Добавил:
Upload Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:
Скачиваний:
668
Добавлен:
03.06.2015
Размер:
8.25 Mб
Скачать

456—Chapter 31. System Estimation

Constant Conditional Correlation (CCC)

Bollerslev (1990) specifies the elements of the conditional covariance matrix as follows:

hiit = ci + aieit2

– 1 + diIit– 1eit2

– 1

+ bihiit – 1

(31.55)

hijt

= rij hiithjjt

 

 

 

 

 

Restrictions may be imposed on the constant term using variance targeting so that:

 

ci = j02(1 – ai bi )

 

(31.56)

where j02 is the unconditional variance.

 

 

 

When exogenous variables are included in the variance specification, the user may choose between individual coefficients and common coefficients. For common coefficients, exogenous variables are assumed to have the same slope, g , for every equation. Individual coefficients allow each exogenous variable effect ei to differ across equations.

hiit = ci + aie2it – 1 + diIit– 1e2it – 1 + bihiit – 1 + eix1t + gx2t (31.57)

Diagonal BEKK

BEKK (Engle and Kroner, 1995) is defined as:

Ht = QQ¢ + Aet – 1et – 1¢A¢ + BHt – 1B¢

(31.58)

EViews does not estimate the general form of BEKK in which A and B are unrestricted. However, a common and popular form, diagonal BEKK, may be specified that restricts A and B to be diagonals. This Diagonal BEKK model is identical to the Diagonal VECH model where the coefficient matrices are rank one matrices. For convenience, EViews provides an option to estimate the Diagonal VECH model, but display the result in Diagonal BEKK form.

References

Andrews, Donald W. K. (1991). “Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimation,” Econometrica, 59, 817–858.

Andrews, Donald W. K. and J. Christopher Monahan (1992). “An Improved Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimator,” Econometrica, 60, 953–966.

Berndt, Ernst R. and David O. Wood (1975). “Technology, Prices and the Derived Demand for Energy,”

Review of Economics and Statistics, 57(3), 259-268.

Bollerslev, Tim (1990). “Modelling the Coherence in Short-run Nominal Exchange Rates: A Multivariate Generalized ARCH Model,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 72, 498–505.

Bollerslev, Tim, Robert F. Engle and Jeffrey M. Wooldridge (1988). “A Capital-Asset Pricing Model with Time-varying Covariances,” Journal of Political Economy, 96(1), 116–131.

Ding, Zhuanxin and R. F. Engle (2001). “Large Scale Conditional Covariance Matrix Modeling, Estimation and Testing,” Academia Economic Paper, 29, 157–184.

Engle, Robert F. and K. F. Kroner (1995). “Multivariate Simultaneous Generalized ARCH,” Econometric Theory, 11, 122-150.

References—457

Greene, William H. (1997). Econometric Analysis, 3rd Edition, Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

Newey, Whitney and Kenneth West (1994). “Automatic Lag Selection in Covariance Matrix Estimation,”

Review of Economic Studies, 61, 631-653.

458—Chapter 31. System Estimation

Chapter 32. Vector Autoregression and Error Correction

Models

The structural approach to time series modeling uses economic theory to model the relationship among the variables of interest. Unfortunately, economic theory is often not rich enough to provide a dynamic specification that identifies all of these relationships. Furthermore, estimation and inference are complicated by the fact that endogenous variables may appear on both the left and right sides of equations.

These problems lead to alternative, non-structural approaches to modeling the relationship among several variables. This chapter describes the estimation and analysis of vector autoregression (VAR) and the vector error correction (VEC) models. We also describe tools for testing the presence of cointegrating relationships among several non-stationary variables.

Vector Autoregressions (VARs)

The vector autoregression (VAR) is commonly used for forecasting systems of interrelated time series and for analyzing the dynamic impact of random disturbances on the system of variables. The VAR approach sidesteps the need for structural modeling by treating every endogenous variable in the system as a function of the lagged values of all of the endogenous variables in the system.

The mathematical representation of a VAR is:

 

yt = A1yt – 1 + º + Apyt p + Bxt + et

(32.1)

where yt is a k vector of endogenous variables, xt is a d vector of exogenous variables, A1, º, Ap and B are matrices of coefficients to be estimated, and et is a vector of innovations that may be contemporaneously correlated but are uncorrelated with their own lagged values and uncorrelated with all of the right-hand side variables.

Since only lagged values of the endogenous variables appear on the right-hand side of the equations, simultaneity is not an issue and OLS yields consistent estimates. Moreover, even though the innovations et may be contemporaneously correlated, OLS is efficient and equivalent to GLS since all equations have identical regressors.

As an example, suppose that industrial production (IP) and money supply (M1) are jointly determined by a VAR and let a constant be the only exogenous variable. Assuming that the VAR contains two lagged values of the endogenous variables, it may be written as:

IPt = a11IPt – 1 + a12M1t – 1 + b11IPt – 2 + b12M1t – 2 + c1 + e1t

(32.2)

M1t = a21IPt – 1 + a22M1t – 1 + b21IPt – 2 + b22M1t – 2 + c2 + e2t

Соседние файлы в папке EViews Guides BITCH