to Performance?
- •Is Executive Compensation Tied to Relative Performance?
- •19.1Management Incentives When Managers Have BetterInformation
- •19.2Earnings Manipulation
- •Incentives to Increase or Decrease Accounting Earnings
- •19.4The Information Content of Dividend and Share Repurchase
- •19.5The Information Content of the Debt-Equity Choice
- •19.6Empirical Evidence
- •19.7Summary and Conclusions
- •20.1AHistory of Mergers and Acquisitions
- •20.2Types of Mergers and Acquisitions
- •20.3 Recent Trends in TakeoverActivity
- •20.4Sources of TakeoverGains
- •Is an Acquisition Required to Realize Tax Gains, Operating Synergies,
- •Incentive Gains, or Diversification?
- •20.5The Disadvantages of Mergers and Acquisitions
- •20.7Empirical Evidence on the Gains from Leveraged Buyouts (lbOs)
- •20.8 Valuing Acquisitions
- •Valuing Synergies
- •20.9Financing Acquisitions
- •Information Effects from the Financing of a Merger or an Acquisition
- •20.10Bidding Strategies in Hostile Takeovers
- •20.11Management Defenses
- •20.12Summary and Conclusions
- •21.1Risk Management and the Modigliani-MillerTheorem
- •Implications of the Modigliani-Miller Theorem for Hedging
- •21.2Why Do Firms Hedge?
- •21.4How Should Companies Organize TheirHedging Activities?
- •21.8Foreign Exchange Risk Management
- •Indonesia
- •21.9Which Firms Hedge? The Empirical Evidence
- •21.10Summary and Conclusions
- •22.1Measuring Risk Exposure
- •Volatility as a Measure of Risk Exposure
- •Value at Risk as a Measure of Risk Exposure
- •22.2Hedging Short-Term Commitments with Maturity-Matched
- •Value at
- •22.3Hedging Short-Term Commitments with Maturity-Matched
- •22.4Hedging and Convenience Yields
- •22.5Hedging Long-Dated Commitments with Short-Maturing FuturesorForward Contracts
- •Intuition for Hedging with a Maturity Mismatch in the Presence of a Constant Convenience Yield
- •22.6Hedging with Swaps
- •22.7Hedging with Options
- •22.8Factor-Based Hedging
- •Instruments
- •22.10Minimum Variance Portfolios and Mean-Variance Analysis
- •22.11Summary and Conclusions
- •23Risk Management
- •23.2Duration
- •23.4Immunization
- •Immunization Using dv01
- •Immunization and Large Changes in Interest Rates
- •23.5Convexity
- •23.6Interest Rate Hedging When the Term Structure Is Not Flat
- •23.7Summary and Conclusions
- •Interest Rate
- •Interest Rate
Immunization and Large Changes in Interest Rates
A$10,000 6-year 8 percent straight-coupon bond with annual coupons trading at par
has a duration of approximately five years. If the term structure of interest rates is flat,
and the interest rate increases slightly, the reinvested coupons will have an increased
value at year 5 that exactly counterbalances the decreased value of the bond in year 5
(that is, the year 5 value of its cash flows after year 5). The same is true when there
is a small decline in interest rates.
It is important, however, to determine how well immunization strategies perform
when there are substantial interest rate changes. Interest rates can sometimes jump by
large amounts when important economic indicators are announced (for example, the
monthly employment report by the U.S. Department of Labor or the Federal Reserve’s
announcement of its target interest rate). Moreover, even a series of small changes in
interest rates can amount to a large effective change in interest rates if transaction costs
lead investors to undertake a lax immunization strategy—failing to maintain the proper
duration for the bond at all points in time.
One can be comforted that immunization strategies work “pretty well” for the 8
percent straight-coupon bond described above and even for large interest rate changes
such as 25 basis points in one day. A25 bp decline in interest rates, from 8 percent to
7.75 percent, makes the sum of the year 5 value of the bond and its reinvested coupons
equal $14,693.14; in the absence of an interest rate shift, the bond’s value is $14,693.28.
Grinblatt |
VI. Risk Management |
23. Interest Rate Risk |
©
The McGraw |
Markets and Corporate |
|
Management |
Companies, 2002 |
Strategy, Second Edition |
|
|
|
-
Chapter 23
Interest Rate Risk Management
839
This is a remarkably insignificant difference! Since a 25 bp shift in the yield of a 6-year
bond would rarely occur over a single day, we can be fairly confident in stating that
immunization in this case would not require exceptionally frequent rebalancing of the
portfolio.
The next section discusses how to better quantify this degree of confidence.
23.5Convexity
Convexity measures how much DV01changes as the yield of a bond or bond portfo-
lio changes. Aportfolio with a DV01of zero will be insensitive to small interest rate
movements and less sensitive to large interest rate movements the smaller the convex-
ity. In other words, the DV01remains close to zero as interest rates change if convex-
ity is close to zero.
Defining and Interpreting Convexity
Convexity is a measure that determines how secure an investor should feel about a
“perfectly hedged” portfolio (for example, whether an electronic feed of bond prices
requires constant monitoring or whether the investor can relax and do other things). If
the convexity of a hedged portfolio is zero, even fairly large changes in interest rates
over a short time span should not alter the value of the portfolio drastically. If the con-
vexity is large, constant monitoring of the bond prices might be a good idea.
Positive Convexity Is More Typical.Most bonds have positive convexity, which
expresses the type of curvature seen earlier in the price-yield curve (Exhibit 23.1).
Exhibit 23.6 portrays price-yield curves for two bonds: one with a large amount of
convexity and one with little convexity. In contrast to this picture, bond portfolios,
withlong and short positions in different bonds, can have positive or “negative
convexity.”15
EXHIBIT23.6Convexity
-
Price
Price
Large amount of convexity
Little convexity
-
Yield
Yield
15Despite
its applications in science and mathematics, the word concavity,which is probably a better
term than negative convexity,has yet to find a place in the vocabulary of the bond markets.
-
Grinblatt
1690 Titman: FinancialVI. Risk Management
23. Interest Rate Risk
© The McGraw
1690 HillMarkets and Corporate
Management
Companies, 2002
Strategy, Second Edition
840Part VIRisk Management
The Convexity Formula.At a single point on the price-yield curve for a bond or
bond portfolio, the curvature, measured by convexity, is formally defined as follows:
The convexity “CONV(r)” of a bond or a bond portfolio at a yield to maturity of ris
the product of (1) $1,000,000 divided by the bond price and (2) the difference between
the current DV01(of the entire bond position) and the DV01(of the entire bond posi-
tion) at a yield of r.0001; that is
CONV(r) $1 million
DV01(r)DV01(r.0001)
P
DV01can be viewed as a derivative of the bond price with respect to its yield to
maturity. It differs from the derivative primarily in that DV01multiplies the derivative
by a constant. Convexity, CONV,is like the second derivative of the portfolio’s price
with respect to its yield in percent (not its basis point shift). To obtain convexity, mul-
tiply the DV01differenceby 10,000 (the square of 100) to undo the DV01convention
of multiplying the derivative with respect to the percentage yield by .01 (100 bps is
1percentage point of interest). In addition, convexity is typically scaled per $100 of
market value. Hence, after multiplying the difference between the DV01s at the two
yields by 10,000, it is customary to multiply by $100 and divide by the bond price per
$100 of face value. Example 23.14 illustrates the calculation.
Example 23.14:Computing Convexity
Compute the convexity of the 8 percent 2-year par straight-coupon bond analyzed in Exam-
ple 23.6.
Answer:The DV01of this bond is .0181516 per $100 face value at an 8.00 percent yield,
since its price at 7.99 percent is $100.0181516.At an 8.01 percent yield, the DV01is
.0181473, the difference between the $100 price at 8.00 percent and the price at 8.01 per-
cent, which is $99.9818527.The difference between the two DV01s is 4.3 106.The
con-
vexity is .043, which is 1 million divided by 100 times this number.
Implications of Convexity forImmunization Strategies.The last section indicated
that immunizing a portfolio for a T-year horizon requires managing the portfolio, so
that when it is combined with a hypothetical short position in a zero-coupon bond of
Tyears maturity, the duration and value of the combined portfolio is zero. If the con-
vexity of the actualportfolio is close to the convexity of the hypothetical T-year zero-
coupon bond, the investor who is immunizing the portfolio does not have to constantly
monitor bond prices. However, frequent rebalancing is needed to maintain the immu-
nized position of the actual portfolio if its convexity differs substantially from that of
the hypothetical portfolio. In the latter case, constant bond price monitoring is required.
Estimating Price Sensitivity to Yield
Investors often use convexity to improve upon the earlier (DV01or duration-based)
estimate of the change in the price of a bond portfolio for a given change in yield.
Specifically, letting rdenote the change in the yield to maturity (in percent form) and
Pthe starting price of the bond or bond portfolio, we can write16
16This
equation is derived from the second order Taylor series expansion. See any elementary calculus
text for details.
Grinblatt |
VI. Risk Management |
23. Interest Rate Risk |
©
The McGraw |
Markets and Corporate |
|
Management |
Companies, 2002 |
Strategy, Second Edition |
|
|
|
-
Chapter 23
Interest Rate Risk Management
841
-
P
CONV(r)2
P100DV01 r.5
(23.8)
100
Example 23.15 illustrates how to apply the formula.
Example 23.15:Using Convexity forAccurate Estimates of Price Change
Compute the change in the price of a bond portfolio with a $200 market value for a 25 basis
point increase in yield.At the current yield to maturity, the bond has a DV01of $0.15 and
a convexity of 1.2 (convexity is computed per $100 of market value).
Answer:Using equation (23.8), the change in price is
$200
2
100($.15)(.25).5 (1.2)(.25) $3.675
100
Hence, the new price will be $196.325.
One would estimate the change in price in Example 23.15 as $3.75 using only
DV01to estimate the change. Using equation (23.8) thus improves the estimate of inter-
est rate sensitivity by $.075.
Convexity (unlike DV01,but like duration) is independent of the scale of the invest-
ment. Holding twice as many bonds of the same type does not change the convexity
of the portfolio. Moreover, the convexity of a portfolio of bonds is the value-weighted
average of the convexity of each bond in the portfolio.
Misuse of Convexity
Throughout this chapter, we have assumed that the term structure of interest rates is
flat. This is the traditional approach taken in all but the most sophisticated bond port-
folio analysis and it is a good way to begin to understand the issues in bond portfolio
management and interest rate hedging. However, we must express caution: Not only is
this assumption generally an incorrect portrait of realistic term structures, but it is
fraught with a number of pitfalls that are based on inherent flaws in logic. Amisguided
application of convexity, discussed next, illuminates this point.
Convexity Appears to Be Good.Equation (23.8) implies that the higher the con-
vexity of a bond portfolio (holding market value and DV01constant), the larger the
value of the portfolio for both an increase and a decline in its yield to maturity. This
seems to imply that convexity is a good thing to have in a portfolio and that, other
things being equal, investments with a large amount of convexity are in some sense
better than investments with little convexity or negative convexity. Exhibit 23.7 illus-
trates this point by plotting the price-yield curve for two default-free bonds, each with
the same market value and DV01at a yield of 8 percent. Note that as yields change,
irrespective of the direction of change, the price of bond Awill be higher than that of
bond B. Bond Athus appears to be the better bond because it has more convexity.
The flaw in this analysis is that the yields to maturity of the two bonds need not
be the same. Unless the term structure of interest rates is flat, the two bonds need not
have the same yields at the same time, and when one bond’s yield moves up, the other’s
yield need not move up by the same amount. Comparing yields between two bonds is
a comparison of apples and oranges.
-
Grinblatt
1694 Titman: FinancialVI. Risk Management
23. Interest Rate Risk
© The McGraw
1694 HillMarkets and Corporate
Management
Companies, 2002
Strategy, Second Edition
842 |
Part VIRisk Management EXHIBIT23.7The Effects of Convexity forSimilarBonds Price |
-
100
Bond A
Bond B
-
Yield
8%
Arbitrage Exists When the Term Structure of Interest Rates Is Always Flat.
What if the term structure of interest rates is always flat? Is it then possible to con-
struct a pair of bond portfolio investments that look like bond Aand bond B? Or is
the construction of two such investments impossible? In the flat term structure sce-
nario, it is always possible to create two portfolios with the same market value and
the same DV01,but with different convexities. (They already have the same yield to
maturity by virtue of the assumption of a flat term structure of interest rates.) How-
ever, if one could find two bond portfolios with the characteristics of bonds Aand B
in Exhibit 23.7 there would be an arbitrage opportunity. By going long in the high-
convexity portfolio and short in the low-convexity portfolio, one achieves an invest-
ment combination that is self-financing and—for any size move in the interest rate—
has a positive value immediately after such move. What this means is that the
relationships depicted in Exhibit 23.7 are unlikely to exist in reality.
Changing the Convexity of a Bond Portfolio.An easy way to increase convexity
while holding DV01and market value constant is tospread payments out around
theduration.17
For example, compare (1) a portfolio consisting of a single 4-year
zero-coupon bond worth $2 million, with (2) a $2 million bond portfolio with equal
17Note
also that bond options, whether put or call options, have more convexity than the underlying
bonds themselves. Similarly, floating-rate investments with caps and floors have more convexity than
otherwise identical floating-rate investments without caps or floors.
Grinblatt |
VI. Risk Management |
23. Interest Rate Risk |
©
The McGraw |
Markets and Corporate |
|
Management |
Companies, 2002 |
Strategy, Second Edition |
|
|
|
-
Chapter 23
Interest Rate Risk Management
843
amounts invested in a 3-year zero-coupon bond and a 5-year zero-coupon bond. With
a flat term structure curve, the duration of the 2-bond portfolio is the value-weighted
average of the durations of the 3- and 5-year bonds, or four years—just like the first
zero-coupon bond. The DV01of the 2-bond portfolio is virtually identical to the DV01
of the 1-bond portfolio18because the durations and market values of the two portfo-
lios are the same.
If interest rates decline by 1 bp, the initial effect on the values of the two portfo-
lios will be about the same. However, since the 5-year bond in the 2-bond portfolio
now carries relatively more weight, the duration of the 2-bond portfolio will now be
closer to five years than to three. For the next basis point decline in interest rates, the
price of the 2-bond portfolio, which has a duration exceeding four years, will go up by
more than the price of the 1-bond portfolio, which has a duration of exactly four years.
This would push the duration even closer to five years. With a higher price and a still
higher duration, the DV01of the 2-bond portfolio would then exceed the DV01of the
1-bond portfolio by even more, and so on.
Consider the reverse situation. As interest rates increase, the duration of the 3-year
bond in the 2-bond portfolio now carries greater weight. Hence, while the first basis
point increase has about the same effect on both portfolios, subsequent basis point
increases result in greater price declines for the 1-bond portfolio because it has a larger
duration. In this case, as interest rates move down from the original rate, the DV01of
the 2-bond portfolio exceeds the DV01of the 1-bond portfolio by increasingly greater
amounts. Since DV01s are proportional to the slopes in a price-yield graph, the price-
yield graphs of the two portfolios look like those depicted in Exhibit 23.7 where the
1-bond portfolio is bond B and the 2-bond portfolio is bond A.
The previous discussion showed how to increase convexity by spreading payments
around the duration of a bond, focusing on zero-coupon bonds. It is possible to gener-
alize this procedure to coupon bonds. Panel Aof Exhibit 23.8 plots the cash flows of
an annuity bond against time. Panel B graphs the annuity bond’s price yield curve to
illustrate the convexity of the bond. Panel C plots the cash flows of a portfolio of two
zero-coupon bonds of different maturities. In panel D, the convexity of the 2-bond port-
folio is greater than the convexity of the annuity bond in panel B, seen as greater cur-
vature in the former. Example 23.16 uses numerical computations to demonstrate this
difference in convexity between an annuity bond and a portfolio of two zero-coupon
bonds.
Example 23.16:Convexity of an Annuity versus a Portfolio of
Zero-CouponBonds
Consider a portfolio consisting of an annuity that pays $100 every year for the next 30 years.
If 8 percent compounded annually is the market interest rate at all maturities, then the pres-
ent value of this annuity at 8 percent is
11
$1001 $1,125.7783
1.0830
.08
Its present values at 7.99 percent and 8.01 percent interest rates are, respectively
11
$1001 $1,126.8413
.07991.079930
18The
derivative implementations of the two DV01s are exactly the same.
-
Grinblatt
1697 Titman: FinancialVI. Risk Management
23. Interest Rate Risk
© The McGraw
1697 HillMarkets and Corporate
Management
Companies, 2002
Strategy, Second Edition
844Part VIRisk Management
EXHIBIT23.8Spreading Cash Flow around the Duration of a Coupon Bond
-
Coupon
Panel A
Price
Panel B
Annunity
Bond
-
t
Yield
-
Coupon
Panel C
Price
Panel D
Portfolio of two
zero-coupon bonds,
1 has a short maturity date
1 has a long maturity date
-
t
Yield
and
11
$1001 $1,124.7170
1.080130
.0801
The DV01s at 8.01 percent and 8.00 percent interest thus equal $1.0613 ( $1,125.7783
$1,124.7170) and $1.0630 ( $1,126.8413$1,125.7783), respectively, implying that the
annuity bond’s convexity is
$1,000,000
(1.06301.0613) 1.510
$1,125.7783
Replacing this annuity with a portfolio consisting of zero-coupon bonds maturing at year 1
and year 30 can increase convexity while maintaining the same DV01at 8 percent interest.
Find such a portfolio.
Answer:The problem requires finding a portfolio with face amounts xand yin the 1-year
and 30-year zero-coupon bonds, respectively.For a $1.00 face amount, note that a 1-year
zero-coupon bond has a DV01of $.000085742, while a 30-year zero-coupon bond has a
DV01of $.000276445.Thus, to generate a portfolio with the same present value and DV01
as the annuity, xand ymust satisfy the equations
Grinblatt |
VI. Risk Management |
23. Interest Rate Risk |
©
The McGraw |
Markets and Corporate |
|
Management |
Companies, 2002 |
Strategy, Second Edition |
|
|
|
-
Chapter 23
Interest Rate Risk Management
845
xy
$1,125.7783 (present value condition)
1.08(1.08)30
.000085742x.000276445y $1.0630 (DV01 condition)
y
The first equation says x $1,125.7783(1.08).Substituting this into the second
(1.08)29
equation gives
y
(.000085742)($1125.7783) (1.08).000276445y $1.0630
(1.08)29
-
or
y(.000276445.000009202476147) $0.958747165213
Thus, y $3,587.60 and x $830.80 (approximately).
The DV01of the portfolio of zero-coupon bonds is 1.0602 at an 8.01 percent yield and
1.0630 at an 8.00 percent yield.This makes convexity
$1,000,000
(1.06301.0602), or 2.487
$1,125.7783
Example 23.16 illustrates how easy it is to increase convexity at no cost. Using equa-
tion (23.8), the difference in convexities for a 25 bp shift upward or downward (to
either 7.75 percent or 8.25 percent) implies that the portfolio of two zero-coupon bonds
has a larger price than the annuity by the difference in the final terms in equation (23.8):
$1125.778
.52
(2.4871.510)(.25) $.34
100
Hence, going long in the portfolio of zero-coupon bonds and short in the annuity gen-
erates approximately a riskless $.34 for a portfolio of this size.19Most portfolios would
be much larger, particularly since this is a hedged portfolio. At 10,000 times the size,
$3,400 is achieved without risk; at 100,000 times the size, $34,000 is achieved with-
out risk.
It is difficult to believe that such arbitrage profits can be achieved. However, if the
term structure of interest rates is always flat, there is no cost to forming a portfolio
strategy in this manner. It is easy to prove that arbitrage profits also arise if the yield
curve is not flat but only shifts in a parallel manner. If convexity is to come at a cost
and if there is no arbitrage, term structure changes cannot be restricted to parallel shifts.