
- •Intended Audience
- •1.1 Financing the Firm
- •1.2Public and Private Sources of Capital
- •1.3The Environment forRaising Capital in the United States
- •Investment Banks
- •1.4Raising Capital in International Markets
- •1.5MajorFinancial Markets outside the United States
- •1.6Trends in Raising Capital
- •Innovative Instruments
- •2.1Bank Loans
- •2.2Leases
- •2.3Commercial Paper
- •2.4Corporate Bonds
- •2.5More Exotic Securities
- •2.6Raising Debt Capital in the Euromarkets
- •2.7Primary and Secondary Markets forDebt
- •2.8Bond Prices, Yields to Maturity, and Bond Market Conventions
- •2.9Summary and Conclusions
- •3.1Types of Equity Securities
- •Volume of Financing with Different Equity Instruments
- •3.2Who Owns u.S. Equities?
- •3.3The Globalization of Equity Markets
- •3.4Secondary Markets forEquity
- •International Secondary Markets for Equity
- •3.5Equity Market Informational Efficiency and Capital Allocation
- •3.7The Decision to Issue Shares Publicly
- •3.8Stock Returns Associated with ipOs of Common Equity
- •Ipo Underpricing of u.S. Stocks
- •4.1Portfolio Weights
- •4.2Portfolio Returns
- •4.3Expected Portfolio Returns
- •4.4Variances and Standard Deviations
- •4.5Covariances and Correlations
- •4.6Variances of Portfolios and Covariances between Portfolios
- •Variances for Two-Stock Portfolios
- •4.7The Mean-Standard Deviation Diagram
- •4.8Interpreting the Covariance as a Marginal Variance
- •Increasing a Stock Position Financed by Reducing orSelling Short the Position in
- •Increasing a Stock Position Financed by Reducing orShorting a Position in a
- •4.9Finding the Minimum Variance Portfolio
- •Identifying the Minimum Variance Portfolio of Two Stocks
- •Identifying the Minimum Variance Portfolio of Many Stocks
- •Investment Applications of Mean-Variance Analysis and the capm
- •5.2The Essentials of Mean-Variance Analysis
- •5.3The Efficient Frontierand Two-Fund Separation
- •5.4The Tangency Portfolio and Optimal Investment
- •Identification of the Tangency Portfolio
- •5.5Finding the Efficient Frontierof Risky Assets
- •5.6How Useful Is Mean-Variance Analysis forFinding
- •5.8The Capital Asset Pricing Model
- •Implications for Optimal Investment
- •5.9Estimating Betas, Risk-Free Returns, Risk Premiums,
- •Improving the Beta Estimated from Regression
- •Identifying the Market Portfolio
- •5.10Empirical Tests of the Capital Asset Pricing Model
- •Is the Value-Weighted Market Index Mean-Variance Efficient?
- •Interpreting the capm’s Empirical Shortcomings
- •5.11 Summary and Conclusions
- •6.1The Market Model:The First FactorModel
- •6.2The Principle of Diversification
- •Insurance Analogies to Factor Risk and Firm-Specific Risk
- •6.3MultifactorModels
- •Interpreting Common Factors
- •6.5FactorBetas
- •6.6Using FactorModels to Compute Covariances and Variances
- •6.7FactorModels and Tracking Portfolios
- •6.8Pure FactorPortfolios
- •6.9Tracking and Arbitrage
- •6.10No Arbitrage and Pricing: The Arbitrage Pricing Theory
- •Verifying the Existence of Arbitrage
- •Violations of the aptEquation fora Small Set of Stocks Do Not Imply Arbitrage.
- •Violations of the aptEquation by Large Numbers of Stocks Imply Arbitrage.
- •6.11Estimating FactorRisk Premiums and FactorBetas
- •6.12Empirical Tests of the Arbitrage Pricing Theory
- •6.13 Summary and Conclusions
- •7.1Examples of Derivatives
- •7.2The Basics of Derivatives Pricing
- •7.3Binomial Pricing Models
- •7.4Multiperiod Binomial Valuation
- •7.5Valuation Techniques in the Financial Services Industry
- •7.6Market Frictions and Lessons from the Fate of Long-Term
- •7.7Summary and Conclusions
- •8.1ADescription of Options and Options Markets
- •8.2Option Expiration
- •8.3Put-Call Parity
- •Insured Portfolio
- •8.4Binomial Valuation of European Options
- •8.5Binomial Valuation of American Options
- •Valuing American Options on Dividend-Paying Stocks
- •8.6Black-Scholes Valuation
- •8.7Estimating Volatility
- •Volatility
- •8.8Black-Scholes Price Sensitivity to Stock Price, Volatility,
- •Interest Rates, and Expiration Time
- •8.9Valuing Options on More Complex Assets
- •Implied volatility
- •8.11 Summary and Conclusions
- •9.1 Cash Flows ofReal Assets
- •9.2Using Discount Rates to Obtain Present Values
- •Value Additivity and Present Values of Cash Flow Streams
- •Inflation
- •9.3Summary and Conclusions
- •10.1Cash Flows
- •10.2Net Present Value
- •Implications of Value Additivity When Evaluating Mutually Exclusive Projects.
- •10.3Economic Value Added (eva)
- •10.5Evaluating Real Investments with the Internal Rate of Return
- •Intuition for the irrMethod
- •10.7 Summary and Conclusions
- •10A.1Term Structure Varieties
- •10A.2Spot Rates, Annuity Rates, and ParRates
- •11.1Tracking Portfolios and Real Asset Valuation
- •Implementing the Tracking Portfolio Approach
- •11.2The Risk-Adjusted Discount Rate Method
- •11.3The Effect of Leverage on Comparisons
- •11.4Implementing the Risk-Adjusted Discount Rate Formula with
- •11.5Pitfalls in Using the Comparison Method
- •11.6Estimating Beta from Scenarios: The Certainty Equivalent Method
- •Identifying the Certainty Equivalent from Models of Risk and Return
- •11.7Obtaining Certainty Equivalents with Risk-Free Scenarios
- •Implementing the Risk-Free Scenario Method in a Multiperiod Setting
- •11.8Computing Certainty Equivalents from Prices in Financial Markets
- •11.9Summary and Conclusions
- •11A.1Estimation Errorand Denominator-Based Biases in Present Value
- •11A.2Geometric versus Arithmetic Means and the Compounding-Based Bias
- •12.2Valuing Strategic Options with the Real Options Methodology
- •Valuing a Mine with No Strategic Options
- •Valuing a Mine with an Abandonment Option
- •Valuing Vacant Land
- •Valuing the Option to Delay the Start of a Manufacturing Project
- •Valuing the Option to Expand Capacity
- •Valuing Flexibility in Production Technology: The Advantage of Being Different
- •12.3The Ratio Comparison Approach
- •12.4The Competitive Analysis Approach
- •12.5When to Use the Different Approaches
- •Valuing Asset Classes versus Specific Assets
- •12.6Summary and Conclusions
- •13.1Corporate Taxes and the Evaluation of Equity-Financed
- •Identifying the Unlevered Cost of Capital
- •13.2The Adjusted Present Value Method
- •Valuing a Business with the wacc Method When a Debt Tax Shield Exists
- •Investments
- •IsWrong
- •Valuing Cash Flow to Equity Holders
- •13.5Summary and Conclusions
- •14.1The Modigliani-MillerTheorem
- •IsFalse
- •14.2How an Individual InvestorCan “Undo” a Firm’s Capital
- •14.3How Risky Debt Affects the Modigliani-MillerTheorem
- •14.4How Corporate Taxes Affect the Capital Structure Choice
- •14.6Taxes and Preferred Stock
- •14.7Taxes and Municipal Bonds
- •14.8The Effect of Inflation on the Tax Gain from Leverage
- •14.10Are There Tax Advantages to Leasing?
- •14.11Summary and Conclusions
- •15.1How Much of u.S. Corporate Earnings Is Distributed to Shareholders?Aggregate Share Repurchases and Dividends
- •15.2Distribution Policy in Frictionless Markets
- •15.3The Effect of Taxes and Transaction Costs on Distribution Policy
- •15.4How Dividend Policy Affects Expected Stock Returns
- •15.5How Dividend Taxes Affect Financing and Investment Choices
- •15.6Personal Taxes, Payout Policy, and Capital Structure
- •15.7Summary and Conclusions
- •16.1Bankruptcy
- •16.3How Chapter11 Bankruptcy Mitigates Debt Holder–Equity HolderIncentive Problems
- •16.4How Can Firms Minimize Debt Holder–Equity Holder
- •Incentive Problems?
- •17.1The StakeholderTheory of Capital Structure
- •17.2The Benefits of Financial Distress with Committed Stakeholders
- •17.3Capital Structure and Competitive Strategy
- •17.4Dynamic Capital Structure Considerations
- •17.6 Summary and Conclusions
- •18.1The Separation of Ownership and Control
- •18.2Management Shareholdings and Market Value
- •18.3How Management Control Distorts Investment Decisions
- •18.4Capital Structure and Managerial Control
- •Investment Strategy?
- •18.5Executive Compensation
- •Is Executive Pay Closely Tied to Performance?
- •Is Executive Compensation Tied to Relative Performance?
- •19.1Management Incentives When Managers Have BetterInformation
- •19.2Earnings Manipulation
- •Incentives to Increase or Decrease Accounting Earnings
- •19.4The Information Content of Dividend and Share Repurchase
- •19.5The Information Content of the Debt-Equity Choice
- •19.6Empirical Evidence
- •19.7Summary and Conclusions
- •20.1AHistory of Mergers and Acquisitions
- •20.2Types of Mergers and Acquisitions
- •20.3 Recent Trends in TakeoverActivity
- •20.4Sources of TakeoverGains
- •Is an Acquisition Required to Realize Tax Gains, Operating Synergies,
- •Incentive Gains, or Diversification?
- •20.5The Disadvantages of Mergers and Acquisitions
- •20.7Empirical Evidence on the Gains from Leveraged Buyouts (lbOs)
- •20.8 Valuing Acquisitions
- •Valuing Synergies
- •20.9Financing Acquisitions
- •Information Effects from the Financing of a Merger or an Acquisition
- •20.10Bidding Strategies in Hostile Takeovers
- •20.11Management Defenses
- •20.12Summary and Conclusions
- •21.1Risk Management and the Modigliani-MillerTheorem
- •Implications of the Modigliani-Miller Theorem for Hedging
- •21.2Why Do Firms Hedge?
- •21.4How Should Companies Organize TheirHedging Activities?
- •21.8Foreign Exchange Risk Management
- •Indonesia
- •21.9Which Firms Hedge? The Empirical Evidence
- •21.10Summary and Conclusions
- •22.1Measuring Risk Exposure
- •Volatility as a Measure of Risk Exposure
- •Value at Risk as a Measure of Risk Exposure
- •22.2Hedging Short-Term Commitments with Maturity-Matched
- •Value at
- •22.3Hedging Short-Term Commitments with Maturity-Matched
- •22.4Hedging and Convenience Yields
- •22.5Hedging Long-Dated Commitments with Short-Maturing FuturesorForward Contracts
- •Intuition for Hedging with a Maturity Mismatch in the Presence of a Constant Convenience Yield
- •22.6Hedging with Swaps
- •22.7Hedging with Options
- •22.8Factor-Based Hedging
- •Instruments
- •22.10Minimum Variance Portfolios and Mean-Variance Analysis
- •22.11Summary and Conclusions
- •23Risk Management
- •23.2Duration
- •23.4Immunization
- •Immunization Using dv01
- •Immunization and Large Changes in Interest Rates
- •23.5Convexity
- •23.6Interest Rate Hedging When the Term Structure Is Not Flat
- •23.7Summary and Conclusions
- •Interest Rate
- •Interest Rate
20.5The Disadvantages of Mergers and Acquisitions
The preceding section described a number of benefits associated with mergers and
acquisitions, but there can also be offsetting disadvantages. The prevailing view of
mergers has changed substantially over time. Investors and analysts have become more
skeptical about potential gains from M&Aand more aware of the potential downside
of combining two firms. This change in the prevailing view is especially true for the
pure conglomerate acquisitions. In the 1960s, conglomerate acquisitions were in fashion
and acquiring firms were rewarded with rising stock prices. The kind of logic illus-
trated in Example 20.1 was generally accepted by the market. However, for the reasons
discussed below, diversifying takeovers have been viewed much more negatively since
the 1980s.
11See Grossman and Hart (1986) for further discussion along these lines.
-
Grinblatt
1424 Titman: FinancialV. Incentives, Information,
20. Mergers and
© The McGraw
1424 HillMarkets and Corporate
and Corporate Control
Acquisitions
Companies, 2002
Strategy, Second Edition
706Part VIncentives, Information, and Corporate Control
Conglomerates Can Misallocate Capital
Combining two firms can destroy value if the managers of the combined firm use the
added flexibility to transfer resources between the two firms to subsidize money-losing
lines of businesses that would otherwise be shut down. Subsidization of this sort is
likely to occur if the firm’s top management is reluctant to cut jobs or has other rea-
sons to keep a losing business in operation. For example, the CEO may not want to
admit that a past decision was a mistake. Hence, the information asymmetries and
incentive problems that can lead financial markets to allocate capital inefficiently also
create even greater problems when managers allocate capital internally. Robert D.
Kennedy, chairman of Union Carbide, a company that was involved in a number of
conglomerate acquisitions, summarized this point as follows:
All that stuff about balancing the cash generators and the cash users sounded great on paper.
But it never worked. When corporate management gets into the business of allocating
resources between businesses crying for cash, it makes mistakes.12
Mergers Can Reduce the Information Contained in Stock Prices
When two firms combine, there is generally one less publicly traded stock. This can
create a cost if stock prices convey information that helps managers to allocate
resources. For example, McDonald’s may have interpreted the rise in its stock price in
the early 1990s to improving opportunities in the growing economies of Southeast Asia.
This “stock market opinion” might have led McDonald’s to expand its efforts in that
part of the world. However, if McDonald’s were instead part of a large conglomerate,
its executives would not have been able to observe market prices and would have had
to make their investment decisions based on more subjective information.
As Chapter 18 noted, the information from stock prices also is useful for com-
pensating and evaluating management. We observed that it is much easier to tie the
compensation of Compaq’s CEO to his performance than it is to tie pay to performance
for the head of IBM’s PC division because there is no observable stock price for IBM’s
PC division. In addition to providing motivation, Compaq’s stock price provides a sig-
nal to shareholders of their CEO’s effectiveness. In contrast, IBM’s stock price con-
tains much less information about the success of any of its individual divisions.
ASummary of the Gains and Costs of Diversification
The past two sections have covered the advantages and disadvantages of purely diver-
sifying takeovers. These are summarized in the following result:
-
Result 20.4
The advantages of diversification can be described as follows:
-
•
Diversification enhances the flexibility of the organization.
•
The internal capital market avoids some of the information problems inherent in an
external capital market.
•
Diversification reduces the probability of bankruptcy for any given level of debt andincreases the firm’s debt capacity.
•
Competitors find it more difficult to uncover proprietary information from
diversified firms.
12“Learning Business Week,Nov. 7, 1988.
to Live with Leverage,”
Grinblatt |
V. Incentives, Information, |
20. Mergers and |
©
The McGraw |
Markets and Corporate |
and Corporate Control |
Acquisitions |
Companies, 2002 |
Strategy, Second Edition |
|
|
|
-
Chapter 20
Mergers and Acquisitions
707
-
•
Diversification is advantageous if it allows the firm to utilize its organization more
effectively.
The disadvantages of diversification can be described as follows:
-
•
Diversification can eliminate a valuable source of information which may, amongother things, make it difficult to compensate the division heads of large diversifiedfirms efficiently.
•
Managers may find it difficult to cut back optimally on losing divisions when theycan subsidize the losers out of the profits from their winners.
20.6 |
Empirical Evidence on TakeoverGains forNon-LBO Takeovers |
Anumber of academics and policymakers have asked whether, on average, mergers
create value. In other words, are the various financial and operating synergies discussed
in this chapter real, or are purported synergies merely a convenient rationale offered
by managers attempting to expand their empires? This section reviews a number of
studies that attempt to measure the value created by mergers.
Three types of studies have sought to determine the extent to which non-LBO
takeovers are value enhancing. The first type analyzes stock returns around the time of
the announcements of tender offers and merger offers, and it attributes the gains and
losses in stock prices to expected gains associated with combining the firms, improv-
ing management, or identifying undervalued assets. The second type of study looks
more specifically at whether diversified firms are either more or less valuable than non-
diversified firms. The third type of study examines accounting data to determine the
change, if any, in the profitability of the target firm’s business after it has been absorbed
by the bidder.
Stock Returns around the Time of Takeover Announcements
Stock market studies look at the returns of both bidding firms and target firms. The
sum of the two returns determines whether mergers create value.
Returns of Target Firms.Stock market evidence strongly indicates that target share-
holders gain from a successful takeover. This is not surprising given that target share-
holders require a premium as an inducement to sell their shares to the acquiring firm.
Jensen and Ruback (1983) reported that, on average, target shares increase in price from
about 16 to 30 percent around the date of the announcement of a tender offer. Evidence
by Jarrell, Brickley, and Netter (1988) found that these returns increased substantially
during the 1980s to an average of about 53 percent. Jensen and Ruback (1983) reported
that the average return to target firms in negotiated merger offers is only about 10 percent.
Returns of BidderFirms.Returns to bidders around tender offer announcements are
sometimes positive and sometimes negative, and the average returns vary considerably
over time. Jarrell and Poulsen (1989) reported that the announcement return to bidders
in tender offers dropped from a statistically significant 5 percent gain in the 1960s to
an insignificant 1 percent loss in the 1980s. This finding can be attributed in part to
regulations that are disadvantageous to the bidder and perhaps to increased competition
among bidders for specific targets. One also can interpret this finding as an indication
that either the number of bad takeovers has been increasing or bidders have been pay-
ing too much in recent years.
-
Grinblatt
1428 Titman: FinancialV. Incentives, Information,
20. Mergers and
© The McGraw
1428 HillMarkets and Corporate
and Corporate Control
Acquisitions
Companies, 2002
Strategy, Second Edition
708Part VIncentives, Information, and Corporate Control
Summary of Bidderand Target Returns.Adding the bidder and target returns
implies that, on average, there is a net gain to shareholders around the time of the
merger announcement. Bradley, Desai, and Kim (1988) found that successful tender
offers increased the combined values of the merging firms an average of 7.4 percent
or $117 million (stated in 1984 dollars), which suggests that mergers are, on average,
value enhancing.
Result 20.5 summarizes how stock prices react at the time of takeover announce-
ments.
-
Result 20.5
Stock price reactions to takeover bids can be described as follows:
-
•
The stock prices of target firms almost always react favorably to merger and tenderoffer bids.
•
The bidder’s stock price sometimes goes up and sometimes goes down, dependingon the circumstances.
•
The combined market values of the shares of the target and bidder go up, onaverage, around the time of the announced bids.
Interpreting the Stock Return Evidence.As Chapter 19 discussed, the stock price
reaction on the announcement of a corporate decision cannot be attributed solely to
how the decision affects the firm’s profitability. The stock returns of the bidder at the
time of the announcement of the bid may tell us more about how the market is reassess-
ing the bidder’s business than it does about the value of the acquisition. Indeed, stock
prices may react favorably to the announcement of an acquisition, even when investors
believe the acquisition harms shareholders.
For example, a tender offer, especially one for cash, may indicate that the bidding
firm has been highly profitable in the past, given that it had accumulated the financial
ability to make the offer. Hence, the bidding firm’s stock price may increase even if
the market views the acquisition as a negative NPVproject. Indeed, stock prices react
very favorably to a firm purchasing its own stock because of the information this deci-
sion conveys, even though a share repurchase is a zero NPVinvestment. Given that
thestock price reaction around the time of the announcement of an offer for another
firm’s stock is generally much weaker, one might conclude that the market, on average,
views these acquisitions as negative NPVinvestments.
Stock Returns and the Means of Payment.The way in which a bidder pays for the
target can have a major effect on how the bidder’s stock reacts to the announced bid.
Franks, Harris, and Mayer (1988) and Travlos (1987) demonstrated that average bid-
der returns differ significantly, depending on whether the bidder offers cash or shares
of its own stock in exchange for the target’s shares. For example, Travlos found that
in U.S. acquisitions financed by an exchange of stock, the bidding firm’s stock prices
fell 1.47 percent, on average, on the two days around the offer’s announcement. Franks,
Harris, and Mayer found a similar negative return for equity-financed bidders in both
the United States and the United Kingdom. Both studies found that the market price of
the bidder reacted favorably to announcements of cash acquisitions, but the returns, on
average, were quite small. The returns on the two days around the announcement of a
cash offer, as reported by Travlos, were only marginally different from zero (0.24 per-
cent) and the monthly returns around the announcements of cash offers reported in
Franks, Harris, and Mayer were 2.0 percent in the United States and 0.7 percent in the
United Kingdom.
Grinblatt |
V. Incentives, Information, |
20. Mergers and |
©
The McGraw |
Markets and Corporate |
and Corporate Control |
Acquisitions |
Companies, 2002 |
Strategy, Second Edition |
|
|
|
-
Chapter 20
Mergers and Acquisitions
709
Chapter 19 provides two explanations for why bidders who make cash offers expe-
rience higher returns. Bidders offer stock when they believe their own stock is over-
valued, but offer cash when they believe their own stock is undervalued. In addition,
a cash offer may signal that the bidder is able to obtain the financial backing of a bank
or other financial institution. Astock offer may then signal that the banks refused to
provide the bidder with financial backing, reflecting badly on the bidder’s financial
strength.
-
Result 20.6
The bidder’s stock price reacts more favorably, on average, when the bidder makes a cashoffer rather than an offer to exchange stock. This may reflect the relatively negative infor-mation about the bidder’s existing business signaled by the offer to exchange stock.
During the technology, software, and Internet stock boom of the late 1990s and
first quarter of 2000 there were a number of mergers where acquirers in these indus-
tries used stock for acquisitions. There was a popular belief at the time that the stock
prices of these firms were overvalued and bidders often saw their stock prices drop
substantially on the announcement of a stock-financed acquisition.
Information Conveyed about the Target.Abidding firm does not only reveal infor-
mation about itself when bidding for another company. If the financial markets believe
that a bidder has special information about a target, then a bid also is likely to convey
information to the market about the value of the target as a stand-alone company. One
can obtain insights about the extent to which special information about a target is
revealed by examining stock price reactions when offers are terminated.
Share prices tend to decline subsequent to the failure of an initial bid, but the prices
generally stay considerably above the stock price for the target that existed before the
bid [see Bradley (1980), Dodd (1980), and Bradley, Desai and Kim (1983)]. This evi-
dence could indicate that the bidders have some special information because, if the
gains were all due to either improved management or synergies, the stock price theo-
retically should drop back to its original level after a failed bid.
Bradley, Desai, and Kim suggested a different interpretation. They pointed out that
the relatively small decline in share prices when initial bids fail may not occur because
the initial bid signaled that the firm was undervalued, but because most failed targets
do eventually get taken over. Indeed, a failed bid is often due to a better offer; there-
fore, the stock price may eventually exceed the price level attained after the initial
acquisition announcement. The authors found that one to five years after the first price-
raising bid, the average share prices of targets that were not subsequently acquired by
any firm returned to the level that existed before the initial offer. This would suggest
that the bidder generally had no special information and that undervalued assets were
not the motivation for the takeovers.
In the Bradley, Desai, and Kim sample, only 26 of 371 target firms (about 7 per-
cent) were not acquired once they were “put into play,” making it difficult to make
strong inferences about the motivation of the initial bidders—whether the bidders felt
they could actually improve the values of the firms or believed that the firms were
undervalued.
In the 1980s, there were substantially more takeover attempts that failed, and many
were not subsequently taken over, making it easier to examine some of the hypothe-
ses considered by Bradley, Desai, and Kim. Safieddine and Titman (1999) examined
573unsuccessful takeover attempts during the 1982–1991 period and found that, on
average, target stock prices declined 5.14 percent on the termination date. This decline
-
Grinblatt
1432 Titman: FinancialV. Incentives, Information,
20. Mergers and
© The McGraw
1432 HillMarkets and Corporate
and Corporate Control
Acquisitions
Companies, 2002
Strategy, Second Edition
710Part VIncentives, Information, and Corporate Control
is smaller than the average increase when the takeover offers were originally
announced, suggesting that either the takeover announcement conveyed information
about the target’s value or, alternatively, that the offer created value, even if the offer
subsequently failed.
In contrast to Bradley, Desai, and Kim’s earlier sample, fewer than half of the tar-
gets of failed takeover bids in the 1982–1991 period were subsequently taken over.
Moreover, more than two-thirds of the failed targets that stayed independent substan-
tially increased their leverage ratios. Many of them implemented restructuring strate-
gies that were similar to the strategies that would have been imposed on them by their
hostile suitor. In particular, there was a tendency of the leverage increasing failed tar-
gets to sell assets, reduce investment, reduce employment, and increase focus. These
firms subsequently performed quite well. This evidence suggests that value is often cre-
ated by takeover offers even when they fail and the firm is not subsequently taken over.
Perhaps, the threat of additional takeover attempts provides management with the incen-
tives to cut wasteful spending and investment and to take other steps that create value
for their shareholders.
Empirical Evidence on the Gains to Diversification
Whether there are gains associated with takeovers depends, in part, on whether diver-
sification helps or hurts firm values. Anumber of empirical studies have documented
that U.S. corporations increased their level of diversification from the early 1960s to
the mid-1970s, in many cases through acquisitions. Starting in the late 1970s, U.S. firms
decreased their level of diversification and continued to do so throughout the 1980s
and 1990s, as many of the earlier acquisitions were spun off or divested.13
Anumber of empirical studies have examined whether diversification increases or
decreases firm values. Lang and Stulz (1994) and Berger and Ofek (1995) found that
the market places lower values on more diversified firms. Comment and Jarrell (1995),
who examined changes in diversification during the 1980s, found that firms destroy
value when they diversify and create value when they sell off divisions and become
more focused. Servaes (1996) found that the market’s attitude toward diversification
depends on the time period studied. In contrast with the earlier findings of diversifica-
tion discounts in the 1980s, Servaes found no significant valuation penalty associated
with diversification in the 1970s. However, he did find significant diversification penal-
ties in the 1960s, as well as the 1980s. Finally, Denis, Denis, and Sarin (1997) found
that the tendency of firms to diversify is related to ownership structure. They found
that firms managed by individuals who own more of the company’s shares are less
diversified. This finding supports the idea that the diversification discount at least par-
tially reflects the tendency to diversify for managerial benefits when there are insuffi-
cient incentives to maximize share value.
Astudy by Morck, Shleifer, and Vishny (1990) provided evidence consistent with
the change in attitudes about diversification during the 1970s and 1980s.14Their study
related the stock returns of bidders around the announcement dates of acquisition bids
to characteristics of both the bidder and the target, measuring the extent to which the
firms were in related lines of business. They found that bidder stock returns for
13
See Comment and Jarrell (1995) and Servaes (1996).
14A
related study by Matsusaka (1993) found that the stock prices of conglomerates responded
positively in the 1960s when they announced acquisitions, but responded negatively to similar announce-
ments in the 1980s.
Grinblatt |
V. Incentives, Information, |
20. Mergers and |
©
The McGraw |
Markets and Corporate |
and Corporate Control |
Acquisitions |
Companies, 2002 |
Strategy, Second Edition |
|
|
|
-
Chapter 20
Mergers and Acquisitions
711
diversifying acquisitions (that is, an acquisition of an unrelated firm) were lower in the
1980s, when they were negative, than they were in the 1970s. For nondiversifying
acquisitions, however, bidder stock returns increased somewhat in the 1980s. The dif-
ference in the announcement returns between diversifying and nondiversifying acqui-
sitions was only 1.31 percent in the 1970s, but it was 6.97 percent in the 1980s.
Accounting Studies
Because stock price reactions reflect the information conveyed by an offer, it is diffi-
cult to use stock returns to draw inferences about the operating synergies or the eco-
nomic efficiency generated by a merger. For this reason, some researchers have exam-
ined accounting data to draw inferences about the underlying economic impact of a
merger.
Evidence of Negative PostmergerPerformance.In their comprehensive study,
Ravenscraft and Scherer (1987) investigated more than 5,000 mergers occurring
between 1950 and 1975. Using accounting data for each of the different lines of busi-
ness in which the firms were involved, they calculated and compared the postmerger
performance of acquired firms with the performance of nonacquired control groups in
the same industry. On average, they found significant declines in the postmerger prof-
itability of the acquired portions of those firms.
The Wealth TransferInterpretation.The evidence in the Ravenscraft and Scherer
study is inconsistent with the view that mergers create value. However, the interpreta-
tion of these results has been the subject of much disagreement. First, the validity ofthe
results depends on the accuracy of the accounting numbers, which have been ques-
tioned by a number of authors. Second, the mergers may be creating value even if the
targets appear to be doing poorly after the takeover. This will be the case if enough
wealth is transferred from the acquired firm to the acquirer. For example, Texas Air
acquired Eastern Airlines in 1986 for $600 million. Subsequent to the Eastern bank-
ruptcy, some of Eastern’s creditors suggested that wealth was transferred from Eastern
to Texas Air. After only four months, Eastern sold a number of jumbo jets (at what
some considered to be favorable prices) to Continental (also owned by Texas Air) and
sold Eastern’s reservation system to the parent firm. Finally, the accounting perfor-
mance of acquired firms will appear to be unfavorable if the targets are generally firms
with poor prospects. Although these firms perform poorly subsequent to being taken
over, they might have performed even worse had they remained independent.
Tobin’s qand the Interpretation of Mediocre Accounting Performance.Hasbrouck
(1985) offered support for the view that targets frequently are firms in decline. Has-
brouck assessed each firm’s Tobin’sq,the ratio of the market value of the firm’s assets
to the replacement value of the assets, which can be viewed as a measure of manage-
rial performance. Well-managed firms have a high Tobin’s qvalue; poorly managed
firms have a low Tobin’s q. Hasbrouck found that target companies have relatively low
values of Tobin’s q; target shares are often selling at a value below their replacement
cost. In addition, several studies [see, for example, Asquith (1983)], have found that tar-
gets tend to experience lower returns than firms of comparable risk in the years before
the merger. Hence, relative to either their past stock prices or their replacement values,
target share prices are low at the time of the initial offer, indicating that investors were
somewhat pessimistic about the target’s prospects as a stand-alone entity. This suggests
-
Grinblatt
1436 Titman: FinancialV. Incentives, Information,
20. Mergers and
© The McGraw
1436 HillMarkets and Corporate
and Corporate Control
Acquisitions
Companies, 2002
Strategy, Second Edition
712Part VIncentives, Information, and Corporate Control
that the subsequent mediocre postmerger accounting performance of firms may have
occurred even if the acquisition had not taken place.
Evidence of Positive PostmergerPerformance.Healy, Palepu, and Ruback (1992)
examined 50 large mergers between 1979 and 1983 and found improvements in both
sales and profits of the combined firms following the mergers. This evidence suggests
that the mergers of the early 1980s may have been quite different from those of the
1960s and 1970s examined by Ravenscraft and Scherer. As mentioned earlier, the moti-
vation for many of the mergers of the 1960s and 1970s was diversification, and there
can be efficiency losses associated with diversification. However, diversification was a
less important motivation for mergers in the 1980s, a decade in which many takeovers
were motivated by the potential gains from improving managerial incentives. The
Healy, Palepu, and Ruback evidence suggests that in many cases productivity did
improve as a result of the takeovers.
Amore comprehensive study by Andrade, Mitchell, and Stafford (2001) examined
approximately 2000 mergers during the 1973 to 1998 period. Their results suggest that
the combined target and acquirer operating margins improve by about 1 percent sub-
sequent to the merger.