
- •Contents
- •General editors’ preface
- •Preface
- •Contributors
- •Table of legislation
- •Austria
- •Belgium
- •England
- •Finland
- •France
- •Germany
- •Greece
- •Italy
- •Portugal
- •Scotland
- •Spain
- •Sweden
- •The Netherlands
- •Austria
- •Belgium
- •Finland
- •France
- •Germany
- •Greece
- •Italy
- •Portugal
- •Spain
- •Sweden
- •The Netherlands
- •Abbreviations
- •1 The notion of pure economic loss and its setting
- •Introduction
- •Pure vs. consequential economic loss
- •Actor’s state of mind: intention vs. negligence
- •The standard cases: a taxonomy
- •Ricochet loss
- •Transferred loss
- •Closure of public markets, transportation corridors and public infrastructures
- •Present vs. future loss
- •In the scale of human values
- •In historical perspective
- •2 The rule against recovery in negligence for pure economic loss: an historical accident?
- •Introduction
- •Continental law before the nineteenth century
- •The Roman texts
- •The natural law schools
- •The nineteenth and twentieth centuries
- •Germany
- •Before the code
- •England
- •Conclusion
- •3A Pure economic loss: an economic analysis
- •Introduction
- •Basic institutions of the market economy
- •Basic rights
- •Freedom of contract
- •Private property
- •Liability
- •Stable legal environment
- •Stable currency
- •Open markets
- •Procedural guarantees
- •Relationship between public bodies
- •Relationships between public bodies and citizens
- •Externalities, rent seeking and dynamic markets
- •Looking at the cases
- •Conclusion
- •A concise summary
- •The economics of pure economic loss
- •Socially relevant externalities and the optimal scope of liability
- •Pure economic loss as a social cost
- •Pure economic loss: towards an economic restatement
- •In search of comparable categories: a hypothesis
- •Recasting the economic loss rule
- •Practical problems in the application of the economic loss rule
- •The problem of foreseeability of pure economic losses
- •Problems of derivative and open-ended litigation
- •Conclusion
- •4 American tort law and the (supposed) economic loss rule
- •Introduction: the relative unimportance of an exclusionary rule in the United States
- •Products liability as an exception
- •Rationales of the rule
- •Contexts and cases
- •Conclusion
- •5 The liability regimes of Europe – their façades and interiors
- •Introduction
- •Two alternative formulas: from façades to operative rules
- •General vs. specific characteristics
- •The liberal, pragmatic and conservative regimes of tort
- •The liberal regimes of France, Belgium, Italy, Spain and Greece
- •France – an enigmatic liberalism
- •In the Belgian looking glass
- •Italy’s recent revolution
- •The Spanish countercurrents
- •Greece’s liberal credentials
- •The pragmatic regimes of England, Scotland and the Netherlands
- •England’s cautious and pragmatic judges
- •Scotland: an ambiguous pragmatism
- •A middle path in the Netherlands
- •The conservative regimes of Germany, Austria, Portugal, Sweden and Finland
- •Germany: narrow in tort but wide in contract
- •The transformed general clause
- •The resort to contractual actions
- •Portugal’s continuous resort to German sources
- •Sweden and Finland: nulla injuria sine lege?
- •Conclusion
- •6 Preliminary remarks on methodology
- •Aim and method of the study
- •The common core approach
- •The three-level response
- •7 The case studies
- •National Reporters and the Editors
- •Comparative Commentary
- •Mauro Bussani and Vernon Valentine Palmer
- •Case 1: cable I – the blackout
- •Editors’ comparative comments
- •Case 2: cable II – the factory shutdown
- •Editors’ comparative comments
- •Case 3: cable III – the day-to-day workers
- •Editors’ comparative comments
- •Case 4: convalescing employee
- •Editors’ comparative comments
- •Case 5: requiem for an Italian all star
- •Editors’ comparative comments
- •Case 6: the infected cow
- •Editors’ comparative comments
- •Case 7: the careless architect
- •Editors’ comparative comments
- •Case 8: the cancelled cruise
- •Editors’ comparative comments
- •Case 9: fire in the projection booth
- •Case 10: the dutiful wife
- •Editors’ comparative comments
- •Case 11: a maestro’s mistake
- •Editors’ comparative comments
- •Case 12: double sale
- •Editors’ comparative comments
- •Case 13: subcontractor’s liability
- •Editors’ comparative comments
- •Case 14: poor legal services
- •Editors’ comparative comments
- •Editors’ comparative comments
- •Case 16: truck blocking entrance to business premises
- •Editors’ comparative comments
- •Case 17: auditor’s liability
- •Editors’ comparative comments
- •Case 18: wrongful job reference
- •Editors’ comparative comments
- •Case 19: breach of promise
- •Editors’ comparative comments
- •Case 20: an anonymous telephone call
- •Editors’ comparative comments
- •8 Summary and survey of the cases and results
- •Introduction
- •Reappraising the divides
- •Certainty vs. uncertainty
- •9 General conclusions of the study
- •Irrelevance of legal families
- •Absence of methodological common core
- •Awareness of the time factor
- •The substantive common core
- •Consequential loss
- •Intentional harm
- •Key areas of selective protection
- •Summary on the ‘limited common core’
- •Introduction
- •Pure economic loss astride private law frontiers
- •The place of pure economic loss within different possible frames of a tort law codification
- •Possible basic scenarios
- •A code imposing liability on the ground of a rigid typecast set of provisions
- •A tort law codification adopting a ‘general clause’: the selection of recoverable losses as the crucial choice
- •A destiny to be interpreted
- •Bibliography
- •Index
t h e l i a b i l i t y r e g i m e s o f e u r o p e |
139 |
The pragmatic regimes of England, Scotland and the Netherlands
England’s cautious and pragmatic judges
The dishevelled design of the English law of torts is due to the hand of history and the cumulative nature of common law growth. The disconnected structure, so different from the codified civil law, is the work of thousands of judicial architects and no central planners.59 Ancient torts such as trespass stand side-by-side with modern torts such as negligence. Nominate torts such as trespass to land or to goods, defamation and conversion make up a lengthy table of wrongful actions, but each is just a snapshot freezing a precise scenario into invariable elements and predictable endings. Compartmentalization – the absence of general principles connecting the nominate torts – is a leading characteristic. The tort of intimidation has nothing to do with the tort of mayhem; slander of title cannot be compared to slander of women.
The English façade tends to make a continental lawyer think more of the criminal law (where all crimes are typically nominate) than the law of tort.60 Most of these torts arose in defence of protecting a plaintiff’s life, limb and property and are far removed from affording relief for pure economic loss. For sure, there are a series of intentional economic torts, notably actions for deceit, interference with trade, inducing breach of contract, passing off, misfeasance in public office,61 intimidation and conspiracy, and if the defendant has intentionally caused such loss, the claim for pure economic loss may fit into one of these pigeonholes. If the loss was occasioned by negligence, however, these actions are unavailable. The plaintiff’s chief recourse must therefore be to the tort of negligence.
59‘No other European country has as many statutes imposing liability as England, yet, as in Ireland and Scotland, its non-contractual liability law remains essentially judge-made’, von Bar, Law of Torts, I, p. 267. As to the Irish tort law regime, which is substantially influenced by English patterns and rules, see, in comparative perspective, von Bar, Law of Torts, I, pp. 316 ff.
60C. von Bar, Law of Torts, I, at Rn. 254, p. 281. The language of the common law has always made a connection between civil and penal redress. ‘We ‘‘commit” a tort as we ‘‘commit” an offence. We can be ‘‘guilty” of either or both; and all our crimes are nominate’. Rudden, ‘Torticles’, at 126.
61Cf. S. Arrowsmith, Civil Liability and Public Authorities (Earlsgate Press, Winteringham, 1992). See David v. Abdul Cader [1963] 1 WLR 834; [1963] 3 All ER 579 (PC); and, obiter, X (some minors) v. Bedfordshire County Council [1995] 2 AC 633, [1995] 3 WLR 152, [1995] 3 All ER 353 (HL); Three Rivers DC and Others v. Governor and Company of the Bank of England
[2000] 2 WLR 1220 (HL).
140 m a u r o b u s s a n i a n d v e r n o n v a l e n t i n e p a l m e r
The generic tort of negligence would appear, at first glance, to hold great promise for the recovery of pure economic loss. Animated by the ‘neighbour principle’ which Donoghue v. Stevenson announced in 1932, this tort has been compared to a general clause covering all forms of negligent behaviour. This is generally true within the realm of protection from physical harm (bodily injury or damage to property).62 But according to a leading authority, Murphy v. Brentwood DC,63 negligence is not primarily applicable to the compensation of pure economic loss. This means that the nature of the plaintiff’s damage controls the existence of a duty to avoid causing it. Indeed, the common law as a matter of policy begins with the proposition that there is, as a rule, no duty of care to avoid causing pure economic loss. The occasions upon which such a duty is recognized are exceptional and must be kept so. This deep misgiving is based upon an instinctive fear of wide liability, customarily expressed by recourse to the floodgates metaphor or the ‘nightmare scenario’, but more fundamentally by a cautious case-by-case approach which studies the economic and social implications of each extension. The judges are willing to impose a ‘duty of care’ in the particular case brought before them only when satisfied on utilitarian grounds that it is socially and economically convenient to do so.
These exceptional cases are highly fact-sensitive and cover narrow fact situations. The exceptions began with Hedley Byrne & Co. Ltd v. Heller & Partners64 and then multiplied. The general principle of no liability for pure economic loss survives, but with a number of exceptions that may be increased in the future if the courts find it ‘fair, just and reasonable’ to do so.65 Thus far, the exceptions are limited to negligent misstatements made and relied upon (in a context of ‘virtual’ contract),66
621932 SC (HL) 31. Even here the principle has been overridden in certain exceptional situations where, for reasons of policy, it was inadvisable to impose a duty of care, though harm to plaintiff’s property was the foreseeable result of defendant’s negligence. See, for example, The Nicholas H [1995] 3 All ER 307.
63 [1991] AC 398. |
64 [1964] AC 465. |
65On the meaning of this phrase, which reserves judicial options for future development (in marked contrast to the more principled methodology announced in
Anns v. Merton London Borough Council [1978] AC 278), see, e.g. Caparo Industries Plc v.
Dickman [1990] 2 AC 605.
66Hedley Byrne, above [1964] AC 465. However, one should be aware that if, after a misrepresentation, the parties actually enter into a contract with each other, it is doubtful whether there is any practical need to resort to the rule of Hedley Byrne, since liability may end up being based on contract under s. 2(1) of the Misrepresentation Act 1967. The text provides that ‘Where a person has entered into a contract after a misrepresentation has been made to it by another party thereto and as a result
t h e l i a b i l i t y r e g i m e s o f e u r o p e |
141 |
negligent interference with the performance of a contract,67 negligent defamation in the writing of a reference for a former employee,68 professional negligence in the drawing up of a will69 and breach of statutory duty.70 What appears characteristic and consistent in these exceptions is the limited quantitative exposure of the defendant to a defined number of plaintiffs, or even better, a single plaintiff. The danger of unbounded financial repercussion is avoided. The total liability can be calculated in advance as not exceeding the value of a lost legacy, a lost job or lost investment. The plaintiff is a particular individual – the potential legatee of a will or a former employee – whose interests are very distinctly contemplated by the defendant at close range. But the presence of other factors which demonstrate a closer degree of proximity between the parties than mere foreseeability of economic harm may be insisted upon, such as defendant’s ‘assumption of responsibility’ for the plaintiff’s economic wellbeing coupled with the plaintiff’s reliance upon it.71 The class of claimants is thereby limited, as if an invisible privity paradigm structured the resulting bond in tort.72 It may be noted that although actions may be brought concurrently, a contract action cannot be used in these circumstances for there is no ‘consideration’ and therefore no contract
thereof he has suffered loss, then, if the person making the misrepresentation would be liable to damages in respect thereof had the misrepresentation been made fraudulently, that person shall be so liable notwithstanding that the
misrepresentation was not made frauduently, unless he proves that he had reasonable ground to believe and did believe up to the time the contract was made that the facts represented were true.’ Through this rule ‘the tort of negligence became otiose’ in this context: von Bar, Law of Torts, I, p. 449.
67Junior Books v. Veitchi [1983] 1 AC 520. This Scottish case, however, has been disapproved in almost every later English case. J. Stapleton, ‘Duty of Care Factors: A Selection from the Judicial Menus’, in P. Cane and J. Stapleton (eds.), The Law of Obligations: Essays in Honour of J. Fleming (1998), p. 59 and p. 80, fn. 82–3; J. M. Thomson, ‘A Prophet Not Rejected in His Own Land’, (1994) 110 Law Quarterly Review 361.
68Spring v. Guardian Assurance PLC [1993] 3 All ER 273 (CA).
69White v. Jones [1993] 3 All ER 481 (CA), [1995] 2 WLR 187 (HL).
70For relevant references, see von Bar, Law of Torts, I, pp. 328 ff.
71The phrase ‘assumption of responsibility’ originates in Hedley Byrne, [1964] AC 465, at 528 (Lord Devlin). It seems to make recourse to an underlying contract model to earmark occasions when it is appropriate to impose a duty of care: the assumption of responsibility and reliance upon it must be voluntary. See Lord Goff’s speech in Henderson v. Merrett Syndicate Ltd [1995] 2 AC 145, [1994] 3 All ER 506, discussing the role played by voluntariness. See also Banakas, ‘Liability for Incorrect Financial Information’, 261, 270–2; J. M. Thomson Delictual Liability (Butterworths, London, 1994), p. 59.
72The opposite view is maintained in Germany. See below footnotes 98 ff. and accompanying text.
142 m a u r o b u s s a n i a n d v e r n o n v a l e n t i n e p a l m e r
between plaintiff and defendant. Given its insistence on consideration, England’s rigid contract law cannot protect legal strangers against such losses. Therefore, it was faced with the choice either to expand its tort law opportunistically or to deny these actions altogether.73
The English judges express their pragmatism in an open manner. Policy decisions are not cloaked behind a particular view of causation or of culpa, as we have already noticed in several continental systems. The unlawfulness issue is isolated as a preliminary policy decision. Thus, in English law the façade of judge-made tort law approaches the inner reality of the process. The use of legal policy, especially in tort cases involving patrimonial injury, is a distinct feature of internal common law culture.74 Our national reporter cautions, however, that English legal policy should not be confused with continental concepts such as French notions of ordre public or the German concept of Treu und Glauben. He writes:
Unlike these Continental concepts, the English concept of legal policy does not assume a legal rule, for which it is, then, judicially used as a limit of its application, but creates one for the case under trial and for the future. A rule that will moreover, change, every time legal policy is invoked again.75
The English judges refuse to be driven by the logical implications of the neighbourhood principle into recognition of a wide theory of fault. Besides proximity and foreseeability, something else is required in order to summon forth a ‘duty of care’ in the field of patrimonial loss. The English judge wishes to remain architect of this common law development.
Scotland: an ambiguous pragmatism
Despite an official Roman and civil law façade, Scotland takes essentially the same pragmatic approach to the recovery of pure economic loss that we have just described in the case of England. There is a similar caution in screening new ‘duty situations’ on a case-by-case basis, and judges
73B. Markesinis, ‘An Expanding Tort Law – The Price of a Rigid Contract Law’, (1987) 103
Law Quarterly Review 354.
74Note, however, that an attempt was made in Henderson v. Merrett Syndicate Ltd [1995] 2 AC 145, [1994] 3 All ER 506, to lay down general criteria for the existence of a duty of care to protect pure economic loss without resort to a policy argument. According to J. M. Thomson, the importance of this case has not been sufficiently recognized.
Delictual Liability (2nd edn, Butterworths, London, pp. 85 ff., 1999). See also Banakas, ‘Liability for Incorrect Financial Information’, 261, 271, 277 ff.
75Introductory comments, on file with editors.
t h e l i a b i l i t y r e g i m e s o f e u r o p e |
143 |
carefully study the concrete socio-economic implications of extending the recovery of pure economic loss. Clearly, there is no general duty of care in Scotland to avoid causing mere financial injury. Leaving aside the case of intentionally caused economic harm, liability for economic loss based on negligence will generally coincide with the exceptional areas also recognized in England. A comparison of the two country reports is striking: the Scottish and English answers are remarkably similar to one another.76 From the comparative point of view, this seems to be an unsurprising case of insular convergence.
Scotland is the oldest ‘mixed jurisdiction’ in the world (its mixity dating from the Treaty of Union with England in 1707, and arguably well before that event) and the only jurisdiction of its kind within the European Union. It is characteristic of mixed jurisdictions to retain private civil law within a surrounding system of Anglo-American public law; it is also characteristic to find in such systems that the law of delict, which obviously lies within the retained civil law sphere, constitutes an area particularly open to common law fertilization and the reception of common law cases and doctrine.77 Scotland’s law of delict is not an exception to that process, though the nature and degree of integration and convergence may well be subject to differences of opinion. The sources of the law of delict in Scotland reflect the layered complexity of this field. According to D. M. Walker, the sources of Scottish law in general include ‘Roman law, indigenous custom, juristic interpretation, judicial modification, the influence of common law, and modern legislation’.78
In presenting the Roman and civil law façade to the reader, the Scottish writers take pride in stating that the law of delict has Roman roots and was elaborated by the usus modernus pandectarum. They studiously avoid the expression ‘law of torts’,79 carefully employ civilian terminology, and place emphasis upon the differences with English law.80 Perhaps the most notable of these differences, according to Walker, is
76This is quite apparent from our comparisons in Part III of this volume. The Scottish report records results, particularly the negative results, nearly identical to the English report. See Table 8.1, in Part III of this volume.
77V. Palmer (ed.), Mixed Jurisdictions Worldwide: The Third Legal Family (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 2001).
78D. M. Walker, The Law of Delict in Scotland, vol. I (Green, 1966), p. 17.
79Thus Walker’s Law of Delict in Scotland, vols. I, II; Thomson, Delictual Liability (1999); W. J. Stewart, Delict and Related Obligations (2nd edn, Green, 1993).
80Von Bar mentions some of the specific characteristics of the Scots law of delict: the less exalted role of trespass; the missing distinction between private and public nuisance; the absence of torts actionable per se; absence of the distinction between libel and slander; the rejection of punitive damages; and the non-adoption of Rylands v. Fletcher. Von Bar, Law of Torts, I, at Rn. 299, pp. 319–20.
144 m a u r o b u s s a n i a n d v e r n o n v a l e n t i n e p a l m e r
that Scottish law bases its law of delict on a general principle for wrongful conduct, not on a system of nominate torts.
The nomenclature of the English nominate torts, such as trespass, defamation and passing off, is well known and frequently used in Scotland, but Walker argues that in reality these names are ‘no more than convenient titles for sets of circumstances giving rise to liability under one or other of the general principles of delictual liability accepted in Scots law’.81 He stresses that while negligence is an independent nominate tort in England, in Scotland this is not so; when the term negligence is used it simply means damages for harm caused negligently.82 Zweigert and Kötz, who seem to accept the claim that civilian principle plays a dominant role in the Scottish law of delict, state that: ‘Scotland operates with only a few high-level principles and concepts, thereby demonstrating that inner economy which ‘‘civilian” thought regards as a virtue.’83 Despite this assurance, however, outsiders may wonder whether Scotland’s commitment to a wide civilian principle has had any measurable effect of expanding the scope of unlawfulness to include pure economic loss.84 That principle appears to be basically limited by judicial interpretation to a set of protected rights and interests which largely excludes pure patrimonial loss. Interestingly, though Scotland has neither the English requirement of consideration nor a rigid law of contract, it has not seen fit to make lateral recourse to expanded contract remedies in these instances.
In our view, the Scottish law of delict is essentially arranged around a fixed set of protected rights and interests.85 Norrie writes that ‘[t]he civil wrong of negligence [is] founded . . . on a moral imperative not to cause harm to others through carelessness’, and that much work of the judges in the twentieth century ‘has been devoted to the development of a unifying general principle (or at least a set of principles) governing negligence, explaining why some neglects are culpable and others are
81 Walker, Law of Delict in Scotland, vol. II at p. 487. |
82 Ibid, vol. I, pp. 44–5. |
83K. Zweigert and H. Kötz, Introduction to Comparative Law (2nd edn, Clarendon, Oxford, 1987), p. 210.
84Indeed one Scots jurist who is a specialist in this subject is sceptical of claims that a single principle really controls this issue in Scotland: ‘The question whether the defender owes a duty of care to the pursuer to prevent him sustaining ‘‘pure economic loss” is one which, even in Scots law, it appears cannot be answered by the application of a simple general principle of liability’, J. M. Thomson ‘Delictual Liability for Pure Economic Loss: Recent Developments’, 1995 SLT (News) 139.
85Thus Walker, who calls ‘breach of duty’ the fundamental concept of the modern Scottish law of delict, divides all breaches of duty into two categories: infringements of personality and damage to property, Law of Delict in Scotland, at pp. 31–2.