
Nafziger Economic Development (4th ed)
.pdf266Part Two. Poverty Alleviation and Income Distribution
examination of the full range of alternatives, including no action, by an informed and democratic public (World Bank 2003i:94–95). Although DCs may be able to afford GM skepticism, LDC needs are critical enough to err on the side of adopting technologies to expand food production.
Conclusion
If we use the World Bank count, more than 3 billion people and 500 million poor people live in rural areas. Rural inequality is probably less than urban inequality in LDCs as a whole, especially in Afro-Asia. Nevertheless, rural populations have a higher percentage in poverty than urban populations, because of much lower average incomes in rural areas. Most rural poverty is concentrated among agricultural laborers, the landless, and the near landless. Households headed by women form a disproportionate share of the rural poor. Two-thirds of sub-Saharan Africa’s rural population (with the highest poverty rate) and more than one-half of Latin America’s rural population live in poverty. Asia has the largest absolute number of rural poor but the lowest rural poverty rate among LDC regions.
Output per person outside agriculture as a multiple of that in agriculture, which is eight in Africa and four in Asia and Latin America, was only about two in Europe in the 19th century.
Because of high levels of capital accumulation, technical knowledge, and worker productivity, agricultural output per worker in developed countries is about 25 times as high as in developing countries.
Subsistence farming dominated LDC agriculture in the past. The major goal of the peasant farmer has been not to maximize income but the family’s probability of survival. Nevertheless, many peasants, attracted by the potential for improving productivity and living standards, have begun to produce more crops for the market. Many others earn a substantial proportion of their incomes from nonfarm activities.
With globalization, a larger proportion of LDC farm ouput is contracted with multinational corporations.
Food production per capita in the developed countries grew 22 percent from 1962 to 1996 compared to 14 percent in developing countries, with sub-Saharan Africa’s average output declining during the same period. Growth rates for both India and China are positive, although generally slower than for LDCs before the late 1970s, and more rapid than other LDCs after liberalization in the late 1970s. Agricultural economists noticed a fall in global average foodgrain production during the late 1980s and early 1990s, but they do not know if foodgrain output per person will grow or decline in the early 21st century.
Entitlement refers to the set of alternative commodities that a person can command in a society using the totality of rights that he or she possesses. An entitlement helps people acquire capabilities (like being well nourished).
Colonial and postcolonial policies biased against agriculture helped contribute to sub-Saharan Africa’s decline in food output per capita from the early 1950s to the early 1990s. Africa’s food security is low because of substantial fluctuations in
7. Rural Poverty and Agricultural Transformation |
267 |
domestic production and foreign-exchange reserves, reductions in food aid, and lack of a Green Revolution in most of the continent.
Inadequate capital (including that for health and social services), lack of technology, low educational and skill levels, the brain drain to urban areas, food price policies, below-market foreign exchange rates, and governmental urban bias contribute to low incomes in rural areas. Land concentration, the bias of technology toward large farmers, and large seasonal variations in income also affect rural poverty rates.
Policies that would increase rural income and reduce rural poverty are manifold. Land reform and redistribution, developing labor-intensive capital equipment, establishing rural credit agencies, agricultural research centers that conduct on-farm tests, institutes to develop and adapt technology for small farmers, an extension service integrated with development agencies, an irrigation authority that conducts careful feasibility studies of proposed projects, and government ministries that provide suitable and timely inputs to farmers are estimable goals. So, too, farm commodity and foreign exchange prices close to market-clearing rates; greater expenditure on social and educational services in rural areas; redistributing land to the rural poor; establishing agro industries, basic consumer goods industries, and other small industries in rural areas; and investment in marketing, transport, and storage facilities for agricultural commodities would improve the lot of the rural poor.
In LDCs, the small family farm is best positioned to have high productivity per hectare, at least if credit, extension, and inputs are readily accessible. Collective farming has not generally increased productivity because of disincentives for work, innovation, and savings.
Production-oriented rural development projects such as small-farmer credit, agricultural innovations and new technology, and improved extension services are likely to reduce agricultural terms of trade and thus reduce rural incomes in the short run. To increase incomes of the rural poor, production-oriented programs need to be combined with policies to improve relative agricultural prices and rural income distribution.
Agriculture biotechnology has substantial potential to increase yields per hectare and per person in developing countries.
The following subjects related to food and agriculture are covered in subsequent chapters: the food-population balance (Chapter 8); disguised unemployment in agriculture and rural–urban migration (Chapter 9); natural resources and the environment (Chapter 13); and the role of trade in agriculture in raising average farm incomes in developing countries (Chapter 17).
TERMS TO REVIEW |
|
|
|
|
cooperative |
|
household responsibility system |
|
elasticity of supply |
|
import substitutes |
|
entitlement |
|
kulak |
|
foodgrain (cereals) deficit |
|
latifundios |
|
food security index (FSI) |
|
minifundios |
268 Part Two. Poverty Alleviation and Income Distribution
|
peasant farming |
|
sharecropping |
|
property rights |
|
ujamaa |
|
real exchange rate |
|
urban bias |
QUESTIONS TO DISCUSS
1.Give arguments in favor of LDCs concentrating their antipoverty programs in rural areas.
2.In what ways does agriculture contribute to economic growth?
3.Why is agricultural productivity in DCs so much higher than in LDCs?
4.How does a peasant economy differ from that of a commercial farm economy?
5.What do you expect the trend in foodgrain output per capita and food consumption per capita to be in LDCs in the next decade? What LDC regions are most vulnerable in the next decade? What LDC regions are most invulnerable in the next decade?
6.Explain and compare India’s progress since the early 1950s in increasing average food output and reducing hunger to China’s progress.
7.Explain sub-Saharan Africa’s negative growth in food output per person between the early 1960s and the late 1990s.
8.What factors contribute to the high incidence of rural poverty in LDCs?
9.What factors contribute to the high incidence of rural poverty among single female heads of households?
10.Indicate the forms of urban bias in LDCs. Give examples of policies of urban bias (or rural bias) in your own country or another one you know well. Has such a policy bias hampered development?
11.What policies are most effective in increasing rural income and reducing rural poverty? What strategies are needed to prevent rural development policies from increasing rural poverty through reduced agricultural terms of trade?
12.Is Soviet and Chinese collectivism (similar to that before 1975) practicable in LDCs? Compare and explain China’s agricultural progress in the Maoist period (1949–76) to that of the period after the 1979 agricultural reforms.
13.Identify an LDC whose productivity could be increased by land reform and indicate the type of reform you would advocate.
GUIDE TO READINGS
Eicher and Staatz (1998) is an excellent book of readings on agricultural and food needs, foreign aid, the agricultural transformation, models of agricultural development, the role of induced innovation, agricultural macroeconomic and trade policies, food and entitlements, urban bias, the role of human capital and institutions, market failure, technology development and sustainability, and agriculture in transition. Pinstrup-Anderson (2002:1201–1214) discusses food and agricultural policy
7. Rural Poverty and Agricultural Transformation |
269 |
amid globalization. Ruttan (2002:161–184) analyzes sources and constraints on productivity growth in world agriculture. Hayami and Ruttan (1985), although more dated, is still a good source on international agricultural development. Other references include Tomich, Kilby, and Johnston (1995); Sanders, Ramaswamy, and Shapiro (1995); and Singh (1990). Binswanger and Deininger (1997:1958–2005) and Binswanger, Deininger, and Feder (1995:2659–2772) are leading articles on agrarian reform and agricultural policies.
Mosley (2002:695–714) sees development of foodcrop agricultural as pivotal to poverty reduction in Africa. Gaiha and Imai (2004:261–281) stress the importance of negative crop production shocks in the persistence of rural poverty in south India.
Data on food output and imports in DCs and LDCs are in publications from the U.S. Department of Agriculture (1986, 1988, 1999, and subsequent years); FAO (2003b and subsequent years); and Internet sources cited in the last paragraph. For a discussion of measuring food production, consumption, and demand in LDCs, see Evenson and Pray (1994:173–97) and Bouis (1994:199–226).

PART THREE. FACTORS OF GROWTH
8Population and Development
Chapters 8–13 analyze factors that influence economic growth. The next three chapters examine the role of the human population in economic growth. This chapter examines how population growth affects economic development and how fertility affects labor force participation and development. Chapter 9 looks at how population growth affects labor force growth and unemployment, and Chapter 10 at what factors affect labor skills – a major component of population quality.
Between 1980 and 2005, the world’s population grew at 1.6 percent per year, from 4.4 billion to 6.5 billion. During the same period, LDC population grew at 2.0 percent per year, from 3.2 billion to 5.3 billion. This chapter explains this phenomenal growth rate and looks at its implications.
Scope of the Chapter
After a brief historical sketch, we consider population growth in DCs and LDCs and by world regions. Next, we explain the rapid but decelerating growth in LDCs by looking at trends in death and birth rates during a period of demographic (population) transition. With this background, we assess the effect of population growth on economic development and review the work of the classical economist Thomas Robert Malthus, who argues that population growth outstrips economic growth. In this connection, we discuss the present and future balance between food and population. Population growth also affects urbanization, labor force growth, and the number of dependents workers must support; we look at all of these elements, too. In the last section, we consider the relative merits of birth control programs and socioeconomic development in reducing population growth.
World Population Throughout History
Throughout most of our existence, population grew at a rate of only 0.002 percent (or 20 per million people) per year. This growth was subject to substantial fluctuations from wars, plagues, famines, and natural catastrophes. However, since about 8000 B.C.E., population growth rates have accelerated. Worldwide population reached one billion in the early 19th century, millions of years after our appearance on earth. The second billion was added about a century later, in 1930. The third billion came along in only 30 years, in 1960; the fourth took only 15 years, in 1975; the fifth, 11 years,
271

272 Part Three. Factors of Growth
World population in billions of persons
7.0 |
|
|
|
6.0 |
|
|
|
5.0 |
|
|
|
4.0 |
|
|
|
3.0 |
|
|
|
2.0 |
|
|
|
1.0 |
|
|
|
0 |
|
|
|
8000 |
7000 6000 5000 4000 3000 2000 1000 |
0 |
1000 2000 |
BCE |
|
|
CE |
|
Year |
|
|
FIGURE 8-1. World Population Growth through History. The graph shows how explosive population growth has been in the last 200 years. World population grew at an annual rate of about 0.002 percent between the appearance of humankind and 8000 B.C.E, 0.05 percent between 8000 B.C.E and 1650, 0.43 percent between 1650 and 1900,
0.91 percent between 1900 and 1950, 1.93 percent between 1950 and 1980, and is growing 1.46 percent per year between 1980 and 2010. Sources: Based on Ehrlich, Ehrlich, and Holdren 1977:183; Thompson and Lewis 1965:384; Carr-Saunders 1936:15–45; U.S. Bureau of the Census 1978:15; U.S. Bureau of the Census 1979:17; U.S. Bureau of the Census 2004; World Bank 1987i:254–255; World Bank 1994i:210–11; Population Reference Bureau 2003.
in 1986; the sixth billion took 12 years, in 1998 (see Figure 8-1); and with population growth deceleration the seventh billion is expected in 2013. Eighty-one percent of the world’s population lives in LDCs.
Population Growth in Developed and Developing Countries
Figure 8-2 indicates the great variation in birth rates, death rates, and population growth among nations. Countries can be roughly divided into three groups: (1) the DCs and transitional economies, consisting of countries in Europe, North America, Australia, New Zealand, and Japan, with population growth rates below 0.8 percent per year; (2) several countries from East and Southeast Asia and Latin America, including Argentina, Chile, Cuba, China, Taiwan, South Korea, Thailand, Vietnam, Indonesia, and Sri Lanka, with crude death rates below 9 per 1,000 and annual growth rates between 0.8 and 1.8 percent, whose demographic behavior is closer to DCs than to LDCs; and (3) the bulk of the LDCs – most of Africa, Asia, and Latin America, with population growth rates of at least 1.9 percent per year.

8. Population and Development |
273 |
FIGURE 8-2. Population Growth in Developed and Developing Countries. A population growth rate of 0.8–1.8 percent yearly roughly divides the DCs from the LDCs.
Source: World Bank 2001h:44–45.
A major distinction between the three groups is the birth rate. (Following the conventional use, crude birth and death rates denote a number per 1,000, not percent.) The DCs’ and transitional countries’ crude birth rate are no more than 16 per 1,000. Most developing countries have birth rates of at least 25 per 1,000. Countries in category 2 generally fall between these two figures.
World Population: Rapid but Decelerating Growth
The world’s population is unevenly distributed geographically. Figure 8-3 shows regional distribution in 1950 and 1994, and projected distribution in 2025. The most rapidly growing regions are in the developing world: Asia, Africa, and Latin America. Their share of the global population increased from 70.0 percent in 1950 to 81.5 percent in 2000, and is expected to reach 85.1 percent in 2025. From 1950 to 2000, Asia, Africa, and Latin America grew at a rate of 2.1 percent yearly, a rate that doubles population in 33 years. Such growth is unprecedented in world history.
Africa is expected to have the most rapid growth, 2000 to 2025, 2.4 percent yearly. This rate, the same as its present rate, is the result of a traditionally high crude birth rate, 38 per 1,000 (with only 26 percent of married women using contraceptives), and a crude death rate, 14 per 1,000. The death rate plummeted from 1930 to 1990

274 Part Three. Factors of Growth
FIGURE 8-3. World Population by Region: 1950, 2000, and 2025 (projected). Asia’s, Africa’s, and Latin America’s share of the world population is increasing over time. Sources: U.N. Department of Economic and Social Affairs 1976:115; Ehrlich, Ehrlich, and Holden 1977:200–201; Population Reference Bureau 2000; World Bank 2001h:44–45; Bongaarts 2001.
because of improvements in health, nutrition, medicine, and sanitation. Although growth in Latin America and the Caribbean until 2025 is projected at 1.3 percent annually, its present yearly rate, 1.7 percent per year, is based on 23 births and 6 deaths per 1,000. Although Asia’s annual growth, 1.3 percent (birth rate of 20 and death rate of 7), will decline to 1.1 percent in the 25 years, 2000 to 2025, it is by far the most heavily populated region, with more than 60 percent of the world’s people.
Population size is a factor in shifting political and military power from the North Atlantic to Asia and the Pacific. The percentage of the world’s people living in North America and Europe (excluding the former Soviet Union) declined from 23.0 percent in 1900 and 29.5 percent in 1950 to 18.0 percent in 2000, and is expected to decrease to 12.3 percent in 2025. Six Asian countries plus the Russian Federation (partly in Asia) are on the list of the 10 largest countries in the world. In 2000, China and India constituted 41.3 percent of the world’s population (Table 8-1).
Most of the large increases in population between 1994 and 2025 are expected in the developing world. India’s addition to population during this period should exceed U.S. total population in 2025. India, China, Nigeria, Indonesia, Pakistan, and Ethiopia (listed in order of absolute growth) will each grow more from 2000 to 2025 than the United States, the world’s third most populated country. Bangladesh, Congo (Kinshasa), Iran, and Mexico follow in order of growth during these years (International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis 2004).
Although the world has witnessed unprecedented population growth during the last 50 to 60 years, faster growth than any other 50to 60-year period, the rate of growth has been decelerating since its peak rate of 2.3 percent yearly in 1960 to

8. Population and Development |
|
275 |
|||||
|
|
|
|
||||
|
TABLE 8-1. The 10 Countries with the Largest Population: 2000 |
|
|||||
|
and 2025 (projected) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
||
|
|
Total population, |
Projected population, |
|
|||
|
|
2000 |
(millions) |
2025 |
(millions) |
|
|
|
|
(world ranking in |
(world ranking in |
|
|||
|
Country |
parentheses) |
parentheses) |
|
|||
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
China |
1261 |
(1) |
1464 |
(1) |
|
|
|
India |
1014 |
(2) |
1377 |
(2) |
|
|
|
U.S. |
275 |
(3) |
338 |
(3) |
|
|
|
Indonesia |
225 |
(4) |
301 |
(4) |
|
|
|
Brazil |
173 |
(5) |
201 |
(7) |
|
|
|
Russia |
146 |
(6) |
136 |
(9) |
|
|
|
Pakistan |
142 |
(7) |
213 |
(5) |
|
|
|
Bangladesh |
129 |
(8) |
177 |
(8) |
|
|
|
Japan |
127 |
(9) |
126 |
(13) |
|
|
|
Nigeria |
123 |
(10) |
204 |
(6) |
|
|
|
Mexico |
97 |
(11) |
134 |
(10) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
||
|
Source: U.S. Bureau of the Census 2004c. |
|
|
|
|
||
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
1.3 percent in 2005 to an expected 0.8 percent in 2025 and 0.4 percent in 2050 (Figure 8-4). Factors discussed later, such as urbanization, greater economic aspirations, increased female education and labor force participation, and more accessibility to family planning, have contributed to the falling population growth rate from 1960 to the present. Indeed, Walter Rostow (1998:1) sees the population spike (growth)
|
2.5 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Rate(Percentage) |
2 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
1.5 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Growth |
1 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0.5 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
1950 |
1960 |
1970 |
1980 |
1990 |
2000 |
2010 |
2020 |
2030 |
2040 |
2050 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Years |
|
|
|
|
|
FIGURE 8-4. World Population Growth Rate: 1950–2050. Source: U.S. Bureau of the Census:
2004a.