Добавил:
Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:

Mankiw Principles of Economics (3rd ed)

.pdf
Скачиваний:
1113
Добавлен:
22.08.2013
Размер:
5.93 Mб
Скачать

524

PART EIGHT THE DATA OF MACROECONOMICS

changes in interest rates, it will be important for us to keep in mind the distinction between real and nominal interest rates.

QUICK QUIZ: Henry Ford paid his workers $5 a day in 1914. If the consumer price index was 10 in 1914 and 166 in 1999, how much was the Ford paycheck worth in 1999 dollars?

CONCLUSION

“A nickel ain’t worth a dime anymore,” baseball player Yogi Berra once quipped. Indeed, throughout recent history, the real values behind the nickel, the dime, and the dollar have not been stable. Persistent increases in the overall level of prices have been the norm. Such inflation reduces the purchasing power of each unit of money over time. When comparing dollar figures from different times, it is important to keep in mind that a dollar today is not the same as a dollar 20 years ago or, most likely, 20 years from now.

This chapter has discussed how economists measure the overall level of prices in the economy and how they use price indexes to correct economic variables for the effects of inflation. This analysis is only a starting point. We have not yet examined the causes and effects of inflation or how inflation interacts with other economic variables. To do that, we need to go beyond issues of measurement. Indeed, that is our next task. Having explained how economists measure macroeconomic quantities and prices in the past two chapters, we are now ready to develop the models that explain long-run and short-run movements in these variables.

Summar y

The consumer price index shows the cost of a basket of goods and services relative to the cost of the same basket in the base year. The index is used to measure the overall level of prices in the economy. The percentage change in the consumer price index measures the inflation rate.

The consumer price index is an imperfect measure of the cost of living for three reasons. First, it does not take into account consumers’ ability to substitute toward goods that become relatively cheaper over time. Second, it does not take into account increases in the purchasing power of the dollar due to the introduction of new goods. Third, it is distorted by unmeasured changes in the quality of goods and services. Because of these measurement problems, the CPI overstates annual inflation by about 1 percentage point.

Although the GDP deflator also measures the overall level of prices in the economy, it differs from the consumer price index because it includes goods and services produced rather than goods and services consumed. As a result, imported goods affect the consumer price index but not the GDP deflator. In addition, whereas the consumer price index uses a fixed basket of goods, the GDP deflator automatically changes the group of goods and services over time as the composition of GDP changes.

Dollar figures from different points in time do not represent a valid comparison of purchasing power. To compare a dollar figure from the past to a dollar figure today, the older figure should be inflated using a price index.

CHAPTER 23 MEASURING THE COST OF LIVING

525

Various laws and private contracts use price indexes to correct for the effects of inflation. The tax laws, however, are only partially indexed for inflation.

A correction for inflation is especially important when looking at data on interest rates. The nominal interest rate is the interest rate usually reported; it is the rate at

which the number of dollars in a savings account increases over time. By contrast, the real interest rate takes into account changes in the value of the dollar over time. The real interest rate equals the nominal interest rate minus the rate of inflation.

Key Concepts

consumer price index (CPI), p. 512

producer price index, p. 515

nominal interest rate, p. 523

inflation rate, p. 514

indexation, p. 521

real interest rate, p. 523

 

 

 

Questions for Review

1.Which do you think has a greater price index: a 10 percent increase or a 10 percent increase in the

2.Describe the three problems that price index an imperfect measure

3.If the price of a Navy submarine price index or the GDP deflator

Problems and Applications

of time, the price of a candy bar rose Over the same period, the consumer 150 to 300. Adjusted for overall

did the price of the candy bar

of nominal interest rate and real they related?

1.Suppose that people consume only three goods, as shown in this table:

 

TENNIS

TENNIS

 

 

BALLS

RACQUETS

GATORADE

 

 

 

 

2001 price

$2

$40

$1

2001 quantity

100

10

200

2002 price

$2

$60

$2

2002 quantity

100

10

200

a.What is the percentage change in the price of each of the three goods? What is the percentage change in the overall price level?

b.Do tennis racquets become more or less expensive relative to Gatorade? Does the well-being of some people change relative to the well-being of others? Explain.

2.Suppose that the residents of Vegopia spend all of their income on cauliflower, broccoli, and carrots. In 2001

they buy 100 heads of cauliflower for $200, 50 bunches of broccoli for $75, and 500 carrots for $50. In 2002 they buy 75 heads of cauliflower for $225, 80 bunches of broccoli for $120, and 500 carrots for $100. If the base year is 2001, what is the CPI in both years? What is the inflation rate in 2002?

3.From 1947 to 1997 the consumer price index in the United States rose 637 percent. Use this fact to adjust each of the following 1947 prices for the effects of inflation. Which items cost less in 1997 than in 1947 after adjusting for inflation? Which items cost more?

ITEM

1947 PRICE

1997 PRICE

 

 

 

University of Iowa tuition

$130

$2,470

Gallon of gasoline

$0.23

$1.22

Three-minute phone call

 

 

from New York to L.A.

$2.50

$0.45

One-day hospital stay in

 

 

intensive care unit

$35

$2,300

McDonald’s hamburger

$0.15

$0.59

526

PART EIGHT THE DATA OF MACROECONOMICS

4.Beginning in 1994, environmental regulations have required that gasoline contain a new additive to reduce air pollution. This requirement raised the cost of gasoline. The Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) decided that this increase in cost represented an improvement in quality.

a.Given this decision, did the increased cost of gasoline raise the CPI?

b.What is the argument in favor of the BLS’s decision? What is the argument for a different decision?

5.Which of the problems in the construction of the CPI might be illustrated by each of the following situations? Explain.

a.the invention of the Sony Walkman

b.the introduction of air bags in cars

c.increased personal computer purchases in response to a decline in their price

d.more scoops of raisins in each package of Raisin Bran

e.greater use of fuel-efficient cars after gasoline prices increase

6.The New York Times cost $0.15 in 1970 and $0.75 in 1999. The average wage in manufacturing was $3.35 per hour in 1970 and $13.84 in 1999.

a.By what percentage did the price of a newspaper rise?

b.By what percentage did the wage rise?

c.In each year, how many minutes does a worker have to work to earn enough to buy a newspaper?

d.Did workers’ purchasing power in terms of newspapers rise or fall?

7.The chapter explains that Social Security benefits are increased each year in proportion to the increase in the CPI, even though most economists believe that the CPI overstates actual inflation.

a.If the elderly consume the same market basket as other people, does Social Security provide the elderly with an improvement in their standard of living each year? Explain.

b.In fact, the elderly consume more health care than younger people, and health care costs have risen faster than overall inflation. What would you do to determine whether the elderly are actually better off from year to year?

8.How do you think the basket of goods and services you buy differs from the basket bought by the typical U.S. household? Do you think you face a higher or lower inflation rate than is indicated by the CPI? Why?

9.Income tax brackets were not indexed until 1985. When inflation pushed up people’s nominal incomes during the 1970s, what do you think happened to real tax revenue? (Hint: This phenomenon was known as “bracket creep.”)

10.When deciding how much of their income to save for retirement, should workers consider the real or the nominal interest rate that their savings will earn? Explain.

11.Suppose that a borrower and a lender agree on the nominal interest rate to be paid on a loan. Then inflation turns out to be higher than they both expected.

a.Is the real interest rate on this loan higher or lower than expected?

b.Does the lender gain or lose from this unexpectedly high inflation? Does the borrower gain or lose?

c.Inflation during the 1970s was much higher than most people had expected when the decade began. How did this affect homeowners who obtained fixed-rate mortgages during the 1960s? How did it affect the banks who lent the money?

P R O D U C T I O N A N D G R O W T H

When you travel around the world, you see tremendous variation in the standard of living. The average person in a rich country, such as the United States, Japan, or Germany, has an income more than ten times as high as the average person in a poor country, such as India, Indonesia, or Nigeria. These large differences in income are reflected in large differences in the quality of life. Richer countries have more automobiles, more telephones, more televisions, better nutrition, safer housing, better health care, and longer life expectancy.

Even within a country, there are large changes in the standard of living over time. In the United States over the past century, average income as measured by real GDP per person has grown by about 2 percent per year. Although 2 percent might seem small, this rate of growth implies that average income doubles every 35 years. Because of this growth, average income today is about eight times as high as average income a century ago. As a result, the typical American enjoys much

IN THIS CHAPTER YOU WILL . . .

See how economic gr owth dif fers

ar ound the world

Consider why pr oductivity is the

key deter minant of a countr y’s standar d of living

Analyze the factors that deter mine

a countr y’s pr oductivity

Examine how a countr y’s policies influence its

pr oductivity gr owth

529

530

PART NINE THE REAL ECONOMY IN THE LONG RUN

greater economic prosperity than did his or her parents, grandparents, and greatgrandparents.

Growth rates vary substantially from country to country. In some East Asian countries, such as Singapore, South Korea, and Taiwan, average income has risen about 7 percent per year in recent decades. At this rate, average income doubles every ten years. These countries have, in the length of one generation, gone from being among the poorest in the world to being among the richest. By contrast, in some African countries, such as Chad, Ethiopia, and Nigeria, average income has been stagnant for many years.

What explains these diverse experiences? How can the rich countries be sure to maintain their high standard of living? What policies should the poor countries pursue to promote more rapid growth in order to join the developed world? These are among the most important questions in macroeconomics. As economist Robert Lucas put it, “The consequences for human welfare in questions like these are simply staggering: Once one starts to think about them, it is hard to think about anything else.”

In the previous two chapters we discussed how economists measure macroeconomic quantities and prices. In this chapter we start studying the forces that determine these variables. As we have seen, an economy’s gross domestic product (GDP) measures both the total income earned in the economy and the total expenditure on the economy’s output of goods and services. The level of real GDP is a good gauge of economic prosperity, and the growth of real GDP is a good gauge of economic progress. Here we focus on the long-run determinants of the level and growth of real GDP. Later in this book we study the short-run fluctuations of real GDP around its long-run trend.

We proceed here in three steps. First, we examine international data on real GDP per person. These data will give you some sense of how much the level and growth of living standards vary around the world. Second, we examine the role of productivity—the amount of goods and services produced for each hour of a worker’s time. In particular, we see that a nation’s standard of living is determined by the productivity of its workers, and we consider the factors that determine a nation’s productivity. Third, we consider the link between productivity and the economic policies that a nation pursues.

ECONOMIC GROWTH AROUND THE WORLD

As a starting point for our study of long-run growth, let’s look at the experiences of some of the world’s economies. Table 24-1 shows data on real GDP per person for 13 countries. For each country, the data cover about a century of history. The first and second columns of the table present the countries and time periods. (The time periods differ somewhat from country to country because of differences in data availability.) The third and fourth columns show estimates of real GDP per person about a century ago and for a recent year.

The data on real GDP per person show that living standards vary widely from country to country. Income per person in the United States, for instance, is about 8 times that in China and about 15 times that in India. The poorest countries have average levels of income that have not been seen in the United States for many

CHAPTER 24 PRODUCTION AND GROWTH

531

 

 

REAL GDP PER PERSON

REAL GDP PER PERSON

GROWTH RATE

COUNTRY

PERIOD

AT BEGINNING OF PERIODa

AT END OF PERIODa

PER YEAR

 

 

 

 

 

Japan

1890–1997

$1,196

$23,400

2.82%

Brazil

1900–1997

619

6,240

2.41

Mexico

1900–1997

922

8,120

2.27

Germany

1870–1997

1,738

21,300

1.99

Canada

1870–1997

1,890

21,860

1.95

China

1900–1997

570

3,570

1.91

Argentina

1900–1997

1,824

9,950

1.76

United States

1870–1997

3,188

28,740

1.75

Indonesia

1900–1997

708

3,450

1.65

India

1900–1997

537

1,950

1.34

United Kingdom

1870–1997

3,826

20,520

1.33

Pakistan

1900–1997

587

1,590

1.03

Bangladesh

1900–1997

495

1,050

0.78

 

 

 

 

 

aReal GDP is measured in 1997 dollars.

SOURCE: Robert J. Barro and Xavier Sala-i-Martin, Economic Growth (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1995), tables 10.2 and 10.3; World Development Report 1998/99, table 1; and author’s calculations.

THE VARIETY OF GROWTH EXPERIENCES

Table 24-1

decades. The typical citizen of China in 1997 had about as much real income as the typical American in 1870. The typical person in Pakistan in 1997 had about onehalf the real income of a typical American a century ago.

The last column of the table shows each country’s growth rate. The growth rate measures how rapidly real GDP per person grew in the typical year. In the United States, for example, real GDP per person was $3,188 in 1870 and $28,740 in 1997. The growth rate was 1.75 percent per year. This means that if real GDP per person, beginning at $3,188, were to increase by 1.75 percent for each of 127 years, it would end up at $28,740. Of course, real GDP per person did not actually rise exactly 1.75 percent every year: Some years it rose by more and other years by less. The growth rate of 1.75 percent per year ignores short-run fluctuations around the long-run trend and represents an average rate of growth for real GDP per person over many years.

The countries in Table 24-1 are ordered by their growth rate from the most to the least rapid. Japan tops the list, with a growth rate of 2.82 percent per year. A hundred years ago, Japan was not a rich country. Japan’s average income was only somewhat higher than Mexico’s, and it was well behind Argentina’s. To put the issue another way, Japan’s income in 1890 was less than India’s income in 1997. But because of its spectacular growth, Japan is now an economic superpower, with average income only slightly behind that of the United States. At the bottom of the list of countries is Bangladesh, which has experienced growth of only 0.78 percent per year over the past century. As a result, the typical resident of Bangladesh continues to live in abject poverty.

Because of differences in growth rates, the ranking of countries by income changes substantially over time. As we have seen, Japan is a country that has risen

532

PART NINE THE REAL ECONOMY IN THE LONG RUN

F Y I

The Magic of

Compounding

and the

Rule of 70

It may be tempting to dismiss differences in growth rates as insignificant. If one country grows at 1 percent while another grows at 3 percent, so what? What difference can 2 percent make?

The answer is: a big difference. Even growth rates that seem small when written in percentage terms seem large after they are compounded for many years. Compounding refers to the accumulation of a growth

rate over a period of time.

Consider an example. Suppose that two college gradu- ates—Jerry and Elaine—both take their first jobs at the age of 22 earning $30,000 a year. Jerry lives in an economy where all incomes grow at 1 percent per year, while Elaine lives in one where incomes grow at 3 percent per year. Straightforward calculations show what happens. Forty years later, when both are 62 years old, Jerry earns $45,000 a year, while Elaine earns $98,000. Because of that difference of 2 percentage points in the growth rate, Elaine’s salary is more than twice Jerry’s.

An old rule of thumb, called the rule of 70, is helpful in understanding growth rates and the effects of compounding. According to the rule of 70, if some variable grows at a rate of x percent per year, then that variable doubles in approximately 70/x years. In Jerry’s economy, incomes grow at 1 percent per year, so it takes about 70 years for incomes to double. In Elaine’s economy, incomes grow at 3 percent per year, so it takes about 70/3, or 23, years for incomes to double.

The rule of 70 applies not only to a growing economy but also to a growing savings account. Here is an example: In 1791, Ben Franklin died and left $5,000 to be invested for a period of 200 years to benefit medical students and scientific research. If this money had earned 7 percent per year (which would, in fact, have been very possible to do), the investment would have doubled in value every 10 years. Over 200 years, it would have doubled 20 times. At the end of 200 years of compounding, the investment would have been worth 220 $5,000, which is about $5 billion. (In fact, Franklin’s $5,000 grew to only $2 million over 200 years because some of the money was spent along the way.)

As these examples show, growth rates compounded over many years can lead to some spectacular results. That is probably why Albert Einstein once called compounding “the greatest mathematical discovery of all time.”

relative to others. One country that has fallen behind is the United Kingdom. In 1870, the United Kingdom was the richest country in the world, with average income about 20 percent higher than that of the United States and about twice that of Canada. Today, average income in the United Kingdom is below average income in its two former colonies.

These data show that the world’s richest countries have no guarantee they will stay the richest and that the world’s poorest countries are not doomed forever to remain in poverty. But what explains these changes over time? Why do some countries zoom ahead while others lag behind? These are precisely the questions that we take up next.

QUICK QUIZ: What is the approximate growth rate of real GDP per person in the United States? Name a country that has had faster growth and a country that has had slower growth.

PRODUCTIVITY : ITS ROLE AND DETERMINANTS

Explaining the large variation in living standards around the world is, in one sense, very easy. As we will see, the explanation can be summarized in a single word—productivity. But, in another sense, the international variation is deeply

CHAPTER 24 PRODUCTION AND GROWTH

533

puzzling. To explain why incomes are so much higher in some countries than in others, we must look at the many factors that determine a nation’s productivity.

WHY PRODUCTIVITY IS SO IMPORTANT

Let’s begin our study of productivity and economic growth by developing a simple model based loosely on Daniel DeFoe’s famous novel Robinson Crusoe. Robinson Crusoe, as you may recall, is a sailor stranded on a desert island. Because Crusoe lives alone, he catches his own fish, grows his own vegetables, and makes his own clothes. We can think of Crusoe’s activities—his production and consumption of fish, vegetables, and clothing—as being a simple economy. By examining Crusoe’s economy, we can learn some lessons that also apply to more complex and realistic economies.

What determines Crusoe’s standard of living? The answer is obvious. If Crusoe is good at catching fish, growing vegetables, and making clothes, he lives well. If he is bad at doing these things, he lives poorly. Because Crusoe gets to consume only what he produces, his living standard is tied to his productive ability.

The term productivity refers to the quantity of goods and services that a worker can produce for each hour of work. In the case of Crusoe’s economy, it is easy to see that productivity is the key determinant of living standards and that growth in productivity is the key determinant of growth in living standards. The more fish Crusoe can catch per hour, the more he eats at dinner. If Crusoe finds a better place to catch fish, his productivity rises. This increase in productivity makes Crusoe better off: He could eat the extra fish, or he could spend less time fishing and devote more time to making other goods he enjoys.

The key role of productivity in determining living standards is as true for nations as it is for stranded sailors. Recall that an economy’s gross domestic product (GDP) measures two things at once: the total income earned by everyone in the economy and the total expenditure on the economy’s output of goods and services. The reason why GDP can measure these two things simultaneously is that, for the economy as a whole, they must be equal. Put simply, an economy’s income is the economy’s output.

Like Crusoe, a nation can enjoy a high standard of living only if it can produce a large quantity of goods and services. Americans live better than Nigerians because American workers are more productive than Nigerian workers. The Japanese have enjoyed more rapid growth in living standards than Argentineans because Japanese workers have experienced more rapidly growing productivity. Indeed, one of the Ten Principles of Economics in Chapter 1 is that a country’s standard of living depends on its ability to produce goods and services.

Hence, to understand the large differences in living standards we observe across countries or over time, we must focus on the production of goods and services. But seeing the link between living standards and productivity is only the first step. It leads naturally to the next question: Why are some economies so much better at producing goods and services than others?

pr oductivity

the amount of goods and services produced from each hour of a worker’s time

HOW PRODUCTIVITY IS DETERMINED

Although productivity is uniquely important in determining Robinson Crusoe’s standard of living, many factors determine Crusoe’s productivity. Crusoe will be

534

PART NINE THE REAL ECONOMY IN THE LONG RUN

physical capital

the stock of equipment and structures that are used to produce goods and services

better at catching fish, for instance, if he has more fishing poles, if he has been trained in the best fishing techniques, if his island has a plentiful fish supply, and if he invents a better fishing lure. Each of these determinants of Crusoe’s pro- ductivity—which we can call physical capital, human capital, natural resources, and technological knowledge—has a counterpart in more complex and realistic economies. Let’s consider each of these factors in turn.

Physical Capital Workers are more productive if they have tools with which to work. The stock of equipment and structures that are used to produce goods and services is called physical capital, or just capital. For example, when woodworkers make furniture, they use saws, lathes, and drill presses. More tools allow work to be done more quickly and more accurately. That is, a worker with only basic hand tools can make less furniture each week than a worker with sophisticated and specialized woodworking equipment.

As you may recall from Chapter 2, the inputs used to produce goods and ser- vices—labor, capital, and so on—are called the factors of production. An important feature of capital is that it is a produced factor of production. That is, capital is an input into the production process that in the past was an output from the production process. The woodworker uses a lathe to make the leg of a table. Earlier the lathe itself was the output of a firm that manufactures lathes. The lathe manufacturer in turn used other equipment to make its product. Thus, capital is a factor of production used to produce all kinds of goods and services, including more capital.

human capital

the knowledge and skills that workers acquire through education, training, and experience

Human Capital A second determinant of productivity is human capital. Human capital is the economist’s term for the knowledge and skills that workers acquire through education, training, and experience. Human capital includes the skills accumulated in early childhood programs, grade school, high school, college, and on-the-job training for adults in the labor force.

Although education, training, and experience are less tangible than lathes, bulldozers, and buildings, human capital is like physical capital in many ways. Like physical capital, human capital raises a nation’s ability to produce goods and services. Also like physical capital, human capital is a produced factor of production. Producing human capital requires inputs in the form of teachers, libraries, and student time. Indeed, students can be viewed as “workers” who have the important job of producing the human capital that will be used in future production.

natural r esources

the inputs into the production of goods and services that are provided by nature, such as land, rivers, and mineral deposits

Natural Resour ces A third determinant of productivity is natural resources. Natural resources are inputs into production that are provided by nature, such as land, rivers, and mineral deposits. Natural resources take two forms: renewable and nonrenewable. A forest is an example of a renewable resource. When one tree is cut down, a seedling can be planted in its place to be harvested in the future. Oil is an example of a nonrenewable resource. Because oil is produced by nature over many thousands of years, there is only a limited supply. Once the supply of oil is depleted, it is impossible to create more.

Differences in natural resources are responsible for some of the differences in standards of living around the world. The historical success of the United States was driven in part by the large supply of land well suited for agriculture. Today, some countries in the Middle East, such as Kuwait and Saudi Arabia, are rich

CHAPTER 24 PRODUCTION AND GROWTH

535

simply because they happen to be on top of some of the largest pools of oil in the world.

Although natural resources can be important, they are not necessary for an economy to be highly productive in producing goods and services. Japan, for instance, is one of the richest countries in the world, despite having few natural resources. International trade makes Japan’s success possible. Japan imports many of the natural resources it needs, such as oil, and exports its manufactured goods to economies rich in natural resources.

Technological Knowledge A fourth determinant of productivity is technological knowledge—the understanding of the best ways to produce goods and services. A hundred years ago, most Americans worked on farms, because farm technology required a high input of labor in order to feed the entire population. Today, thanks to advances in the technology of farming, a small fraction of the population can produce enough food to feed the entire country. This technological change made labor available to produce other goods and services.

Technological knowledge takes many forms. Some technology is common knowledge—after it becomes used by one person, everyone becomes aware of it. For example, once Henry Ford successfully introduced production in assembly lines, other carmakers quickly followed suit. Other technology is proprietary—it is known only by the company that discovers it. Only the Coca-Cola Company, for instance, knows the secret recipe for making its famous soft drink. Still other technology is proprietary for a short time. When a pharmaceutical company discovers a new drug, the patent system gives that company a temporary right to be the

technological knowledge society’s understanding of the best ways to produce goods and services

F Y I

The Production

Function

Economists often use a production function to describe the relationship between the quantity of inputs used in production and the quantity of output from production. For example, suppose Y denotes the quantity of output, L the quantity of labor, K the quantity of physical capital, H the quantity of human capital, and N the quantity of natural resources. Then we might write

Y A F (L, K, H, N ),

amount of output to double as well. Mathematically, we write that a production function has constant returns to scale if, for any positive number x,

xY A F ( xL, xK, xH, xN ).

A doubling of all inputs is represented in this equation by x = 2. The right-hand side shows the inputs doubling, and the left-hand side shows output doubling.

Production functions with constant returns to scale have an interesting implication. To see what it is, set x = 1/L. Then the equation above becomes

Y/L A F (1, K/L, H/L, N/L).

where F ( ) is a function that shows how the inputs are combined to produce output. A is a variable that reflects the available production technology. As technology improves, A rises, so the economy produces more output from any given combination of inputs.

Many production functions have a property called constant returns to scale. If a production function has constant returns to scale, then a doubling of all the inputs causes the

Notice that Y/L is output per worker, which is a measure of productivity. This equation says that productivity depends on physical capital per worker (K/L ), human capital per worker (H/L ), and natural resources per worker (N/L). Productivity also depends on the state of technology, as reflected by the variable A. Thus, this equation provides a mathematical summary of the four determinants of productivity we have just discussed.