Добавил:
Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:

Gintis Moral Sentiments and Material Interests The Foundations of Cooperation in Economic Life (MIT, 2005)

.pdf
Скачиваний:
23
Добавлен:
22.08.2013
Размер:
2.08 Mб
Скачать

268

Ostrom

Walker 1994; Tang 1992; Lam 1998; Hess 1999). In Nepal, for example, we have now collected data about the rules and general management strategies used to govern and manage over 200 irrigation systems including systems that are managed by government agencies (agency managed irrigation systems, or AMIS) as well as those managed by the farmers themselves (farmer managed irrigation systems, or FMIS). We have consistently found that FMIS are able to achieve a higher agricultural yield than AMIS, that water is distributed more equitably in FMIS than AMIS, and that the irrigation systems are better maintained by FMIS than by AMIS (see Lam 1998; Joshi et al. 2000; Shivakoti and Ostrom 2002).

What is striking, moreover, is the difference in how rules are enforced by the farmers themselves on their own systems versus government officials on the government systems. On 23 percent of the AMIS systems, farmers report that government officials are likely to record official infractions. In contrast, farmers on 58 percent of the FMIS report that their own farmer-monitors record infractions observed ( Joshi et al. 2000, 76). In addition, fines are more likely to actually be imposed within FMIS than within AMIS. Furthermore, farmers also report that rules are highly likely to be followed 65 percent of the time in FMIS and only 35 percent of the time in AMIS ( Joshi et al. 2000, 76). Thus, rules and sanctions devised by the farmers themselves—and monitored by individuals who are responsible to the farmers—are more likely to be enforced and lead to higher levels of rule compliance than rules and sanctions imposed by an external agency. Rules enforced by FMIS crowd in cooperation levels rather than crowding out cooperation.

We are now engaged in a massive ten-country comparative, overtime study of diverse forest institutions (Gibson, McKean, and Ostrom 2000; Poteete and Ostrom 2004). We have again found that resource systems where local users have considerable authority to make their own rules and enforce them are able to increase the level of cooperation achieved as contrasted to systems where rules are imposed from the outside. We are also paying particular attention to the specific rules that individuals use to regulate entry and allocate uses of local resources.

What one learns from this research is the huge variety of rules that are used in practice—many combinations of which are successful. For example, we have identified twenty-seven different types of boundary rules used by self-organized resource regimes (for specifics, see E.

Policies That Crowd out Reciprocity and Collective Action

269

Ostrom 1999). Many of these rules enhance the likelihood that individuals know each other and will be engaged over the long-term with one another. In other words, the endogenously designed rules enhance the conditions needed to solve collective-action problems. We have also identified over 100 authority rules used to allocate resource users’ rights to the flow from a resource system (E. Ostrom 1999). Many of these rules focus on time, space, and technology rather than on the quantity of resource flow allocated. Consequently, these rules increase the information that individuals obtain about the actions taken by others at a low cost. Compliance rates increase when individuals feel that others are also following the rules.

The policy of assigning all authority to a central agency to design rules is based on a false conception that there are only a few rules that need to be considered and that only experts know these options and can design optimal policies. Our empirical research strongly challenges this assumption. There are thousands of individual rules that can be used to manage resources. No one, including a scientifically trained professional staff, can do a complete analysis of any particular situation.

All policies need to be viewed as experiments (Campbell 1969). The possibility of errors is always present given human limitations. Thus, creating some redundancy in the design of rules for well-bounded local resources (or communities) encourages considerable experimentation essential to discover some of the more successful combinations of rule systems (Low et al. 2001). Further, ecological systems vary from one place to another and from one mix of species to another. The combination of rules that works well for lobster fisheries may be a disaster for deep-sea fisheries (and vice versa) (Wilson et al. 2001). A good combination of rules for a river system that has multiple regulatory devices, such as dams, may be a disaster for a run-of-the-river system, and vice versa.

Thus, instead of proposing highly centralized governance systems, the best empirical evidence we can bring to bear on the question of building sustainable democratic systems for sustainable resource use is to design polycentric systems (V. Ostrom 1987, 1997). A polycentric system has multiple semiautonomous units of governance located at small, regional, national, and now international scales of organization (Keohane and Ostrom 1995). Some of these governance units may be organized in the private sector while others are organized in the public sector. Government is not the only form of governance that humans have devised over the centuries. The essential elements of dynamic

270

Ostrom

polycentric systems are mechanisms for generating information about patterns of interactions and outcomes and mechanisms for oversight and self-correction. A completely decentralized system of small local units without overlap is as incapable of learning and self-correction as a fully centralized system. Large-scale, overlapping units are an essential part of a modern democratic system. However, smallerto medium-scale units are also a necessary part of an overall polycentric system.

Modern policy analysis needs to catch up with contemporary empirical and theoretical research. The two implicit messages contained in much of contemporary public policy analysis are not only inefficient and ineffective, they are dangerous for the long-term sustainability of democratic systems of governance. The first message undermines the normative foundations of a free society. It basically says that it is okay to be narrowly self-interested and to wait for externally imposed inducements or sanctions before voluntarily contributing to collective action. The second message undermines the positive foundations of a free society by destroying the capacity of citizens to experiment with diverse ways of coping with multiple problems and to learn from this experimentation over time. This message basically says that there is one best way of solving all collective-action problems and it is only knowable to experts. Citizens are viewed as having little to contribute to the design of public policies.

Thus, much of contemporary policy analysis and the policies adopted in many modern democracies crowd out citizenship and voluntary levels of cooperation. They do this by crowding out norms of trust and reciprocity, by crowding out the knowledge of local circumstances, by crowding out the discussion of ethical issues with others who are affected, and by crowding out the experimentation needed to design effective institutions. Crowding out reciprocity, cooperation, and citizenship is a waste of human and material resources and presents a serious challenge to the sustainability of democratic institutions over time.

Notes

An earlier version of this paper was presented at a conference on ‘‘Intrinsic Motivation in Law and Business’’ in Gerzensee, Switzerland, June 18–22, 2001. The author thanks the MacArthur Foundation and the Ford Foundation for financial support; Bruno Frey, Herbert Gintis, and two anonymous reviewers for very useful comments; and Patty Lezotte for her excellent editing of multiple versions of this paper.

Policies That Crowd out Reciprocity and Collective Action

271

References

Agrawal, Arun. 1994. ‘‘Rules, Rule Making, and Rule Breaking: Examining the Fit between Rule Systems and Resource Use.’’ In Rules, Games, and Common-Pool Resources. Eds. Elinor Ostrom, Roy Gardner, and James M. Walker. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 267–282.

———. 1999. Greener Pastures: Politics, Markets, and Community among a Migrant Pastoral People. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.

Arnold, J. E. M. 1998. Managing Forests as Common Property. FAO Forestry Paper #136. Rome, Italy: Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations.

Berg, Joyce, John W. Dickhaut, and Kevin McCabe. 1995. ‘‘Trust, Reciprocity, and Social History.’’ Games and Economic Behavior 10(1):122–142.

Blomquist, William. 1992. Dividing the Waters: Governing Groundwater in Southern California. Oakland, CA: ICS Press.

Bowles, Samuel. 1998. ‘‘Endogenous Preferences: The Cultural Consequences of Markets and Other Economic Institutions.’’ Journal of Economic Literature 36:76–111.

Bromley, Daniel W., David Feeny, Margaret McKean, Pauline Peters, Jere Gilles, Ronald Oakerson, C. Ford Runge, and James Thomson, eds. 1992. Making the Commons Work: Theory, Practice, and Policy. Oakland, CA: ICS Press.

Brown, Lee P. 1977. ‘‘Bridges over Troubled Waters: A Perspective on Policing in the Black Community.’’ In Black Perspectives on Crime and the Criminal Justice System: A Symposium. Ed. Robert L. Woodson. Boston, MA: G. K. Hall, 79–105.

Campbell, Donald T. 1969. ‘‘Reforms as Experiments.’’ American Psychologist 24:409–429.

Cardenas, Juan-Camilo, John K. Stranlund, and Cleve E. Willis. 2000. ‘‘Local Environmental Control and Institutional Crowding-out.’’ World Development 28(10):1719– 1733.

Chong, D. 1991. Collective Action and the Civil Rights Movement. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Davis, Douglas D., and Charles A. Holt. 1993. Experimental Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Dawes, Robyn M., Jeanne McTavish, and Harriet Shaklee. 1977. ‘‘Behavior, Communication, and Assumptions about Other People’s Behavior in a Commons Dilemma Situation.’’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 35:1–11.

Deci, E. L., R. Koestner, and R. M. Ryan. 1999. ‘‘A Meta-analytic Review of Experiments Examining the Effects of Extrinsic Rewards on Intrinsic Motivation.’’ Psychological Bulletin 125.

Deci, E. L., and R. M. Ryan. 1985. Intrinsic Motivation and Self-Determination in Human Behavior. New York: Plenum Press.

Fehr, Ernst, and S. Ga¨chter. 1998. ‘‘Cooperation and Punishment.’’ Working paper. Zu¨- rich, Switzerland: University of Zu¨rich.

Fehr, Ernst, and Bettina Rockenbach. 2003. ‘‘Detrimental Effects of Sanctions on Human Altruism.’’ Nature 442 (March 13): 137–140.

272

Ostrom

Finlayson, A. C., and Bonnie J. McCay. 1998. ‘‘Crossing the Threshold of Ecosystem Resilience: The Commercial Extinction of Northern Cod.’’ In Linking Social and Ecological Systems: Management Practices and Social Mechanisms for Building Resilience. Eds. Fikret Berkes and Carl Folke. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Frey, Bruno S. 1994. ‘‘How Intrinsic Motivation Is Crowded Out and In.’’ Rationality and Society 6:334–352.

———. 1997. Not Just for the Money: An Economic Theory of Personal Motivation. Cheltenham, England: Edward Elgar.

Frey, Bruno S., and Matthias Benz. 2001. ‘‘Motivation Transfer Effect.’’ Working paper. Zu¨rich: University of Zu¨rich, Institute for Empirical Research in Economics.

Frey, Bruno S., and Reto Jegen. 2001. ‘‘Motivation Crowding Theory: A Survey of Empirical Evidence.’’ Journal of Economic Surveys 15:589–611.

Frey, Bruno S., and F. Oberholzer-Gee. 1997. ‘‘The Cost of Price Incentives: An Empirical Analysis of Motivation Crowding Out.’’ American Economic Review 87:746–755.

Frohlich, Norman, and Joe A. Oppenheimer. 2003. ‘‘Optimal Policies and Socially Oriented Behavior: Some Problematic Effects of an Incentive Compatible Device.’’ Public Choice 117:273–293.

Gibson, Clark C. 1999. Politicians and Poachers: The Political Economy of Wildlife Policy in Africa. New York: Cambridge University Press.

Gibson, Clark C., Margaret McKean, and Elinor Ostrom, eds. 2000. People and Forests: Communities, Institutions, and Governance. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Hardin, Garrett. 1968. ‘‘The Tragedy of the Commons.’’ Science 162:1243–1248.

Hess, Charlotte. 1999. A Comprehensive Bibliography of Common Pool Resources. (CD-ROM) Bloomington: Indiana University, Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis.

Isaac, R. Mark, and James M. Walker. 1988. ‘‘Group Size Effects in Public Goods Provision: The Voluntary Contributions Mechanism.’’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 103:179– 199.

Isaac, R. Mark, James M. Walker, and Susan Thomas. 1984. ‘‘Divergent Evidence on Free Riding: An Experimental Examination of Some Possible Explanations.’’ Public Choice 43:113–149.

Isaac, R. Mark, James M. Walker, and Arlington Williams. 1994. ‘‘Group Size and the Voluntary Provision of Public Goods: Experimental Evidence Utilizing Large Groups.’’ Journal of Public Economics 54:1–36.

Joshi, Neeraj N., Elinor Ostrom, Ganesh P. Shivakoti, and Wai Fung Lam. 2000. ‘‘Institutional Opportunities and Constraints in the Performance of Farmer-Managed Irrigation Systems in Nepal.’’ Asia-Pacific Journal of Rural Development (APJORD) 10:67–92.

Kaboolian, L., and B. J. Nelson. 1998. ‘‘Creating Organizations of Concord: Lessons for Collective Goods Theory.’’ Working paper. Berkeley: University of California, School of Public Policy and Social Research.

Keohane, Robert O., and Elinor Ostrom, eds. 1995. Local Commons and Global Interdependence: Heterogeneity and Cooperation in Two Domains. London: Sage.

Policies That Crowd out Reciprocity and Collective Action

273

Kirchler, E., Ernst Fehr, and R. Evans. 1996. ‘‘Social Exchange in the Labor Market: Reciprocity and Trust versus Egoistic Money Maximization.’’ Journal of Economic Psychology 17:313–341.

Lam, Wai Fung. 1996. ‘‘Institutional Design of Public Agencies and Coproduction: A Study of Irrigation Associations in Taiwan.’’ World Development 24(6):1039–1054.

———.1998. Governing Irrigation Systems in Nepal: Institutions, Infrastructures, and Collective Action. Oakland, CA: ICS Press.

———.Forthcoming. ‘‘Reforming Taiwan’s Irrigation Associations: Getting the Nesting of Institutions Right.’’ In Asian Irrigation in Transition: Responding to Challenges. Eds. Ganesh Shivakoti, Douglas Vermillion, Wai Fung Lam, Elinor Ostrom, Ujjwal Pradhan, and Robert Yoder. New Delhi: Sage Publications India.

Lazear, Edward P. 2000. ‘‘Performance Pay and Productivity.’’ American Economic Review 90(5):1346–1361.

Ledyard, John O. 1995. ‘‘Is There a Problem with Public Goods Provision?’’ In The Handbook of Experimental Economics. Eds. John Kagel and Alvin Roth. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 111–194.

Levine, Gilbert. 1977. ‘‘Management Components in Irrigation System Design and Operation.’’ Agricultural Administration 4:37–48.

Loveman, M. 1998. ‘‘High-Risk Collective Action: Defending Human Rights in Chile, Uruguay, and Argentina.’’ American Journal of Sociology 104:477–525.

Low, Bobbi S., Elinor Ostrom, Robert Costanza, and James Wilson. 2001. ‘‘HumanEcosystems Interactions: A Basic Dynamic Integrated Model.’’ In Institutions, Ecosystems, and Sustainability. Eds. Robert Costanza, Bobbi S. Low, Elinor Ostrom, and James Wilson. New York: Lewis Publishers, 33–57.

McGinnis, Michael, ed. 1999a. Polycentric Governance and Development: Readings from the Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

———, ed. 1999b. Polycentricity and Local Public Economies: Readings from the Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

———, ed. 2000. Polycentric Games and Institutions: Readings from the Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

Moore, Mike. 1989. ‘‘The Fruits and Fallacies of Neoliberalism: The Case of Irrigation Policy.’’ World Politics 17(1):733–750.

Offerman, T. 1997. Beliefs and Decision Rules in Public Goods Games: Theory and Experiments. Dordrecht, the Netherlands: Kluwer.

Olson, Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Ostrom, Elinor. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. New York: Cambridge University Press.

———. 1998. ‘‘Self-Governance of Common-Pool Resources.’’ In The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law, vol. 3. Ed. Peter Newman. London: Macmillan Press, 424– 433.

274

Ostrom

———.1999. ‘‘Coping with Tragedies of the Commons.’’ Annual Review of Political Science 2:493–535.

———.2000. ‘‘Collective Action and the Evolution of Social Norms.’’ Journal of Economic Perspectives 14(3):137–158.

Ostrom, Elinor, and James Walker, eds. 2003. Trust and Reciprocity: Interdisciplinary Lessons from Experimental Research. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

Ostrom, Elinor, Roy Gardner, and James M. Walker. 1994. Rules, Games, and Common-Pool Resources. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

Ostrom, Elinor, James M. Walker, and Roy Gardner. 1992. ‘‘Covenants with and without a Sword: Self-Governance is Possible.’’ American Political Science Review 86:404–417.

Ostrom, Vincent. 1987. The Political Theory of a Compound Republic: Designing the American Experiment. 2d rev. ed. Oakland, CA: ICS Press.

———. 1997. The Meaning of Democracy and the Vulnerability of Democracies: A Response to Tocqueville’s Challenge. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

Plott, Charles R. 1979. ‘‘The Application of Laboratory Experimental Methods to Public Choice.’’ In Collective Decision Making: Applications from Public Choice Theory. Ed. Clifford S. Russell. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 137–160.

Poteete, Amy, and Elinor Ostrom. 2004. ‘‘Heterogeneity, Group Size, and Collective Action: The Role of Institutions in Forest Management.’’ Development and Change 35:435– 461.

Repetto, Robert. 1986. Skimming the Water: Rent-seeking and the Performance of Public Irrigation Systems. Research report no. 4. Washington, DC: World Resources Institute.

Rothstein, B. 1998. Just Institutions Matter: The Moral and Political Logic of the Universal Welfare State. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Schlager, Edella. 1994. ‘‘Fishers’ Institutional Responses to Common-Pool Resource Dilemmas.’’ In Rules, Games, and Common-Pool Resources. Eds. Elinor Ostrom, Roy Gardner, and James M. Walker. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 247–265.

Schlager, Edella, and Elinor Ostrom. 1992. ‘‘Property-Rights Regimes and Natural Resources: A Conceptual Analysis.’’ Land Economics 68:249–262.

Sen, Amartya K. 1974. ‘‘Choice, Orderings and Morality.’’ In Practical Reason: Papers and Discussions. Ed. S. Ko¨rner. Oxford: Blackwell.

———. 1977. ‘‘Rational Fools: A Critique of the Behavioral Foundations of Economic Theory.’’ Philosophy and Public Affairs 6:317–344.

Shivakoti, Ganesh P., and Elinor Ostrom, eds. 2002. Improving Irrigation Governance and Management in Nepal. Oakland, CA: ICS Press.

Smith, Vernon L. 1982. ‘‘Microeconomic Systems as an Experimental Science.’’ American Economic Review 72:923–955.

Snaveley, Keith. 1990. ‘‘Governmental Policies to Reduce Tax Evasion: Coerced Behavior versus Services and Values Development.’’ Policy Sciences 23:57–72.

Tang, Shui Yan. 1992. Institutions and Collective Action: Self Governance in Irrigation. Oakland, CA: ICS Press.

Policies That Crowd out Reciprocity and Collective Action

275

Titmuss, R. M. 1970. The Gift Relationship. London: Allen and Unwin.

Varughese, George, and Elinor Ostrom. 2001. ‘‘The Contested Role of Heterogeneity in Collective Action: Some Evidence from Community Forestry in Nepal.’’ World Development 29(5):747–765.

Wade, Robert. 1995. ‘‘The Ecological Basis of Irrigation Institutions: East and South Asia.’’ World Development 23(12):2041–2049.

Wilson, James, Robert Costanza, Bobbi S. Low, and Elinor Ostrom. 2001. ‘‘Scale Misperceptions and the Spatial Dynamics of a Social-Ecological System.’’ In Institutions, Ecosystems, and Sustainability. Eds. Robert Costanza, Bobbi S. Low, Elinor Ostrom, and James Wilson. New York: Lewis Publishers, 59–75.

Wunsch, James S., and Dele Olowu, eds. 1995. The Failure of the Centralized State: Institutions and Self-Governance in Africa. 2d ed. Oakland, CA: ICS Press.

Yamagishi, Toshio. 1986. ‘‘The Provision of a Sanctioning System as a Public Good.’’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 51:110–116.

10

Reciprocity and the

 

 

Welfare State

 

Christina M. Fong, Samuel

 

Bowles, and Herbert Gintis

A man ought to be a friend to his friend and repay gift with gift. People should meet smiles with smiles and lies with treachery.

From the Edda, a thirteenth-century collection of Norse epic verse

10.1Introduction

The modern welfare state is a remarkable human achievement. In the world’s advanced economies, a substantial fraction of total income is regularly transferred from the better off to the less well off, and the governments that preside over these transfers are regularly endorsed by publics (Atkinson 1999). The modern welfare state is thus the most significant case in human history of a voluntary egalitarian redistribution of income among total strangers. What accounts for its popular support?

We suggest below that a compelling case can be made that people support the modern welfare state because it conforms to deeply held norms of reciprocity and conditional obligations to others. Economists have for the most part offered an alternative (empirically implausible) theory of self-regarding human motivation to explain who votes for redistribution. The most widely accepted model of the demand for redistribution in economics is the median voter model, which holds that each voter desires a personal wealth-maximizing level of redistribution. Under appropriate assumptions, it follows that the redistribution implemented by a government elected under a majority rule system is that preferred by the median-income voter. Because the distribution of income is generally skewed to the right (there are a few very rich individuals), the median voter is poorer than the mean voter and will therefore demand a positive level of redistribution.

Соседние файлы в предмете Экономика