
- •Intended Audience
- •1.1 Financing the Firm
- •1.2Public and Private Sources of Capital
- •1.3The Environment forRaising Capital in the United States
- •Investment Banks
- •1.4Raising Capital in International Markets
- •1.5MajorFinancial Markets outside the United States
- •1.6Trends in Raising Capital
- •Innovative Instruments
- •2.1Bank Loans
- •2.2Leases
- •2.3Commercial Paper
- •2.4Corporate Bonds
- •2.5More Exotic Securities
- •2.6Raising Debt Capital in the Euromarkets
- •2.7Primary and Secondary Markets forDebt
- •2.8Bond Prices, Yields to Maturity, and Bond Market Conventions
- •2.9Summary and Conclusions
- •3.1Types of Equity Securities
- •Volume of Financing with Different Equity Instruments
- •3.2Who Owns u.S. Equities?
- •3.3The Globalization of Equity Markets
- •3.4Secondary Markets forEquity
- •International Secondary Markets for Equity
- •3.5Equity Market Informational Efficiency and Capital Allocation
- •3.7The Decision to Issue Shares Publicly
- •3.8Stock Returns Associated with ipOs of Common Equity
- •Ipo Underpricing of u.S. Stocks
- •4.1Portfolio Weights
- •4.2Portfolio Returns
- •4.3Expected Portfolio Returns
- •4.4Variances and Standard Deviations
- •4.5Covariances and Correlations
- •4.6Variances of Portfolios and Covariances between Portfolios
- •Variances for Two-Stock Portfolios
- •4.7The Mean-Standard Deviation Diagram
- •4.8Interpreting the Covariance as a Marginal Variance
- •Increasing a Stock Position Financed by Reducing orSelling Short the Position in
- •Increasing a Stock Position Financed by Reducing orShorting a Position in a
- •4.9Finding the Minimum Variance Portfolio
- •Identifying the Minimum Variance Portfolio of Two Stocks
- •Identifying the Minimum Variance Portfolio of Many Stocks
- •Investment Applications of Mean-Variance Analysis and the capm
- •5.2The Essentials of Mean-Variance Analysis
- •5.3The Efficient Frontierand Two-Fund Separation
- •5.4The Tangency Portfolio and Optimal Investment
- •Identification of the Tangency Portfolio
- •5.5Finding the Efficient Frontierof Risky Assets
- •5.6How Useful Is Mean-Variance Analysis forFinding
- •5.8The Capital Asset Pricing Model
- •Implications for Optimal Investment
- •5.9Estimating Betas, Risk-Free Returns, Risk Premiums,
- •Improving the Beta Estimated from Regression
- •Identifying the Market Portfolio
- •5.10Empirical Tests of the Capital Asset Pricing Model
- •Is the Value-Weighted Market Index Mean-Variance Efficient?
- •Interpreting the capm’s Empirical Shortcomings
- •5.11 Summary and Conclusions
- •6.1The Market Model:The First FactorModel
- •6.2The Principle of Diversification
- •Insurance Analogies to Factor Risk and Firm-Specific Risk
- •6.3MultifactorModels
- •Interpreting Common Factors
- •6.5FactorBetas
- •6.6Using FactorModels to Compute Covariances and Variances
- •6.7FactorModels and Tracking Portfolios
- •6.8Pure FactorPortfolios
- •6.9Tracking and Arbitrage
- •6.10No Arbitrage and Pricing: The Arbitrage Pricing Theory
- •Verifying the Existence of Arbitrage
- •Violations of the aptEquation fora Small Set of Stocks Do Not Imply Arbitrage.
- •Violations of the aptEquation by Large Numbers of Stocks Imply Arbitrage.
- •6.11Estimating FactorRisk Premiums and FactorBetas
- •6.12Empirical Tests of the Arbitrage Pricing Theory
- •6.13 Summary and Conclusions
- •7.1Examples of Derivatives
- •7.2The Basics of Derivatives Pricing
- •7.3Binomial Pricing Models
- •7.4Multiperiod Binomial Valuation
- •7.5Valuation Techniques in the Financial Services Industry
- •7.6Market Frictions and Lessons from the Fate of Long-Term
- •7.7Summary and Conclusions
- •8.1ADescription of Options and Options Markets
- •8.2Option Expiration
- •8.3Put-Call Parity
- •Insured Portfolio
- •8.4Binomial Valuation of European Options
- •8.5Binomial Valuation of American Options
- •Valuing American Options on Dividend-Paying Stocks
- •8.6Black-Scholes Valuation
- •8.7Estimating Volatility
- •Volatility
- •8.8Black-Scholes Price Sensitivity to Stock Price, Volatility,
- •Interest Rates, and Expiration Time
- •8.9Valuing Options on More Complex Assets
- •Implied volatility
- •8.11 Summary and Conclusions
- •9.1 Cash Flows ofReal Assets
- •9.2Using Discount Rates to Obtain Present Values
- •Value Additivity and Present Values of Cash Flow Streams
- •Inflation
- •9.3Summary and Conclusions
- •10.1Cash Flows
- •10.2Net Present Value
- •Implications of Value Additivity When Evaluating Mutually Exclusive Projects.
- •10.3Economic Value Added (eva)
- •10.5Evaluating Real Investments with the Internal Rate of Return
- •Intuition for the irrMethod
- •10.7 Summary and Conclusions
- •10A.1Term Structure Varieties
- •10A.2Spot Rates, Annuity Rates, and ParRates
- •11.1Tracking Portfolios and Real Asset Valuation
- •Implementing the Tracking Portfolio Approach
- •11.2The Risk-Adjusted Discount Rate Method
- •11.3The Effect of Leverage on Comparisons
- •11.4Implementing the Risk-Adjusted Discount Rate Formula with
- •11.5Pitfalls in Using the Comparison Method
- •11.6Estimating Beta from Scenarios: The Certainty Equivalent Method
- •Identifying the Certainty Equivalent from Models of Risk and Return
- •11.7Obtaining Certainty Equivalents with Risk-Free Scenarios
- •Implementing the Risk-Free Scenario Method in a Multiperiod Setting
- •11.8Computing Certainty Equivalents from Prices in Financial Markets
- •11.9Summary and Conclusions
- •11A.1Estimation Errorand Denominator-Based Biases in Present Value
- •11A.2Geometric versus Arithmetic Means and the Compounding-Based Bias
- •12.2Valuing Strategic Options with the Real Options Methodology
- •Valuing a Mine with No Strategic Options
- •Valuing a Mine with an Abandonment Option
- •Valuing Vacant Land
- •Valuing the Option to Delay the Start of a Manufacturing Project
- •Valuing the Option to Expand Capacity
- •Valuing Flexibility in Production Technology: The Advantage of Being Different
- •12.3The Ratio Comparison Approach
- •12.4The Competitive Analysis Approach
- •12.5When to Use the Different Approaches
- •Valuing Asset Classes versus Specific Assets
- •12.6Summary and Conclusions
- •13.1Corporate Taxes and the Evaluation of Equity-Financed
- •Identifying the Unlevered Cost of Capital
- •13.2The Adjusted Present Value Method
- •Valuing a Business with the wacc Method When a Debt Tax Shield Exists
- •Investments
- •IsWrong
- •Valuing Cash Flow to Equity Holders
- •13.5Summary and Conclusions
- •14.1The Modigliani-MillerTheorem
- •IsFalse
- •14.2How an Individual InvestorCan “Undo” a Firm’s Capital
- •14.3How Risky Debt Affects the Modigliani-MillerTheorem
- •14.4How Corporate Taxes Affect the Capital Structure Choice
- •14.6Taxes and Preferred Stock
- •14.7Taxes and Municipal Bonds
- •14.8The Effect of Inflation on the Tax Gain from Leverage
- •14.10Are There Tax Advantages to Leasing?
- •14.11Summary and Conclusions
- •15.1How Much of u.S. Corporate Earnings Is Distributed to Shareholders?Aggregate Share Repurchases and Dividends
- •15.2Distribution Policy in Frictionless Markets
- •15.3The Effect of Taxes and Transaction Costs on Distribution Policy
- •15.4How Dividend Policy Affects Expected Stock Returns
- •15.5How Dividend Taxes Affect Financing and Investment Choices
- •15.6Personal Taxes, Payout Policy, and Capital Structure
- •15.7Summary and Conclusions
- •16.1Bankruptcy
- •16.3How Chapter11 Bankruptcy Mitigates Debt Holder–Equity HolderIncentive Problems
- •16.4How Can Firms Minimize Debt Holder–Equity Holder
- •Incentive Problems?
- •17.1The StakeholderTheory of Capital Structure
- •17.2The Benefits of Financial Distress with Committed Stakeholders
- •17.3Capital Structure and Competitive Strategy
- •17.4Dynamic Capital Structure Considerations
- •17.6 Summary and Conclusions
- •18.1The Separation of Ownership and Control
- •18.2Management Shareholdings and Market Value
- •18.3How Management Control Distorts Investment Decisions
- •18.4Capital Structure and Managerial Control
- •Investment Strategy?
- •18.5Executive Compensation
- •Is Executive Pay Closely Tied to Performance?
- •Is Executive Compensation Tied to Relative Performance?
- •19.1Management Incentives When Managers Have BetterInformation
- •19.2Earnings Manipulation
- •Incentives to Increase or Decrease Accounting Earnings
- •19.4The Information Content of Dividend and Share Repurchase
- •19.5The Information Content of the Debt-Equity Choice
- •19.6Empirical Evidence
- •19.7Summary and Conclusions
- •20.1AHistory of Mergers and Acquisitions
- •20.2Types of Mergers and Acquisitions
- •20.3 Recent Trends in TakeoverActivity
- •20.4Sources of TakeoverGains
- •Is an Acquisition Required to Realize Tax Gains, Operating Synergies,
- •Incentive Gains, or Diversification?
- •20.5The Disadvantages of Mergers and Acquisitions
- •20.7Empirical Evidence on the Gains from Leveraged Buyouts (lbOs)
- •20.8 Valuing Acquisitions
- •Valuing Synergies
- •20.9Financing Acquisitions
- •Information Effects from the Financing of a Merger or an Acquisition
- •20.10Bidding Strategies in Hostile Takeovers
- •20.11Management Defenses
- •20.12Summary and Conclusions
- •21.1Risk Management and the Modigliani-MillerTheorem
- •Implications of the Modigliani-Miller Theorem for Hedging
- •21.2Why Do Firms Hedge?
- •21.4How Should Companies Organize TheirHedging Activities?
- •21.8Foreign Exchange Risk Management
- •Indonesia
- •21.9Which Firms Hedge? The Empirical Evidence
- •21.10Summary and Conclusions
- •22.1Measuring Risk Exposure
- •Volatility as a Measure of Risk Exposure
- •Value at Risk as a Measure of Risk Exposure
- •22.2Hedging Short-Term Commitments with Maturity-Matched
- •Value at
- •22.3Hedging Short-Term Commitments with Maturity-Matched
- •22.4Hedging and Convenience Yields
- •22.5Hedging Long-Dated Commitments with Short-Maturing FuturesorForward Contracts
- •Intuition for Hedging with a Maturity Mismatch in the Presence of a Constant Convenience Yield
- •22.6Hedging with Swaps
- •22.7Hedging with Options
- •22.8Factor-Based Hedging
- •Instruments
- •22.10Minimum Variance Portfolios and Mean-Variance Analysis
- •22.11Summary and Conclusions
- •23Risk Management
- •23.2Duration
- •23.4Immunization
- •Immunization Using dv01
- •Immunization and Large Changes in Interest Rates
- •23.5Convexity
- •23.6Interest Rate Hedging When the Term Structure Is Not Flat
- •23.7Summary and Conclusions
- •Interest Rate
- •Interest Rate
20.7Empirical Evidence on the Gains from Leveraged Buyouts (lbOs)
From the late 1970s to the late 1980s, a number of large publicly traded firms were
taken over in highly leveraged transactions that transformed the public companies into
privately held firms. The announcements of those LBOs generally resulted in dramatic
increases in the stock prices of the target firms, which suggests that LBOs create sub-
stantial value. However, because these LBOs did not involve the combination of two
firms, the kind of synergies discussed previously do not apply. Most analysts point to
improved management incentives as the motivation for LBOs.
How Leveraged Buyouts Affect Stock Prices
Avariety of studies have examined the premiums offered in LBOs as well as the stock
returns when the LBO transactions are first announced. These studies find that the aver-
age price paid in an LBO was 40 to 60 percent above the market price of the stocks
one to two months before the offers. Around the time of the announcements of these
offers, the stock price increased about 20 percent, on average.
Characteristics of HigherPremium Targets.Lehn and Poulsen (1989) found that
higher premiums were offered for firms with high cash flows, relatively low growth
opportunities, and high tax liabilities relative to their equity values. The higher premi-
ums for the high-cash flow/low-growth firms support the idea that there are larger gains
associated with levering up firms with these characteristics (for example, leverage
reduces their tendency to overinvest). The relation between the tax liabilities and the
premium suggests that part of the tax gain from the LBO transaction is passed along
to the original shareholders.
Competing Bids.The presence of competing bids also affects the premium offered
in LBOs. Lowenstein (1985) studied 28 LBOs, finding that those with less than three
competing bids received an average premium of 50 percent while those with more than
three competing bids received an average premium of 69 percent.
Grinblatt |
V. Incentives, Information, |
20. Mergers and |
©
The McGraw |
Markets and Corporate |
and Corporate Control |
Acquisitions |
Companies, 2002 |
Strategy, Second Edition |
|
|
|
-
Chapter 20
Mergers and Acquisitions
713
EXHIBIT20.4Summary of Changes in Firm Operations afterLBOs*
-
Kaplan
Muscarella and
Opler
Smith
Variable
(1989)
Vetsuypens (1990)
(1993)
(1990)
-
Cash flow/sales
20.1%
23.5%
8.8%
18%
Sales per employee
NA†
3.1%
16.7%
18%
-
Taxes
NA
NA
90.5%
80%
Investment/sales
31.6%
11.4%
46.7%
25%
Employees
0.9%
0.6%
0.7%
22%
R&D/sales
NA
NA
0.0%
75%
Time period studied
1980–86
1976–87
1986–89
1976–86
Number of LBOs
37
43
46
18
Window in years (before, after)
( 1, 2)
Variable
Variable
( 1, 2)
*Expressed as a percent increase or decrease.
†NAmeans statistic not available or not computed.
Cash Flow Changes Following Leveraged Buyouts
Anumber of studies have analyzed operating changes following LBOs. These studies,
summarized in Exhibit 20.4, examined changes in a number of variables that provide
insights into how LBOs affect a firm’s performance.
The results summarized in Exhibit 20.4 indicate that the magnitude of the cash
flow improvements following LBOs declined in the latter half of the 1980s. For exam-
ple, Kaplan (1989) found that from 1980 to 1986, cash flows increased, on average,
by 20.1 percent following an LBO. However, Opler (1993) found an average improve-
ment in cash flows of only 8.8 percent for LBOs initiated between 1986 and 1989.
One explanation for this decline in the performance of LBOs is that the success of the
earlier deals attracted a number of new investors, resulting in “too much money chas-
ing too few good deals,” which in turn led to buyouts of firms with less potential for
improvement.
Additional evidence suggests that LBOs occurring in later years were priced higher
and were more highly leveraged, leading to much higher default rates on LBO debt.
Kaplan and Stein (1993) found that noneof the 24 LBOs in their sample initiated
between 1980 and 1983 subsequently defaulted on their debt. However, defaults
claimed 46.7 percent of the LBOs initiated in 1986, 30.0 percent of those initiated in
1987, 16.1 percent of those initiated in 1988, and 20.0 percent of those initiated in
1989. Despite their high default rates, the firms that initiated these later LBOs still
tended to show improvements in productivity. In many cases, however, the productiv-
ity gains were not sufficient to justify their high prices and the firms did not generate
sufficient cash flows to pay off the high levels of debt incurred in the LBOs.
Productivity Increases Following LBOs.Exhibit 20.4, which summarizes four LBO
studies, provides evidence that at least part of the post-LBO increase in cash flows is
due to increased productivity. The three studies that measured the average change in
the value of sales per employee (labor productivity) found that labor productivity
increases after LBOs. Astudy by Lichtenberg and Siegel (1990), using plant-level data,
provides additional evidence about the sources of productivity improvements. They
-
Grinblatt
1440 Titman: FinancialV. Incentives, Information,
20. Mergers and
© The McGraw
1440 HillMarkets and Corporate
and Corporate Control
Acquisitions
Companies, 2002
Strategy, Second Edition
714Part VIncentives, Information, and Corporate Control
documented significant post-LBO reductions in the ratio of white-collar to blue-collar
labor, reflecting perhaps a reduction in excess overhead. In addition, Smith (1990)
found strong evidence that working capital is reduced after LBOs.
The Direction of Causation forthe LBO Cash Flow Improvement.The increase
in cash flows following LBOs may not solely reflect improvements resulting from the
LBOs. Perhaps firms that undergo leveraged buyouts would have shown similar
improvements without the LBOs. Managers and LBO sponsors are unlikely to consider
an LBO of a firm for which business prospects are forecasted to be unfavorable. There-
fore, firms that undergo LBOs are likely to experience subsequent increases in their
cash flows even without productivity improvements. In addition, some of the observed
increase in the cash flows of LBOs probably can be explained by the selection process
of LBO candidates. However, we are unaware of any convincing evidence on this.
Cost Deferral as an Explanation forthe LBO Cash Flow Improvement.Another
explanation for the observed increase in cash flows following LBOs is that higher lever-
age ratios provide managers with an incentive to increase cash flows in the short run
at the expense of their long-run cash flows (see Chapter 16). Critics of leveraged buy-
outs say that after initiating a leveraged buyout, firms improve their cash flows in the
short run by deferring maintenance, cutting R&D, and reducing advertising and pro-
motion budgets. If these actions were the prime cause of the observed increase in cash
flows, then one would expect the increase to be reversed later. Although it is certainly
plausible that some of the increase in cash flows can be explained by this possibility,
we again are unaware of any convincing evidence suggesting that part of the short-term
gain in cash flows comes at the expense of long-term cash flows.
Smith (1990), Lichtenberg and Siegel (1990), and Opler (1993) found that post-
LBO research and development expenditures do not generally decline. However, this
may not be particularly relevant since most firms that have done LBOs belong to indus-
tries that conduct little R&D. Smith (1990) also found no significant reductions in
advertising or maintenance following LBOs, but she is cautious about interpreting these
results because of the limited size of her sample.
-
Result 20.7
On average, cash flows of firms improve following leveraged buyouts. Three possible expla-nations for these improvements are:
-
•
Productivity gains.
•
Initiation of LBOs by firms with improving prospects.
•
The incentives of leveraged firms to accelerate cash flows, sometimes at the expenseof long-run cash flows.
While we expect all three factors to contribute to the observed increase in cash flows, existing
empirical evidence suggests that a major part of the increase is due to productivity gains.