Добавил:
Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:
книги / 591.pdf
Скачиваний:
6
Добавлен:
07.06.2023
Размер:
5.91 Mб
Скачать

China Power System Transformation

Policy, market and regulatory frameworks for power system transformation

 

 

 

 

 

 

stringent. With all eight sectors included, the China ETS will cover roughly half of the country’s CO2 emissions, with an estimated 6 000 firms participating (Pizer and Zhang, 2018).

The China ETS follows a different design than that in the European Union and systems used in the United States. Allowance allocation and standard setting are based on output and technology, using sectoral benchmarks, with free allowance allocation in the initial phases. There is no fixed cap in place, with output-based allocation being instrumental in creating extensive data networks for cap setting in later stages. As administratively set prices in China’s power sector limit the possibility for cost pass-through, the ETS is also going to include indirect emissions from electricity consumption.

In its current form, the China ETS resembles a tradeable performance standard (TPS) with technology-specific intensity standards. Since subcategorisation creates incentives for intratechnology efficiency improvements, but does not stimulate technology switching, which can lead to less cost-efficient emission reduction outcomes (Pizer and Zhang, 2018), the number of fuel standards will be limited, with higher stringency for coal than for gas-fired power plants. Contrary to a cap-and-trade system, which puts a positive price on all CO2 emissions, a TPS only prices emissions surpassing benchmark levels, which can result in lower carbon prices. However, in the long term, the objective of China’s ETS is to cap national CO2 emissions and achieve emission reduction targets for all eight sectors in line with China’s Ecological Civilisation vision. Low carbon prices and free allocation are likely to be features only in the initial ETS phases in the next few years, with the potential for the TPS to be replaced by a cap-and-trade system after China’s emissions have peaked, which it aims to achieve before 2030.

The development of China’s ETS is, furthermore, set to follow reforms that are planned for the electricity sector, as alignment between both is critical to an effective functioning of the ETS. Whereas China’s ETS policy is nationally determined and applicable to all regions, electricity sector reform is developed and implemented at provincial level. This division in jurisdictional authority can pose added complexities when provinces opt for electricity sector designs that have different outcomes on the incentives for electricity generators (low-carbon and carbonintensive generation) and consumers under a carbon pricing system. This will be a key area for China to focus effort on once electricity sector reforms are being implemented and the ETS is maturing.

Sources: ICAP (International Carbon Action Partnership) (2018), ICAP ETS Map, https://icapcarbonaction.com/en/ets-map. NDRC (2017), Contruction Plan for the National Carbon Emission Trading

Market www.ndrc.gov.cn/gzdt/201712/W020171220577386656660.pdf.

Pizer and Zhang (2018), “China’s new national carbon market”, NI WP 18-01, Nicholas Institute, Durham, NC, https://nicholasinstitute.duke.edu/publications/chinas-new-national-carbon-market.

Retail markets and distributed energy resources

Retail pricing reform

Driven largely by the many changes described in this report, reforms in retail rate design are being pursued in many jurisdictions (IEA, 2016a).40 At the same time, advances in information

40 The discussion in this section is taken from IEA (2017a).

PAGE | 110

IEA. All rights reserved

China Power System Transformation

Policy, market and regulatory frameworks for power system transformation

and communications technology (ICT) have lowered the transaction cost of communicating prices for energy and other utilities more dynamically, which opens opportunities for introducing more cost-reflective pricing structures with higher levels of granularity.

A growing number of end users now have an alternative to grid supply, and they use retail tariffs as a reference to make investment decisions. As the cost of distributed energy resources (DER) continues to decline, uptake will continue to rise.

At low penetrations, this effect is likely to have marginal impact on retail prices (LBNL, 2017). As DER uptake continues, however, this situation raises questions about distributional fairness among different end users, and may lead to a spiralling uptake of DER as grid supply price increases continue to improve the economics of self-supply.

In addition, sector coupling will link economic signals from other sectors with those of the electricity sector, and make it possible to meet a certain energy service using various sources. For example, customers may choose between using electricity (via efficient heat pumps) or natural gas for heating, or they may choose between electric or internal combustion engine cars. This increases the need for a level playing field between the different resources, whereby energy services are priced similarly and are subject to similar taxes and levies.

Finally, DER may provide system services that are not captured at all in current tariff design. This creates a need not only to consider reform of retail tariffs, but also of valuation frameworks for DER more broadly. Both aspects will be discussed in turn.

When approaching retail pricing reform, a number of relevant trade-offs and distinctions need to be made. End customers – especially residential and small commercial – often do not have the expertise and/or the interest in navigating a complex pricing structure that may expose them to wholesale market risk. However, making it possible for retailers and aggregators to access the differences in value of electricity by time and location can be critical for unlocking the full contribution of DER.

Degrees of granularity for retail tariffs

As DER generation options become cheaper, retail prices should be designed to provide fair and appropriate incentives to both network users and DER (IEA, 2016c). With modern ICT systems and emerging valuation methodologies, it becomes possible to calculate in greater detail the actual value of a given kilowatt hour (kWh) of electricity consumption at a specific time and place. The deployment of smart meters makes it possible to communicate this value to end users and use data measurements at more regular intervals to apply them in the billing process. Price signals that accurately capture the impact on overall system cost give a stronger incentive for demand shaping when and where this is most valuable to the power system.

Retail prices can be refined along three dimensions (Figure 22). First, to indicate the supplydemand balance throughout the day, tariff design may move from a single, flat tariff to various degrees of time dependency. Real-time pricing, the most advanced form of time-based pricing, has been applied in Spain since 2014, although consumers can opt out and subscribe to other supplier or contract structures (IEA, 2016d).

In addition, demand charges can reflect the contribution of an individual customer to overall generation and network costs. The precise characteristics of electricity consumption, such as the timing and magnitude of peak electricity demand, will influence the timing and location of grid planning and reinforcement.

The third dimension relates to the geographical location of consumption. The cost of delivering power to end users depends on transmission and distribution losses, and on the occurrence of congestion and voltage-related network constraints (Schweppe, 1988). The options for

Page | 111

IEA. All rights reserved

China Power System Transformation

Policy, market and regulatory frameworks for power system transformation

translating this spatial cost granularity into electricity prices range from regional tariff differences to more precise, real-time calculations of locational marginal pricing that reflect how a customer is located relative to the various grid nodes.

Figure 22. Options for retail pricing at different levels of granularity

Notes: Tx = transmission; Dx = distribution; LMP = locational marginal price.

Source: IEA (2017a), Status of Power System Transformation 2017: System Integration and Local Grids.

Retail electricity prices can be refined along three main dimensions.

Compensating DER

The methodology for compensating DER, in particular distributed generation, is a strong driver for uptake of these technologies. As far as distributed generation is concerned, setting the right level and structure of remuneration for grid injection is a complex undertaking with important implications. If set too high, a disproportionate amount of money will flow to DER owners; if too low, compensation might be unfair to DER owners. Fixed remuneration (per unit of energy) provides investment certainty, whereas variable pricing can more effectively encourage systemfriendly choices that maximise injections during hours of higher system demand.

Pricing and compensation for DER goes beyond generation options and includes incentives for energy efficiency, demand-side response and battery storage. In this report, the focus is on pricing of distributed solar PV, given the novelty of this option in China. However, this does not mean that other options are less relevant and similar principles apply to all DER.

Traditional compensation mechanisms, such as net energy metering, were designed on the supposition that the grid can act as a buffer for the differences in timing of electricity production and consumption of individual households. Household production and consumption are brought together on the final electricity bill. Under net energy metering, localised electricity production is implicitly valued at the rate of the variable component of the retail tariff, as the household can bank production both within and between billing periods (IEA, 2016c).41

Net billing applies a similar method, whereby injected surplus electricity is deducted from the electricity bill at a predetermined rate. This can be a fixed rate or it can be time and location specific. In jurisdictions where a large proportion of retail tariffs consists of volumetric rates, net energy metering has come under pressure as DER owners are able to disproportionately offset their contribution to network cost. A third compensation mechanism for DER is the feed-in

41 Under net energy metering, banked kWh credits may eventually expire. When this occurs, they are deemed “net excess generation” and are typically credited to the customer at a predetermined rate, usually set between the avoided utility wholesale energy cost and the retail electricity rate.

PAGE | 112

IEA. All rights reserved

China Power System Transformation Policy, market and regulatory frameworks for power system transformation

tariff. In this arrangement, all electricity injected into the grid is compensated at an administratively determined rate.

Many jurisdictions are shifting to other, value-based methods of compensation for decentralised generation (see IEA, 2017a, Chapter 2). Methods for such value-based compensation for DER generally fall into two categories. The first category involves taking a snapshot of current DER value, and then providing a long-term compensation guarantee based on that.

A value-of-solar (VoS) tariff assigns fixed price tariffs based on an assessment of value components, including energy services, grid support and fuel price hedging, among others (Figure 23). Minnesota became the first US state to adopt a VoS tariff, with a 25-year inflationindexed tariff that was determined through benefit-cost analysis and an extensive stakeholder consultation process (Farrell, 2014).

The second category of value-based DER compensation involves more granular DER tariffs that reflect market conditions at specific times and locations. Adding price variability based on time and location can contribute to lower system costs by sending appropriate price signals to DER customers.

Figure 23. Value components of local generation

Note: Depending on deployment scenario, the value components may be negative; for example, if deployment of distributed solar PV leads to grid upgrade requirements, it would contribute to increasing rather than decreasing capacity costs.

Source: IEA (2017a), Status of Power System Transformation 2017: System Integration and Local Grids.

Accurately rewarding DER requires a detailed analysis of the various value components.

Implications for general policy design

Recognising temporal and spatial value in the pricing of electricity supply and demand can foster greater flexibility and lower the cost of planning and operating a power system. When implementing more efficient short-run pricing, however, it is important to consider the tradeoffs that determine the effectiveness of any new tariff design.

First and foremost, regulatory design needs to balance the costs and benefits of higher granularity. Computation and implementation are the primary cost drivers when adopting higher price granularity. Whereas the pass-through of wholesale prices or LMPs calculated at the interface with high-voltage networks can be achieved by a rollout of advanced metering equipment, the use of more precise LMPs requires additional time and resources as considerable ICT capabilities are needed to verify cost calculations (MIT, 2016).

Moreover, customers, regulators and third parties all benefit from simplicity. If consumers are to adapt their behaviour in line with system needs, they must understand the applicable tariff. Alternatively, an intermediary (aggregator, retailer) can offer a simple tariff to the consumer, while monetising the value to the system as a whole.

Page | 113

IEA. All rights reserved

Соседние файлы в папке книги