Добавил:
Upload Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:

International_Economics_Tenth_Edition (1)

.pdf
Скачиваний:
563
Добавлен:
10.06.2015
Размер:
30.47 Mб
Скачать

Chapter 5

149

Orderly Marketing Agreements

Manufactured Good

Principal Nations

Accord Provisions

Specialty steel

United States, European

 

Union, Sweden, Japan,

 

Canada

TV sets

Japan, Benelux, Britain

Ships

Japan, European Union

Garments and textiles

41 exporting and importing

 

nations

Autos

Japan, United States

Japan negotiates export quota in U.S. market; United States imposes import quota on others.

Japan voluntarily limits exports to Britain and Benelux.

Japan enters into agreement with European Union to curb price competition.

Export and import quotas; annual growth rates.

Japan voluntarily restrains exports to the United States.

1111111'/1.1111'/111 III 1111 111111 II

Source: Annual Reportof the President of the UnitedStateson the Trade Agreements Program (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, various issues).

States, Japan, and Germany. Assume that Su,s, and Du.s. depict the supply and demand schedules of autos for the United States. SJ denotes the supply schedule of Japan, assumed to be the world's lowcost producer, and SG denotes the supply schedule of Germany.

Referring to Figure 5.4(a), the price of autos to the U.S. consumer is $20,000 under free trade. At that price, U.S. firms produce 1 auto, and U.S. consumers purchase 7 autos, with imports from Japan totaling 6 autos. Note that German autos are too costly to be exported to the United States at the free-trade price.

Suppose that Japan, responding to protectionist sentiment in the United States, decides to restrain auto shipments to the United States rather than face possible mandatory restrictions on its exports. Assume that the Japanese government imposesan export quota on its auto firms of 2 units, down from the free-trade level of 6 units. Above the free-trade price, the total U.S. supply of autos now equals U.S. production plus the export quota; the auto supply curve thus shifts from Su.s. to Su.s.+Q in Figure 5.4(a). The reduction in imports from 6 autos to 2 autos raises the equilibrium price to $30,000. This leads to an increase in the quanti-

ty supplied by u.s. firms from 1 auto to 3 autos and a decrease in the U.S. quantity demanded from 7 autos to 5 autos.

The export quota's price increase causes consumer surplus to fall by area a + b + c + d + e + f + g + h + i + j + k + I, an amount totaling $60,000. Area a + h ($20,000) represents the transfer to U.S. auto companies as profits. The export quota results in a deadweight welfare loss for the U.S. economy equal to the protective effect, denoted by area b + c + i ($10,000), and the consumption effect, denoted by area f + g + I ($10,000). The export quota's revenue effect equals area d + e + j + k ($20,000), found by multiplying the quotainduced increase in the Japanese price times the volume of autos shipped to the United States.

Remember that under an import quota, the disposition of the revenue effect is indeterminate: It will be shared between foreign exporters and domestic importers, depending on the relative concentration of bargaining power. But under an export quota, it is the foreign exporter who is able to capture the larger share of the quota revenue. In our example of the auto export quota, the Japanese exporters, in compliance with their government, self-regulate shipments to the United

150

Nontariff Trade Barriers

FIGURE 5.4

Trade and Welfare Effects of a Voluntary Export Quota

(01Japanese Export Quota (b) Japanese Export Quota with German Exports

~

~

0

0

e.

e.

e

.~

;E

Q:

QL...L_--'---------L_--'---------L_--'---------L_--'-----"----_

4

7

4

7

Quantity of Autos

 

Quantity of Autos

 

Byreducingavailable supplies of a product, an export quota (levied by the foreign nation) leads to higher prices in the importing nation. The priceincrease induces a decrease in consumer surplus. Of this amount, the welfare loss to the importing nation equals the protectiveeffect, the consumption effect. andthe portion of the revenue effect that iscaptured by the foreign exporter. Tothe extent that nonrestrained countries augment shipments to the importing nation, the welfare loss of an export quota decreases.

1 111111111111111

States. This supply-side restriction, resulting from japanese firms' behaving like a monopoly, leads to a scarcity of autos in the United States. japanese auto makers then are able to raise the price of their exports, capturing the quota revenue. For this reason, it is not surprising that exporters might prefer to negotiate a voluntary restraint pact in lieu of facing other protectionist measures levied by the importing country. As for the export quota's impact on the U.S. economy, the expropriation of revenue by the japanese represents a welfare loss in addition to the deadweight losses of production and consumption.

Another characteristic of a voluntary export agreement is that it typically applies only to the most important exporting nation(s). This is in contrast to a tariff or import quota, which generally applies to imports from all sources. When volun-

tary limits are imposed on the chief exporter, the exports of the nonrestrained suppliers may be stimulated. Nonrestrained suppliers may seek to increase profits by making up part of the cutback in the restrained nation's shipments. They may also want to achieve the maximum level of shipments against which to base any export quotas that might be imposed on them in the future. For example, japan was singled out by the United States for restrictions in textiles during the 1950s and in color television sets during the 1970s. Other nations quickly increased shipments to the United States to fill in the gaps created by the japanese restraints. Hong Kong textiles replaced most japanese textiles, and TV sets from Taiwan and Korea supplanted japanese sets.

Referring to Figure 5.4(b), let us start again at the free-trade price of $20,000, with U.S. imports

from japan totaling 6 autos. Assume that japan agrees to reduce its shipments to 2 units. However, suppose Germany, a nonrestrained supplier, exports 2 autos to the United States in response to

the japanese cutback. Above the free-trade price, the total u.s. supply of autos now equals U.S. pro-

duction plus the Japanese export quota plus the nonrestrained exports coming from Germany. In Figure 5.4(b), this is illustrated by a shift in the supply curve from Su.s. to Su.S.+Q+N'The reduction in imports from 6 autos to 4 autos raises equilibrium price to $25,000. The resulting deadweight losses of production and consumption inefficiencies equal area b + g ($5,000), less than the deadweight losses under japan's export quota in the absence of nonrestrained supply. Assuming that japan administers the export restraint program, japanese companies would be able to raise the price of their auto exports from $20,000 to $25,000 and earn profits equal to area c + d ($10,000). Area e + (($10,000) represents a trade-diversion effect, which reflects inefficiency losses due to the shifting of 2 units from japan, the world's low-cost producer, to Germany, a higher-cost source. Such trade diversion results in a loss of welfare to the world because resources are not being used in their most productive manner. The overall welfare of the United States thus decreases by area b + c + d + e + ( + g under the export-quota policy.

When increases in the nonrestrained supply offset part of the cutback in shipments that occurs under an export quota, the overall inefficiency loss for the importing nation (deadweight losses plus revenue expropriated by foreign producers) is lessthan that which would have occurred in the absence of nonrestrained exports. In the preceding example, this reduction amounts to area i + j + k + I ($15,000). The next section will consider the effects of voluntary export quotas on the U.S. auto industry.

Japanese Auto Restraints Put Brakes on U.S. Motorists

In 1981, as domestic auto sales fell, protectionist sentiment gained momentum in the U.S. Congress, and legislation was introduced calling for import quotas. This momentum was a major factor in the

Chapter 5

151

administration's desire to negotiate a voluntary restraint pact with the japanese. japan's acceptance of this agreement was apparently based on its view that voluntary limits on its auto shipments would derail any protectionist momentum in Congress for more stringent measures.

The restraint program called for self-imposed export quotas on japanese auto shipments to the United States for three years, beginning in 1981. First-year shipments were to be held to 1.68 million units, 7.7 percent below the 1.82 million units exported in 1980. In subsequent years, auto shipments were to be held to the same number plus 16.5 percent of any increase in domestic U.S. auto sales recorded in 1981. As it turned out, falling U.S. sales caused japanese auto exports to be limited to 1.68 million units in 1982 and 1983. Still facing a weak auto industry, the United States was able to negotiate an export restraint pact with japan for 1984, during which japanese firms would limit auto shipments to the United States to 1.85 million units. In 1984, the United States released japan from its formal commitment to the export agreement, but the japanese government thought it imprudent to permit its automakers to export freely to the United States. The japanese government has imposed its own export quotas on its auto manufacturers since the termination of the export agreement.

The purpose of the export agreement was to help u.s. automakers by diverting u.s. customers from japanese to u.s. showrooms. As domestic sales increased, so would jobs for American autoworkers. It was assumed that japan's export quota would assist the U.S. auto industry as it went through a transition period of reallocating production toward smaller, more fuel-efficient autos and adjusting production to become more cost-competitive. The restraint program would provide U.S. auto companies temporary relief from foreign competition so they could restore profitability and reduce unemployment.

Not all japanese auto manufacturers were equally affected by the export quota. By requiring japanese auto companies to form an export cartel against the U.S. consumer, the quota allowed the large, established firms (Toyota, Nissan, and Honda) to increase prices on autos

152

Nontariff Trade Barriers

sold in the United States. To derive more revenues from a limited number of autos, Japanese firms shipped autos to the United States with fancier trim, bigger engines, and more amenities such as air-conditioners and deluxe stereos as standard equipment. Product enrichment also helped the Japanese broaden their hold on the U.S. market and enhance the image of their autos. As a result, the large Japanese manufacturers earned record profits in the United States.

The export quota was unpopular, however, with smaller japanese automakers, including Suzuki and Isuzu. Under the restraint program, as administered by the japanese government, each company's export quota was based on the number of autos sold in the United States three years prior to initiation of the quota. Smaller producers claimed that the quota forced them to freeze their U.S. dealer networks and abandon plans to introduce new models. Table 5.4 depicts the estimated welfare effectsfor the United States of the japanese export quota.

TABLE 5.4

Effects of Japanese Export Quota in Autos'

Effect

Amount

Price of Japanese autos sold in

 

the United States (increase)

$1,300

Price of U.S. autos sold in the

 

United States (increase)

$660

Cost to U.S. consumers (increase)

$15.7 million

Number of Japanese autos sold in

 

the United States (decrease)

1 million units

Japanese share of U.S. auto

 

market (decrease)

9.6%

Sales of U.S.-produced autos

 

(increase)

618,000 units

U.S. auto industry jobs

 

(increase)

44,000

 

 

 

 

'These estimates apply to 1984, the fourth year of the export quota.

Source: U.s. International Trade Commission, A Review of Recent Developments in the U.S. AutomobileIndustry Including an Assessment of the Japanese Voluntary Restraint Agreements (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1985).

Dom~stic Content S-xA'Y

Requirements

Today, many products, such as autos and aircraft, embody worldwide production. Domestic manufacturers of these products purchase resources or perform assembly functions outside the home country, a practice known as outsourcing or production sharing. For example, General Motors has obtained engines from its subsidiaries in Mexico, Chrysler has purchased ball joints from Japanese producers, and Ford has acquired cylinder heads from European companies. Firms have used outsourcing to take advantage of lower production costs overseas, including lower wage rates. Domestic workers often challenge this practice, maintaining that outsourcing means that cheap foreign labor takes away their jobs and imposes downward pressure on the wages of those workers who are able to keep their jobs.

To limit the practice of outsourcing, organized labor has lobbied for the use of domestic content requirements. These requirements stipulate the minimum percentage of a product's total value that must be produced domestically if the product is to quality for zero tariff rates. The effect of content requirements is to pressure both domestic and foreign firms who sell products in the home country to use domestic inputs (workers) in the production of those products. The demand for domestic inputs thus increases, contributing to higher input prices. Manufacturers generally lobby against domestic content requirements, because they prevent manufacturers from obtaining inputs at the lowest cost, thus contributing to higher product prices and loss of competitiveness.

Worldwide, local content requirements have received most attention in the automobile industry. Developing countries have often used content requirements to foster domestic automobile production, as shown in Table 5.5.

Figure 5.5 illustrates possible welfare effects of an Australian content requirement on automobiles. Assume that DA denotes the Australian demand schedule for Toyota automobiles while 5J depicts the supply price of Toyotas exported to Australia,

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Chapter 5

153

 

TABt::E 5.5

 

 

$24,000. With free trade, Australia imports 500

 

 

 

 

Toyotas. japanese resource owners involved in

 

 

Domestic Content Requirements Applied to

 

manufacturing this vehicle realize incomes totaling

 

 

 

$12 million, denoted by area c + d.

 

 

Automobiles in Selected Countries

 

 

 

 

Suppose the Australian government imposes a

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Minimum Domestic Content

domestic content requirement on autos. This poli-

 

 

 

cy causes Toyota to establish a factory in Australia

 

 

Required (Percent) to Qualify for

 

 

Country

Zero Duty Rates

 

to produce vehicles replacing the Toyotas previous-

 

 

 

 

 

Argentina

76%

 

ly imported by Australia. Assume that

the trans-

 

 

plant factory combines japanese management with

 

 

Mexico

62

 

 

 

Brazil

60

 

Australian resources (labor and materials) in vehi-

 

 

Uruguay

60

 

cle production. Also assume that high Australian

 

Vietnam

60

 

resource prices (wages) cause the transplant's sup-

 

Chinese Taipei

40

 

 

 

ply price to be $33,000, denoted by ST'Under the

 

Venezuela

30

 

 

 

content

requirement,

Australian

consumers

 

Colombia

30

 

 

 

 

 

 

demand

300 vehicles.

Because production has

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

SOUTce: U.S. Department

of Commerce, International

Trade

shifted from japan to Australia, japanese resource

 

 

owners lose $12 million of income. Australian

 

Administration, Office of

Automotive Affairs, Vehicle

Import

 

 

Requirements, December 2003, at http://www.ita.doc.gov/auto/impreq.

resource owners gain $9.9 million of income (area

 

htrnl.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

FIGURE 5.5

Welfare Effects of a Domestic Content Requirement

~

 

 

 

~

 

 

 

0

 

 

 

e. 33,000

 

 

ST

OJ

 

 

U

 

 

'C

 

 

c,

 

 

 

24,000

SJ

 

o L -

...L-

---'-

"'----_ _+_

 

300

500

 

Quantity of Toyotas

A domestic content requirement leadsto rising production costs and pricesto the extent that manufacturers are "forced" to locate production facilities in a high-cost nation. Although the content requirement helps preserve domestic jobs, it imposeswelfare losses on domestic consumers.

12

1!lllllm

154

Nontariff Trade Barriers

 

 

Did you know that U.S. buyers of cars and light trucks can learn how American or foreign their new vehicle is? On carsand trucks weighing 8,500 pounds or less, the law requires content labels telling buyers where the parts of the vehicle were made. Content is measured by the dollar value of components, not the labor cost of assembling vehicles. The percentages of North American (tl.S. and Canadian) and foreign parts must be listed as

an average for each car line. Manufacturers are free to design the label, which can be included on the price sticker or fuel economy sticker or can be separate. Below are some examples of the domestic and foreign content of vehicles sold in the United States for the 2004 model year. The data were collected from automobile stickers at dealers' lots.

 

 

 

North American

Foreign

 

 

Vehicle

Assembly

Parts Content (percent)

Parts Content (percent)

 

 

Ford Taurus

United States

95%

5%

 

 

Ford Focus

United States

80

20

 

 

Ford Crown Victoria

Canada

95

5

 

 

Lincoln Navigator

United States

90

5

 

 

GMC Yukon

United States

65

35

 

 

Pontiac Vibe AWD

United States

64

36

 

 

Cadillac Deville

United States

86

14

 

 

DaimlerChrysler Durango

United States

77

23

 

 

Chevrolet Suburban

Mexico

65

35

 

 

Chevrolet Tahoe

United States

65

35

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

a + c) minus the income paid to Japanese managers and the return to Toyota's capital investment (factory) in Australia.

However, the income gains of Australian resource owners inflict costs on Australian consumers. Because the content requirement causes the price of Toyotas to increase by $9,000, Australian consumer surplus decreases by area a + b ($3,600,000). Of this amount, area b ($900,000) is a deadweight welfare loss for Australia. Area a ($2,700,000) is the consumer cost of employing higher-priced Australian resources instead of lower-priced Japanese resources; this amount represents a redistribution of welfare from Australian consumers to Australian resource owners. Similar to other import restrictions, content requirements

lead to the subsidizing by domestic consumers of the domestic producer.

I Subsidies

National governments sometimes grant subsidies to their producers to help improve their trade position. By providing domestic firms a cost advantage, a subsidy allows them to market their products at prices lower than warranted by their actual cost or profit considerations. Governmental subsidies assume a variety of forms, including outright cash disbursements, tax concessions, insurance arrangements, and loans at below-market interest rates. Table 5.6 provides examples of governmental subsidies for several nations.

Chapter 5

155

TABId! 5.6

Examples of Governmental Subsidies

Country

Subsidy Policy

Australia

Export market development grants extended to Australian exporters to seek

 

out and develop overseas markets

Canada

Rail transportation subsidies granted to Canadian exporters of wheat, barley,

 

oats, and alfalfa

European Union

Export subsidies provided to many agricultural products such as wheat, beef,

 

poultry, fruits, and dairy products; financial assistance extended to Airbus

Japan

Financial assistance extended to Japanese aerospace producers, including

 

loans at low interest rates and assistance with R&D costs

United States

Export subsidies provided to U.S. producers of agricultural and manufactured

 

goods through the Commodity Credit Corporation and the Export Import Bank

Source: Office of the U.S. Trade Representative, Foreiqn Trade Barriers (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, various issues).

For purposes of our discussion, two types of subsidies can be distinguished: a domestic subsidy, which is sometimes granted to producers of importcompeting goods, and an export subsidy, which goes to producers of goods that are to be sold overseas. In both cases, the government adds an amount to the price the purchaser pays rather than subtracting from it. The net price actually received by the producer equals the price paid by the purchaser plus the subsidy. The subsidized producer is thus able to supply a greater quantity at each consumer's price. Let us use Figure 5.6 on page 156 to analyze the effects of these two types of subsidies.

Domestic Subsidy

Figure 5.6(a) illustrates the trade and welfare effects of a production subsidy granted to importcompeting manufacturers. Assume that the initial supply and demand schedules of the United States for steel are depicted by curves Su.s.oand Du.s.o' so that the market equilibrium price is $430 per ton. Assume also that, because the United States is a small buyer of steel, changes in its purchases do not affect the world price of $400 per ton. Given a free-trade price of $400 per ton, the United States consumes 14 tons of steel, produces 2 tons, and imports 12 tons.

To partially insulate domestic producers from foreign competition, suppose the U.S. government grants them a production subsidy of $25 per ton of steel. The cost advantage made possible by the subsidy results in a shift in the U.S. supply schedule from 5u.s.1) to 5u.s. 1Domestic production expands from 2 to 7 million tons, and imports fall from 12 to 7 million tons. These changes represent the subsidy's trade effect.

The subsidy also affects the national welfare of the United States. According to Figure 5.6(a), the subsidy permits U.S. output to rise to 7 million tons. Note that, at this output, the net price to the steelmaker is $425-the sum of the price paid by the consumer ($400) plus the subsidy ($25). To the U.S. government, the total cost of protecting its steelmakers equals the amount of the subsidy ($25) times the amount of output to which it is applied (7 million tons), or $175 million.

Where does this subsidy revenue go? Part of it is redistributed to the more efficient U.S. producers in the form of producer surplus. This amount is denoted by area a ($112.5 million) in the figure. There is also a protective effect, whereby more costly domestic output is allowed to be sold in the market as a result of the subsidy. This is denoted by area b ($62.5 million) in the figure. To the

156 Nontariff Trade Barriers

FUiuRE 1.1

,

Trade and Welfare Effects of Subsidies

101

Domestic Subsidy

 

]~ ~~~

p~CJ(

.~

"-_......400

\evel d67S

litO\- C 0.01VI..¥)

 

s, S I

~;~a~~i1D1

 

 

 

-: .'. 'O'1ffO~~~

 

 

 

Co~ J P'WlOij.

 

 

 

 

[----.-------- ~

1

~~l'

 

 

of:.-'u

YI' ,.\><,,1. ,,\

~ ~V'

]

125

"<>",~,P~__#::;:~~~~y~":~~!:.:,v=-/. ,,~#'

100

f-

s;

g

 

 

 

~~~ i

75

;j:--

 

 

"

COVl(W'V\Qn:

 

 

 

Dos o

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Dr 0 h(}! .e-A?ccJ.J----'----'-------'------~

 

 

 

15

 

 

 

 

_"

VlO CO YIJ~lA/fliIph0n

 

 

14

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Steel (Millions of Tansi

 

 

 

Quantity of TVs[Millions]

 

 

 

 

k(~cA--

 

 

 

 

 

r',

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

A' ,

I

e...1itri--government su y grante

 

to Import-competing pro ucers eadsto mcrease

 

omestic pro

u Ion

I m-~.tcLtl\Je

 

'J..,.. I'If::

bsidSl

d

 

i

lnc orod

I

i

d d

 

'

dcti

(,{¥

-n,\I (J 0-

.

pM) dJ1~'nd reduced imports. The subsidy revenue accruing to the producer is absorbed by producer surplus

(J\-

c\OV\,lJ_S.lI G

and high-cost production (protective effect), A government subsidy granted to exporters results in an

~c\.RC.Q.~..5 li'ho export revenue effect and a terms-of-trade effect.

 

 

 

 

 

 

lm't\~

b)

 

1111111

 

 

1 IliA

1111

 

 

 

 

 

 

a:v t

v..

••--------------------------------6161161116--1-

\( ~:~eq)V"en~

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

6J..l~V\..L\ q\\4- \1%.5>

 

 

 

 

Subsidies are not free goods, however, for they

 

 

 

 

 

United States as a whole, the protective effect rep-

 

 

 

 

 

resents a deadweight loss of welfare.

must be financed by someone, The direct cost of

 

 

 

 

 

To encourage production by its import-com-

the subsidy is a burden that must be financed out

 

 

 

 

 

peting manufacturers, a government might levy

of tax revenues paid by the public. Moreover,

 

 

 

 

 

tariffs or quotas on imports. But tariffs and quotas

when a subsidy is given to an industry, it is often

 

 

 

 

 

involve larger sacrifices in national

welfare than

in return for accepting government conditions on

 

 

 

 

 

would occur under an equivalent subsidy. Unlike

key matters (such is wage and salary levels). Thus

 

 

 

 

 

subsidies, tariffs and quotas distort choices for

a subsidy may not be as superior to other types of

 

 

 

 

 

domestic consumers (resulting in a decrease in the

commercial policies as this analysis suggests.

 

 

 

 

 

domestic demand for imports), in addition to per-

Export Subsidy

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

mitting less efficient home production to occur.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

The result is the familiar consumption effect of

Besides attempting to protect import-competing

 

 

 

 

 

protection, whereby a deadweight loss of con-

industries, many national governments grant subsi-

 

 

 

 

 

sumer surplus is borne by the home nation, This

dies, including special tax exemptions and the pro-

 

 

 

 

 

welfare loss is absent in the subsidy case. Thus, a

vision of capital at favored rates, to increase the

 

 

 

 

 

subsidy tends to yield the same result for domestic

volume of exports. By providing a cost advantage

 

 

 

 

 

producers as does an equivalent tariff or quota,

to domestic producers, such subsidies are intended

 

 

 

 

 

but at a lower cost in terms of national welfare.

to encourage a

nation's

exports

by reducing the

price paid by foreigners. Foreign consumers are favored over domestic consumers to the extent that the foreign price of a subsidized export is less than the product's domestic price.

The granting of an export subsidy yields two direct effects for the home economy: a terms-of- trade effect and an export-revenue effect. Because subsidies tend to reduce the foreign price of home-nation exports, the home nation's terms of trade is worsened. But lower foreign prices generally stimulate export volume. Should the foreign demand for exports be relatively elastic, so that a given percentage drop in foreign price is more than offset by the rise in export volume, the home nation's export revenues will increase.

Figure 5.6(b) illustrates the case of an export subsidy applied to television sets in trade between Japan and the United States. Under free trade, market equilibrium exists at point E, where Japan exports 1 million television sets to the United States at a price of $100 per unit. Suppose the Japanese government, to encourage export sales, grants to its exporters a subsidy of $50 per set. The Japanese supply schedule shifts from 510 to 511, and market equilibrium moves to point F. The terms of trade thus turns against Japan because its export price falls from $100 to $75 per television set exported. Whether Japan's export revenue rises depends on how U.S. buyers respond to the price decrease. If the percentage increase in the number of television sets sold to U.S. buyers more than offsets the percentage decrease in price, Japan's export revenue will rise. This is the case in Figure 5.6(b), which shows Japan's export revenue rising from $100 million to $112.5 million as the result of the decline in the price of its export good.

Although export subsidies may benefit industries and workers in a subsidized industry by increasing sales and employment, the benefits may be offset by certain costs that fall on the society as a whole. Consumers in the exporting nation suffer as the international terms of trade moves against them. This situation comes about because, given a fall in export prices, a greater number of exports must be exchanged for a given dollar amount in imports. Domestic consumers also find they must pay higher prices than foreigners for the goods they

Chapter 5

157

help subsidize. Furthermore, to the extent that taxes are required to finance the export subsidy, domestic consumers find themselves poorer. In the previous example, the total cost of the subsidy to Japanese taxpayers is $75 million ($50 subsidy times 1.5 million television sets).

IDumping

The case for protecting import-competing producers from foreign competition is bolstered by the antidumping argument. Dumping is recognized as a form of international price discrimination. It occurs when foreign buyers are charged lower prices than domestic buyers for an identical product, after allowing for transportation costs and tariff duties. Selling in foreign markets at a price below the cost of production is also considered dumping.

Forms of Dumping

Commercial dumping is generally viewed as sporadic, predatory, or persistent in nature. Each type is practiced under different circumstances.

Sporadic dumping (distress dumping) occurs when a firm disposes of excess inventories on foreign markets by selling abroad at lower prices than at home. This form of dumping may be the result of misfortune or poor planning by foreign producers. Unforeseen changes in supply and demand conditions can result in excess inventories and thus in dumping. Although sporadic dumping may be beneficial to importing consumers, it can be quite disruptive to import-competing producers, who face falling sales and short-run losses. Temporary tariff duties can be levied to protect home producers, but because sporadic dumping has minor effects on international trade, governments are reluctant to grant tariff protection under these circumstances.

Predatory dumping occurs when a producer temporarily reduces the prices charged abroad to drive foreign competitors out of business. When the producer succeeds in acquiring a monopoly position, prices are then raised commensurate with its market power. The new price level must be sufficiently high to offset any losses that occurred during the period of cutthroat pricing. The firm would

158 Nontariff Trade Barriers

presumably be confident in its ability to prevent the entry of potential competitors long enough for it to enjoy economic profits. To be successful, predatory dumping would have to be practiced on a massive basis to provide consumers with sufficientopportunity for bargain shopping. Home governments are generally concerned about predatory pricing for monopolizing purposes and may retaliate with antidumping duties that eliminate the price differential. Although predatory dumping is a theoretical possibility, economists have not found empirical evidence that supports its existence.

Persistent dumping, as its name suggests, goes on indefinitely. In an effort to maximize economic profits, a producer may consistently sell abroad at lower prices than at home. The rationale underlying persistent dumping is explained in the next section.

International Price

Discrimination

Consider the case of a domestic seller that enjoys market power as a result of barriers that restrict

'IGURE 1.11

International Price Discrimination

competition at home. Suppose this firm sells in foreign markets that are highly competitive. This means that the domestic consumer response to a change in price is less than that abroad; the home demand is less elastic than the foreign demand. A profit-maximizing firm would benefit from international price discrimination, charging a higher price at home, where competition is weak and demand is less elastic, and a lower price for the same product in foreign markets to meet competition. The practice of identifying separate groups of buyers of a product and charging different prices to these groups results in increased revenues and profits for the firm as compared to what would occur in the absence of price discrimination.

Figure 5.7 illustrates the demand and cost conditions of South Korean Steel Inc. (SKS), which sells steel to buyers in South Korea (less elastic market) and in Canada (more elastic market); the total steel market consists of these two submarkets. Let DSK be the South Korean steel demand and Dc be the Canadian demand, with the corresponding marginal revenue schedules represented

 

South Korea

 

 

 

Canada

 

 

Total

Morket

 

 

(Less Elastic Submorket)

(More Elastic Submorket)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

0;-

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

j;

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

0

 

 

 

 

0;-

 

 

 

 

 

 

0

 

 

 

 

700

 

'"

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

J?

 

 

 

 

Q)

 

 

 

 

o

 

 

u

 

 

 

u

 

 

 

 

 

 

d:

 

 

 

""

 

 

 

 

o

 

 

 

 

 

 

c,

 

 

 

 

~

500

 

500

 

 

 

500

 

 

 

 

;:E

 

 

400

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

2001 --- 4 -

 

 

 

 

 

300

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

- 200

 

 

 

 

 

o '-----------'-~

o '--------'"-----

0

 

 

 

 

 

25

35

10

20

30

 

15

30

45

60

 

Steel (Tons)

 

 

Steel (Tons)

 

 

Steel (Tons)

 

A price-discriminating firm maximizes profits by equating marginal revenue, in each submarket, with marginal cost. The firm will charge a higher price in the less-elastic-demand (less competitive) market and a lower price in the more-elastic-demand (more competitive) market. Successful dumping leads to additional revenue and profits for the firm compared to what would be realized in the absenceof dumping.

lUI. III

rrrr ~u '~ 'l1innill nunn [ [ 11.1