Добавил:
Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:

Nafziger Economic Development (4th ed)

.pdf
Скачиваний:
1961
Добавлен:
22.08.2013
Размер:
11.95 Mб
Скачать

466 Part Four. The Macroeconomics and International Economics of Development

Scope of the Chapter

LDCs encounter even greater limitations than DCs in using monetary and fiscal policies to achieve macroeconomic goals. The first section of this chapter discusses some of the limitations of monetary policy in LDCs. Next, we look at the low tax rates in LDCs. The third section examines tax policy goals, including limitations LDCs face in using various taxes. Political constraints on implementing tax policies are mentioned in the fourth section. A fifth section, on government expenditures, indicates the limits of using spending policies to stabilize income and prices. The sixth section, on the problem of inflation, analyzes worldwide inflation since 1970; the explanations for inflation; their benefits and costs; and the relationship between inflation and growth. The seventh section examines banking in LDCs, and financial repression and liberalization. The eighth section looks at the capital market and financial system; the ninth at financial instability; and the tenth at Islamic banking.

Limitations of Monetary Policy

In DCs, central banks (like the Bank of England or the U.S. Federal Reserve) can increase the supply of money by buying government bonds, lowering the interest rate charged commercial banks, and reducing these banks’ required ratio of reserves to demand deposits. The increased money supply and decreased interest rate should increase investment spending and raise output and employment during recession. And a decreased money supply should curtail investment, so that inflation is reduced.

The banking system, often limited in its ability to regulate the money supply to influence output and prices in DCs, is even more ineffective in LDCs. Usually, the money market in developing countries is externally dependent, poorly organized, fragmented, and cartelized (there will be more on this last point when we discuss financial repression later in this chapter).

1.Many of the major commercial banks in LDCs are branches of large private banks in DCs, such as Citigroup, Bank of America, J. P. Morgan Chase, or Barclay’s Bank. Their orientation is external: They are concerned with profits in dollars, euros, pound sterling, or other convertible currency, not rupees, nairas, pesos, and other currencies that cannot be exchanged on the world market.

2.Many LDCs are so dependent on international transactions that they must limit the banking system’s local expansion of the money supply to some multiple of foreign currency held by the central bank. Thus, the government cannot always control the money supply because of the variability of foreign exchange assets.

3.The LDC central banks do not have much influence on the amount of bank deposits. They generally make few loans to commercial banks. Furthermore, because securities markets are rarely well developed in LDCs, the central bank usually buys and sells few bonds on the open market.

4.Commercial banks generally restrict their loans to large and medium enterprises in modern manufacturing, mining, power, transport, construction, electronics

14. Monetary, Fiscal, and Incomes Policy and Inflation

467

and telecommunications, and plantation agriculture. Small traders, artisans, and farmers obtain most of their funds from close relatives or borrow at exorbitant interest rates from local money lenders and landlords. Thus, LDC banking systems have less influence than DCs on the interest rate, level of investment, and aggregate output.

5.Transactions deposits (checking accounts) as a percentage of the total money supply are generally lower in LDCs than DCs. In the United States, they make up three-fourths of the total money supply, but, in most developing countries, the figure is less than half. Checks are not widely accepted for payment in LDCs. Generally commercial banks in LDCs control a smaller share of the money supply than in DCs (Tun Wai 1956:249–278; 1957:80–125).

6.The links between interest rate, investment, and output assumed in DCs are questionable in LDCs. Investment is not very sensitive to the interest rate charged by commercial banks, partly because a lot of money is lent by money lenders, landlords, relatives, and others outside the banks. Furthermore, because of supply limitations, increases in investment demand may result in inflation rather than expanded real output. The LDCs often face these limitations at far less than full employment because of poor management, monopolistic restraints, bureaucratic delay, and the lack of essential inputs (resulting from licensing restrictions on foreign exchange or domestic materials).

Tax Ratios and GNP per Capita

We have seen the monetary policy limitations in LDCs. Fiscal policy – taxation and government spending – comprises another tool for controlling income, employment, and prices. Tax policy also has other purposes – raising funds for public spending being the most obvious one. However, as the IMF economists Vito Tanzi and Howell Zee (2000:3) argue, the “paucity of reliable data [in many LDCs] makes it difficult for policy makers to assess the potential impact of major changes to the statutory tax system.” Still, we have enough information to make generalizations. The next four sections examine changes in tax revenues as an economy develops, factors to be considered in formulating tax policy, political obstacles to tax collections, and patterns of government spending in DCs and LDCs.

The concept of systematic state intervention to stimulate economic development has been a major part of the ideology of many developing countries. Yet, perhaps surprisingly, taxes as a percentage of GNP in LDCs are generally less than in DCs. According to Table 14-1, in 1995–97, tax (including social security) revenue as a percentage of GDP was 18.2 percent for developing countries and 37.9 percent for developed (OECD) countries. Data also indicate that the tax ratio for a given country increases with economic growth (Chelliah, Baas, and Kelly 1975:187–205; Tait, Gratz, and Eichengreen 1979:123–56; Perry 1980:89–93; Tanzi 1987:205–241).

The increase in tax ratio with GNP per capita is a reflection of both demand and supply factors – demand for social goods (collective goods such as education,

468 Part Four. The Macroeconomics and International Economics of Development

TABLE 14-1. Comparative Levels of Tax Revenue,

1985–1997 (percent of GDP)

 

1985–87

1995–97

 

 

 

OECD countriesa

36.6

37.9

America

30.6

32.6

Pacific

30.7

31.6

Europe

38.2

39.4

Developing countriesb

17.5

18.2

Africa

19.6

19.8

Asia

16.1

17.4

Middle East

16.5

18.1

Western Hemisphere

17.6

18.1

aExcludes the Czech Republic, Hungary, Korea, Mexico, and Poland.

bConsists of a sample of 8 African countries, 9 Asian countries, 7 Middle Eastern countries, and 14 Western Hemisphere countries.

Source: Tanzi and Zee 2000:8.

highways, sewerage, flood control, and national defense) – and the capacity to levy and pay taxes.

Wagners law, named for the 19th-century German economist Adolph Wagner, states that as real GNP per capita rises, people demand relatively more social goods and relatively fewer private goods. A poor country spends a high percentage of its income on food, clothing, shelter, and other essential consumer goods. After these needs have been largely fulfilled, an increased proportion of additional spending is for social goods (Wagner 1958:1–16).

Goals of Tax Policy

The power to tax is an important component of making a nation-state. The most important taxation goal in LDCs is to mobilize resources for public expenditure. Mexico and Brazil’s federal tax collection as a percentage of GDP is only 12 percent compared to 19 percent in the United States and 35 percent in Sweden (Lyons 2004:A14). According to the IMF, the amount of these resources is determined by GNP per capita, the share of the mining sector in GNP, the share of exports in GNP, and tax policy. Part of this section looks at how tax policies affect public spending. In addition, we consider the impact of taxes on stability of income and prices. However, achieving these crucial taxation goals must be viewed in light of other goals, such as improved income distribution, efficient resource allocation, increased capital and enterprise, and administrative feasibility. The LDC governments must consider all of these goals when designing tax schemes to achieve rapid economic growth, to improve the lot of the poor, and to stabilize prices.

14. Monetary, Fiscal, and Incomes Policy and Inflation

469

MOBILIZING RESOURCES FOR PUBLIC EXPENDITURE

A major reason that tax ratios increase with GNP per capita is that richer countries rely more heavily on taxes with greater elasticity (that is, percentage change in taxation/percentage change in GNP). An elastic tax, whose coefficient exceeds one, rises more rapidly than GNP. Direct taxes – primarily property, wealth, inheritance, and income taxes (such as personal and corporate taxes) – are generally more elastic than indirect taxes such as import, export, turnover, sales, value-added, and excise taxes (except for sales or excise taxes on goods purchased mostly by high-income groups).

In 1995–97, direct or income (corporate, including capital gains, and personal) taxes accounted for 33.1 percent of tax revenue in LDCs and 55.1 percent in DCs or high-income OECD countries (where revenue means central government current revenue except from social security taxes, a concept that understates these and subsequent figures when compared to all revenue from all levels of government). The average ratio of direct taxes to GDP is 5.2 percent in developing countries and 14.2 percent in high income countries. Another difference on direct taxes is that DCs raise three to four times more revenue from personal than corporate income tax, whereas LDCs raise more revenue from the corporate than the personal tax (Table 14-2).

Indirect taxes include consumption (excise, export, import, sales, and value-added) taxes (Table 14-2). Indirect taxes are 44.8 percent of tax revenue and 11.4 percent of GDP in DCs, and 66.9 percent of tax revenue and 10.5 percent of GDP in LDCs.

A major source of tax for LDCs is international trade, an indirect tax comprising 22.3 percent of the total – with import duties about 80–85 percent of trade taxes and the remainder export duties.1 Other important indirect taxes – excise, sales, value-added, and other taxes on production and internal transactions – account for 38.2 percent of the total (see Table 14-2).

A major problem of economies in transition to a market economy, such as Russia and China, is to devise a tax system that will yield the revenue that was raised previously from the turnover tax (Chapter 11) and surpluses from government enterprises that set monopoly prices.

In recent decades, a number of LDCs have introduced the value-added tax (VAT), a tax on the difference between the sales of a firm and its purchases from other firms. Indeed, a majority of LDCs use the VAT (or a VAT-like tax) (Tanzi and Zee 2000:21), the benefit of which is discussed later.

Although personal income taxes rarely comprise more than 7 percent of GDP in LDCs, they often account for 10–20 percent of GDP in the DCs. In most DCs, the income tax structure is progressive, which means that people with higher incomes pay a higher percentage of income in taxes. For example, in 2003, a married couple filing jointly with two children in the United States earning $25,000 or $50,000 would pay no tax; one earning $75,000 would pay $776 (1.0 percent); one earning $100,000 would pay $7,020 (7.0 percent); one earning $150,000 would pay $20,580

1Loewy (2002) shows the optimal path that nations follow as they substitute income taxes for tariffs as they develop.

TABLE 14-2. Comparative Composition of Tax Revenue, 1985–1997 (In percent of GDP)

 

 

 

Social

security

9.5

 

6.1

3.5

10.8

1.3

 

0.5

0.3

1.1

2.3

 

 

 

 

 

Trade

0.3

 

0.3

0.6

0.3

3.5

 

5.1

2.7

4.3

2.6

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

1995–97

Consumptiontaxes

 

Ofwhich

 

Total General Excises

11.4 6.6 3.6

 

7.0 3.7 2.0

8.4 4.3 2.6

12.4 7.3 4.0

10.5 3.6 2.4

 

11.6 3.8 2.3

9.7 3.1 2.2

10.3 1.5 3.0

10.6 4.8 2.3

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Incometaxes

 

Ofwhich

 

Corporate Personal

3.1 10.8

 

3.0 12.3

4.3 11.4

2.9 10.6

2.6 2.2

 

2.4 3.9

3.0 3.0

3.2 1.3

2.3 1.0

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Total

14.2

 

15.4

16.3

13.7

5.2

 

6.9

6.2

5.0

3.7

 

 

 

Social

security

8.8

 

5.8

2.8

10.1

1.2

 

0.4

0.1

1.2

2.4

 

 

 

 

 

 

Consumptiontaxes

 

 

 

Trade

0.7

 

0.6

0.8

0.7

4.2

 

5.7

3.6

4.4

3.7

 

 

 

 

 

 

1985–87

 

Ofwhich

 

Total General Excises

11.3 6.0 3.8

 

7.6 3.4 2.2

7.5 2.3 3.7

12.4 6.8 4.0

10.3 2.3 2.6

 

11.7 3.2 2.3

9.5 1.9 2.5

9.1 1.5 2.4

10.6 2.6 3.0

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Incometaxes

 

Ofwhich

 

Corporate Personal

2.8 11.3

 

2.5 11.4

3.9 13.2

2.7 11.0

2.8 1.7

 

2.9 3.1

3.5 2.1

4.3 1.0

1.8 1.0

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Total

13.9

 

14.0

17.1

13.3

4.9

 

6.3

5.7

4.7

3.7

 

 

 

 

 

countries

Developing

countries

Africa

 

MiddleEast

Western Hemisphere

 

 

 

 

 

 

OECD

America

Pacific

Europe

Asia

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

a

 

 

 

 

b

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

theCzechRepublic,Hungary,Korea,Mexico,andPoland.

of8Africancountries;9Asiancountries;7MiddleEasterncountries;and14WesternHemispherecountries.

Excludes

Asample

a

b

Source: Tanzi and Zee 2000:13.

470

14. Monetary, Fiscal, and Incomes Policy and Inflation

471

(13.7 percent), and one earning $200,000 would pay $35,845 (17.9 percent). Many people feel the progressive tax is just – that those with higher incomes should bear a larger tax burden, as they have a much greater ability to pay. Moreover, a progressive income tax has an elasticity greater than one, so a rising GNP pushes taxpayers into higher tax brackets. Let us examine the personal income tax and others in light of overall tax policy goals before discussing some of the administrative and political reasons why LDCs rely so little on the individual income tax.

STABILITY OF INCOME AND PRICES

As we said earlier, developed countries use fiscal and monetary policies to achieve macroeconomic goals of economic growth, employment, and price changes. When there is high unemployment, the government can increase spending and decrease taxes to increase aggregate demand and employment. In times of inflation, government can reduce spending and increase taxes to decrease aggregate demand and diminish price rises.

At times, fiscal policy has a limited effect in stabilizing employment and prices in DCs, and, not surprisingly, it is even less effective in LDCs. There are several reasons for this ineffectiveness.

First, as indicated earlier, tax receipts as a share of GNP in LDCs are typically smaller than in DCs.

Second, LDCs, relying more on indirect taxes (leaving aside for now the valueadded tax), have less control than DCs over the amount of taxes they can raise. Personal and corporate income taxes can generally not be used to stabilize aggregate spending, because they comprise only 5.2 percent of GDP in LDCs. Furthermore, LDC indirect taxes are subject to wide variation – especially taxes on international trade, which frequently are affected by sharp fluctuations in volume and price (see Chapter 4). In the 1970s, Zaire raised about four-fifths of its revenue from export taxes. However, when the price of its leading export, copper, fell by 40 percent from 1974 to 1975, export receipts dropped 40 percent, too, resulting in a 36-percent decline in export tax revenue and a 19-percent decline in total government revenue (World Bank 1980i).

Third, prices and unemployment are not so sensitive to fiscal policy in LDCs as in DCs. Chapter 9 details (and we reiterate here) why expansionary fiscal policies (increased government spending and decreased tax rates) may have only a limited effect in reducing unemployment in LDCs: (1) there are major supply limitations, such as shortages of skills, infrastructure, and efficient markets; (2) creating urban jobs through expanded demand may result in more people leaving rural areas;

(3) employment may not rise with output because of factor price distortions or unsuitable technology; and (4) government may set unrealistically high wages for educated workers. On the other side of the coin, although contractionary fiscal policies may reduce Keynesian demand–pull inflation, they are not likely to reduce cost–push, ratchet, and structural inflation (discussed later).

Generally, tax policy, as monetary policy, is a very limited tool for achieving income and price stability.

472Part Four. The Macroeconomics and International Economics of Development

IMPROVING INCOME DISTRIBUTION

The progressive personal income tax takes a larger proportion of income from people in upper-income brackets and a smaller proportion from people in lower-income brackets. Thus, income distribution after taxes is supposed to be less unequal than before taxes.

Excise taxes or high import tariffs on luxury items redistribute income from higherincome to lower-income groups. These taxes are especially attractive when the income would otherwise be spent on lavish living and luxury imports.

The broad-based sales tax is usually levied as a fixed percentage of the price of retail sales. The sales tax, used widely by state and local governments in the United States, and the value-added tax, a major tax source of the European Union, is usually regressive, in that people with lower incomes pay a larger percentage of income in taxes. Because the poor save a smaller proportion of income than the rich, a LDC government wanting to use the tax system to reduce income inequality should not rely much on a value-added or general sales tax. However, exempting basic consumer goods, such as food and medicine can modify the regressive feature of the tax. But this modification is often opposed by treasury officials because it reduces revenues substantially and is costlier to administer.

Two experienced IMF economists, however, favor sales, excise, and value-added taxes, because of their more favorable effect on efficiency and spurring capital and enterprise. For Tanzi and Zee (2000:9): “Since the labor tax is equivalent to a tax on consumption . . . the income tax gives rise to an additional distortion – on savings – that is absent from the consumption tax.”

EFFICIENCY OF RESOURCE ALLOCATION

One goal of a tax system, then, is to encourage efficient use of resources or at least to minimize inefficiencies. Export taxes reduce the output of goods whose prices are determined on world markets. Such taxes shift resources from export to domestic production with a consequent loss of efficiency and foreign exchange earnings (Due and Friedlaender 1981:548).

Import duties raise the price of inputs and capital goods needed for agricultural and industrial exports and domestic goods. The price of locally produced goods requiring imported inputs increases, altering consumer choice.

An economy maximizes output and optimizes resource efficiency when price equals marginal cost. If government raises revenue from indirect taxes, price cannot equal marginal cost in all industries. However, indirect taxes can be levied at uniform rates on all final goods and exemptions. In this way, price will be proportional to marginal costs in all industries, and a minimum distortion of consumer choice will occur. Essentially, a sales tax distorts efficiency least if it is broad-based, that is, if it applies to the final sale of producer goods as well as to consumer goods and services. A uniform tax rate based on value added has a similar effect to the sales tax on resource allocation and tax incidence, but it is usually more difficult for LDC governments to administer (McLure 1975:339–349; Due 1976:164–186).

14. Monetary, Fiscal, and Incomes Policy and Inflation

473

INCREASING CAPITAL AND ENTERPRISE

The LDC governments can mobilize saving through direct taxes (on personal income, corporate profits, and property), taxes on luxury items, and sales and value-added taxes. These taxes result in a higher rate of capital formation if government has a higher investment rate than the people taxed. Moreover, the state can use taxes and subsidies to redistribute output to sectors with high growth potential and to individuals with a high propensity to save (see Nafziger’s supplement [2006b]).

The government can use tax policy to encourage domestic and foreign entrepreneurship. Tax revenues can be used for transport, power, and technical training to create external economies for private investment. Government development banks, development corporations, and loans boards can lend capital to private entrepreneurs. Fiscal incentives to attract business, especially from abroad, include tax holidays (for the first few years of operation), income averaging (where losses in one year can be offset against profits in another), accelerated depreciation, import duty relief, lower tax rates for reinvested business profits, and preferred purchases through government departments. The LDC governments may limit these incentives to enterprises and sectors that are of high priority in their development plan.

Surveys suggest that fiscal incentives have, at best, only a slight effect on the amount of investment. Moreover, subsidized investment may crowd out existing firms or firms that might have been willing to invest without subsidy. Using tax incentives successfully requires careful economic planning, skillfully structuring taxes, competent tax administration, quick decisions on applications, and no political favoritism (Heller 1975:5–28; Shah and Toye 1978:269–296; Tanzi and Zee 2000:24–29).2

Is there a conflict between the redistributive effect of the progressive income tax and increased capital accumulation? As Nafziger’s supplement (2006b) indicates, profits are a major source of new capital formation. Because, for the successful businessperson, expansion takes precedence over the desire for higher consumption, taxes on profits affect consumption far more than saving. Nicholas Kaldor (1975:33) even argues that progressive taxation, by curbing luxury spending that distorts the investment pattern, may even stimulate capital accumulation. Before progressive taxation, too much capital is invested in industries catering to the rich. After taxation, some investment shifts from luxury production to necessities. Thus, although there are conflicts between income redistribution and capital accumulation, they are probably less than is commonly believed in LDCs.

According to Alberto Alesina and Dani Rodrik (1994:465–490), the conflict does not occur because lower disposable (after-tax) income inequality causes lower savings, but because of pressures for redistribution by the majority of the population when incomes and wealth are highly unequal. Alesina and Rodik contend that any conflict results from the fact that a greater inequality of wealth and income contributes to increased political pressures for redistribution and higher rates of taxation on holders of capital and land, and the ensuing lower rates of growth.

2 Global competition to attract international businesses and capital has put pressure on countries to reduce tax rates (Economist 2000a:S5).

474Part Four. The Macroeconomics and International Economics of Development

ADMINISTRATIVE FEASIBILITY

Some developed countries use income taxes (especially the progressive personal tax) to mobilize large amounts of resources for public expenditures, improve income distribution, stabilize income and prices, and prevent inefficient allocation that comes from a heavy reliance on indirect taxes. However, few LDCs rely much on income taxes, because they have trouble administering them.3

The following conditions must be met if income tax is to become a major revenue source for a country: (1) existence of a predominantly money economy, (2) a high standard of literacy among taxpayers, (3) widespread use of accounting records honestly and reliably maintained, (4) a large degree of voluntary taxpayer compliance, and (5) honest and efficient administration. Even DCs, to say nothing of LDCs, have trouble fulfilling these conditions (Goode 1962:157–171; Tanzi 1966:156–162). Tanzania, under President Julius K. Nyerere from 1974 to 1985, was probably the only African country that used its tax system to redistribute income to low-income classes.

Taxes on international trade are the major source of tax revenue in LDCs, especially for low-income countries with poor administrative capacity. Import duties can restrict luxury goods consumption, which reduces saving and drains foreign exchange.4 However, the government can exempt the import of capital goods and other inputs needed for the development process. Export taxes, by contrast, can substitute for income taxes on (commercial) farmers, as, for example, in Ghana.

Exports and imports usually pass through a limited number of ports and border crossings. A relatively small administrative staff can measure volume and value and collect revenue. To be sure, traders may underinvoice goods or seek favors or concessions from customs officials. However, these problems are not so great as those encountered with an income, sales, or value-added tax.

The LDCs may be able to administer excise taxes if the number of producers is small. Rates are usually specific rather than percentage of value to simplify collection. The principal excises in LDCs, just as in DCs, are motor fuel (often for road finance), cigarettes, beer, and liquor. However, as the economy develops, introducing more excise taxes complicates administration and discriminates against consumers of taxed items.

The inadequacies of segmented excise taxes have led a number of developing countries to introduce sales taxes. In the poorest countries, using a retail tax is impossible. Enumerating, let alone collecting from, the numerous, very small, uneducated peddlers, traders, and shopkeepers is the major difficulty. Thus, a number of African countries have levied a sales tax on manufacturers, where numbers are fewer and control is easier. But this tax discriminates among products, favors imports, and

3Given their consciousness concerning how much the U.S. Internal Revenue Service and the Canadian personal income tax service emphasize tax enforcement and penalties, many students from the U.S. and Canada are surprised to learn that the two countries have some of the highest rates of personal income tax compliance in the world.

4 Note, however, some of the unintended side effects of a tax on luxury items (Chapter 17).

14. Monetary, Fiscal, and Incomes Policy and Inflation

475

interferes with the allocation of functions by production stage. Other countries restrict the sales tax to large retail firms, which also introduces distortions and inequities (Due and Friedlaender 1981:539–548).

INCREASING THE STATE’S CAPACITY TO COLLECT TAXES:

THE VALUE-ADDED TAX

Chapter 4 mentions the importance of an LDC raising revenue and providing basic services. In weak or failing low-income countries, especially those facing internal conflict, such as several in sub-Saharan Africa, the state does not provide minimal functions of defense, law and order, health and education, and macroeconomic stability. Countries whose fiscal positions are deteriorating and can no longer supply basic functions risk a loss of legitimacy. Governments need a social compact with their citizens to provide basic needs in return for tax contributions according to the ability to pay.

Replacing widely evaded direct taxes, such as personal income taxes, with indirect taxes is a way to increase state legitimacy and raise tax revenue. Several LDCs have used value-added taxes (VAT), a tax on the difference between the sales of a firm and its purchases from other firms, to raise a substantial fraction of revenues. Chile and South Korea both began using the value-added tax in the 1970s; Chile raises almost 40 percent and South Korea about 25 percent of their tax revenues from VAT. Colombia, Argentina, Uruguay, Mexico, Peru, Haiti, Honduras, Turkey, and Indonesia mobilize one-sixth to one-fourth of their tax moneys from VAT. Other LDCs using VAT (or a VAT-like tax) include Cote d’Ivoire, Kenya, Mauritius, South Africa, Zambia, the Philippines, Sri Lanka, Thailand, Egypt, Jordan, Morocco, Pakistan, Tunisia, Bolivia, Costa Rica, Dominican Republic, El Salvador, Nicaragua, Panama, and Venezuela (Tanzi and Zee 2000:22). Stanford University’s Ronald McKinnon (1993:134–135) recommends that former socialist countries such as Russia, which have relied heavily on enterprise taxes, adopt the VAT. VAT, which is less difficult to administer, permits the central government to tax all forms of enterprise income uniformly.

The appeals of the value-added tax are simplicity, uniformity, the generation of buoyant revenues (from a high income elasticity), and the enabling of a gradual lowering of other tax rates throughout the system (for example, the lowering or elimination of the distortions of a cascade tax). One example of a cascade is the simplest sales tax that takes a straightforward percentage of all business turnover, so that tax on tax occurs as a taxed product passes from manufacturer to wholesaler to retailer (Tait 1988; Weidenbaum and Christian 1989:1–16).

The most frequently used approach for levying VAT is the subtractive-indirect (the invoice and credit) method. Under this approach, the firm issues invoices for all taxable transactions, using these invoices to compute the tax on total sales. But the firm is given credit for VAT paid by its suppliers. To a substantial degree, VAT is self-enforcing, as the firm has an incentive to present invoices to subtract VAT on purchases from VAT on sales; these invoices provide a check on VAT payments

Соседние файлы в предмете Экономика