
- •Commercial Law
- •Contents
- •Preface
- •Abbreviations
- •Table of Statutory Provisions
- •Table of Cases
- •1 Introduction
- •1 Introduction
- •2 What is agency?
- •3 Nature and characteristics of agency
- •4 The different types of agency
- •5 Conclusion
- •6 Recommended reading
- •1 Introduction
- •2 The authority of an agent
- •3 Agency by ratification
- •4 Agency of necessity
- •5 Conclusion
- •6 Recommended reading
- •1 Introduction
- •2 Duties of an agent
- •3 Rights of an agent
- •4 Commercial agents and principals
- •5 Disclosed agency
- •6 Undisclosed agency
- •7 Termination of agency
- •8 Recommended reading
- •Introduction
- •1 Introduction
- •2 Background
- •3 Development of the sale of goods
- •4 Equality of bargaining power: non-consumers and consumers
- •5 Impact of the European Union
- •6 Contract of sale
- •7 Contracts for non-monetary consideration
- •8 Contracts for the transfer of property or possession
- •9 Recommended reading
- •1 Introduction
- •2 Background
- •3 Sale of Goods Act 1979, section 12: the right to sell
- •4 Sale of Goods Act 1979, section 13: compliance with description
- •5 Sale of Goods Act 1979, section 14(2): satisfactory quality
- •6 Sale of Goods Act 1979, section 14(3): fitness for purpose
- •7 Sale of Goods Act 1979, section 15: sale by sample
- •8 Exclusion and limitation of liability
- •9 Acceptance
- •10 Remedies
- •11 Recommended reading
- •1 Introduction
- •2 Background to the passage of property and risk
- •3 Rules governing the passage of property
- •4 Passage of risk
- •5 The nemo dat exceptions
- •6 Delivery and payment
- •7 Remedies
- •8 Recommended reading
- •1 Introduction
- •2 Background
- •3 Provision of Services Regulations 2009
- •4 Supply of Goods and Services Act 1982
- •5 Recommended reading
- •1 Introduction
- •2 Background
- •3 Electronic Commerce (EC Directive) Regulations 2002
- •4 Distance selling
- •5 Recommended reading
- •Introduction
- •1 Introduction
- •2 CIF contracts
- •3 FOB contracts
- •4 Ex Works
- •5 FAS contracts
- •6 Conclusion
- •7 Recommended reading
- •1 Introduction and background
- •2 Structure and scope
- •3 UNIDROIT Principles of International Commercial Contracts
- •4 Conclusion
- •5 Recommended reading
- •1 Introduction and background
- •2 Open account
- •3 Bills of exchange
- •4 Documentary collections
- •5 Introduction to letters of credit
- •6 Factoring
- •7 Forfaiting
- •8 Conclusion
- •9 Recommended reading
- •1 Introduction
- •2 Hague and Hague-Visby Rules
- •3 Charterparties
- •4 Time charterparty
- •5 Common law obligations of the shipper
- •6 Common law obligations of the carrier
- •7 Bills of lading
- •8 Electronic bills of lading
- •9 Conclusion
- •10 Recommended reading
- •Introduction
- •1 Introduction
- •2 Background
- •3 Development of negligence
- •4 The move to strict liability
- •5 Types of defect
- •6 Developments in strict liability
- •7 Recommended reading
- •1 Introduction
- •2 Personnel
- •3 Meaning of ‘product’
- •4 Defectiveness
- •5 Defences
- •6 Contributory negligence
- •7 Recoverable damage
- •8 Limitations on liability
- •9 Recommended reading
- •Introduction
- •1 Introduction
- •2 Background
- •3 Enforcement strategy
- •4 Criminal law controls
- •5 Civil law enforcement
- •6 Recommended reading
- •1 Introduction
- •2 Scope of the 2008 Regulations
- •3 Prohibition against unfair commercial practices
- •4 Codes of practice
- •5 Misleading actions
- •6 Misleading omissions
- •7 Aggressive commercial practices
- •8 Commercial practices which are automatically unfair
- •9 Offences
- •10 Recommended reading
- •1 Introduction
- •2 Background
- •3 Controls over misleading advertising
- •4 Comparative advertising
- •5 Promotion of misleading or comparative advertising
- •6 Recommended reading
- •1 Introduction
- •1 Introduction
- •2 History of banking regulation: early policy initiatives
- •3 New Labour and a new policy
- •4 The Financial Services Authority
- •5 The Coalition government
- •6 Conclusion
- •7 Recommended reading
- •1 Introduction
- •2 What is a bank?
- •3 What is a customer?
- •4 Bank accounts
- •5 Cheques
- •6 Payment cards
- •7 Banker’s duty of confidentiality
- •8 Banking Conduct Regime
- •9 Payment Services Regulations 2009
- •10 Conclusion
- •11 Recommended reading
- •1 Introduction
- •2 European banking regulation
- •3 The Financial Services Authority
- •4 Financial Services Compensation Scheme
- •5 Financial Ombudsman Scheme
- •6 Financial Services and Markets Tribunal
- •7 The Bank of England
- •8 Bank insolvency
- •9 Illicit finance
- •10 Conclusion
- •11 Recommended reading
- •1 Introduction
- •1 Introduction
- •2 Evolution of the consumer credit market
- •3 Consumer debt, financial exclusion and over-indebtedness
- •4 Irresponsible lending
- •5 Regulation of irresponsible lending
- •6 Irresponsible borrowing
- •7 Ineffective legislative protection for consumers
- •8 A change of policy
- •9 Lessons from the United States
- •10 Conclusion
- •11 Recommended reading
- •1 Introduction
- •2 Crowther Committee on Consumer Credit
- •3 Consumer Credit Act 1974
- •4 Formalities
- •5 Cancellation of agreements
- •7 Documentation of credit and hire agreements
- •8 Matters arising during the currency of credit or hire agreements
- •9 Credit advertising
- •10 Credit licensing
- •11 Unfairness test
- •12 Other powers of the court
- •13 Financial Ombudsman Service
- •14 Enforcement
- •15 Consumer Credit Directive
- •16 Conclusion
- •17 Recommended reading
- •Bibliography
- •Index
410 |
|
Government policy |
|
|
|
|
|
which were legal bodies, supervising their members and operating in differ- |
|
|
ent sectors of the investment industry.23 In order to be recognised, a prospect- |
|
|
ive SRO had to apply to the SIB for recognition and, if the application satisfied |
|
|
the statutory conditions, it must be accepted. A recognised professional body |
|
|
(RPB) regulated the practice of a profession rather than having as its main pur- |
|
|
pose the regulation of investment business.24 |
|
|
The Financial Services Act (FSA) 1986 came into effect on 29 April 1988 and it |
|
continued the traditional self-regulation system of financial regulation.25 The aim |
|
|
|
of the Act was to regulate investment business and some elements of the occupa- |
|
|
tional pension schemes.26 According to Professor Gower, ‘the scope of the Act |
|
|
is wide – much wider than that of the Prevention of Fraud (Investments) Acts’.27 |
|
However, the FSA 1986 did not apply to all aspects of the financial services sec- |
|
|
tor; for example, the banking sector was regulated by the Bank of England under |
|
|
the Banking Act 1987. The FSA 1986 remained on the statute books until it was |
|
|
replaced by the Financial Services and Markets Act (FSMA) 2000. |
3â New Labour and a new policy
Three weeks after the 1997 general election, Gordon Brown, then Chancellor of the Exchequer, announced that work would begin on the reform of the regulatory structure created under the FSA 1986.28 The government had outlined its intention to reform the system in 1995,29 and proclaimed that ‘we propose to make the SIB directly responsible for the regime broadly covered by the 1986 Act’.30 This was emphatically re-emphasised in 1997 when the Labour Party pledged that ‘as the guardians of other people’s money there needs to be effective supervision and regulation of the industry’.31 However, it must be noted that the Conservative government had previously asked the then Chairman of the SIB, Andrew Large, to conduct a review of its effectiveness in 1992.32 Similarly, in 1994 the Treasury Select Committee also conducted a broad enquiry into financial services regulation.33 Following the announcement in May 1997, the
23A self-regulating organisation was defined as an organisation that ‘regulates the carrying on of investment business of any kind by enforcing rules which are binding on persons carrying on business of that kind either because they are members of that body or because they are otherwise subject to its control’. FSA 1986, s.8(1).
24Fisher and Bewsey above, n 2 at 28.
25For a more detailed discussion of self regulation under the FSA 1986 see Gower above, n 11, at 13–17.
26 Fisher and Bewsey, above n. 2, at 16.â 27â Gower, above n. 11, at 18.
28HC. Debs. cols. 508–11, 20 May 1997. See also S. Bazley, ‘The Financial Services Authority: risk based regulation, principles based rules and accountability’ (2008) 23(8) Journal of International Banking Law and Regulation 422.
29 HC Debs. cols. 1184–5, 14 December 1995, Alistair Darling.â 30â Ibid.
31Labour’s Manifesto: Equipping Britain for the Future (London, 1997).
32Securities and Investment Board, Financial Services Regulation: Making the Two Tier System work (London, 1993).
33Treasury and Civil Service Committee The Regulation of Financial Services in the UK, HC 332-I, 1994–1995 (London, 1995).
411 |
3â New Labour and a new policy |
|
|
|
|
|
Conservative Party, then in opposition, expressed its concerns over the state- |
|
|
ment and subsequent uncertainty arising from it.34 However, this view was |
|
|
in the minority, as the proposals were supported by the Financial Times,35 |
|
|
the Consumers Association36 and the Chief Executive of Lloyds TSB.37 One |
|
|
of the most interesting responses was from the Bank of England, whose offi- |
|
|
cial response was ‘studiously guarded’.38 It took the view that ‘what matters |
|
|
is not the Bank’s position but the whole structure of financial regulation and |
|
|
what is best for depositor, investor and policy-holder protection’.39 Following |
|
|
the announcement, ‘the government lost no time in beginning to implement |
|
|
its ambitious proposals. A new Chairman of the SIB was appointed in August |
|
|
1997, and in anticipation of its new role, the SIB was renamed the Financial |
|
|
Services Authority (FSA) in October 1998’.40 The reforms were published in the |
|
|
Financial Services and Markets Bill 1998. The next part of the chapter identifies |
|
|
the factors that influenced the government to alter its policy from self-regula- |
|
|
tion towards creating a sole financial regulatory agency. |
|
|
(a)â Importance of the banking sector to the United Kingdom economy |
|
|
An important reason why the self-regulatory stance of the FSA 1986 was |
|
|
reformed is the contribution made by the financial services sector towards the |
|
|
economy. The economic functions of the financial services sector can be divided |
|
|
into three broad categories: matching savers, borrowers and investments |
|
|
through the investment chain; risk pooling; and managing and facilitating pay- |
|
|
ments.41 London’s importance as the centre of the global financial services sec- |
|
|
tor can be traced back to the twelfth century.42 Blair noted that ‘the process of |
|
|
internationalisation received an important boost in London’s “bid bang” in the |
|
|
mid-1980s. In particular, deregulation made it possible for non-UK acquisition |
|
|
of firms, and led to enormous inward investment.’43 Similarly, Professor Gower |
|
|
noted that ‘London, thanks to the Euro-market, was still a major international |
|
|
financial centre and the national interest demanded that it remained’.44 |
|
|
34 |
HC Debs. cols 509–11,20 May 1997, Kenneth Clarke. |
|
35 |
‘All change for the super-SIB’, Financial Times, 21 May 1997, available at www.ft.com. |
|
36 |
‘Brown signals overhaul of City regulation’, Independent, 21 May 1997, available at www. |
|
|
independent.co.uk. |
|
37 |
‘One watchdog to monitor all City dealings’, The Times, 21 May 1997, available at www. |
|
|
thetimesonline.co.uk. |
|
38 |
Blair, above n. 8, at 23. |
|
39 |
‘Transfer of banking supervision’, Bank of England Press Release, 20 May 1997, available at www. |
|
|
bankofengland.co.uk. |
|
40 |
E. Lomnicka, ‘Reform of the UK financial services regulation: the creation of a single regulator’ |
|
|
(1999) Journal of Business Law 480, 481. |
|
41 |
HM Treasury, The UK Financial Services Sector: rising to the Challenges and Opportunities of |
|
|
Globalisation (London, 2005) 5. |
|
42 |
Fisher and Bewsey, above n. 2, at 167. |
|
43 |
W. Blair, ‘The reform of financial regulation in the UK’ (1998) Journal of International Banking |
|
|
Law 43. |
|
44 |
Gower, above n. 11, at 2. |
412 |
Government policy |
|
|
In addition to its historical significance, the following statistics highlight the importance of the financial services sector to the economy.45 In 1996, the financial intermediation sector contributed 6.4 per cent, or £42.7 billion to the United Kingdom’s gross domestic product.46 In 1999, over 1.17 million people were employed in the financial intermediation sector.47 In 1998, the typical daily turnover of foreign exchange in the United Kingdom was approximately £380 billion. This was almost more than that of the United States, Japan and Singapore combined.48 It is also interesting to note that more companies are listed on the London Stock Exchange than on the Tokyo or New York Stock Exchanges.49 In 1998, the annual turnover of the London Stock Market was £1,037.1 billion, making it the world’s third largest stock market. In 2003, the United Kingdom produced over 40 per cent of the world’s turnover in crossborder foreign equity trading.50 The UK private equity industry accounted for 47 per cent of the total annual European private equity investment in 2003.51 According to a 2005 study by the Centre for Economic and Business Research, the City of London accounted for ‘41 per cent of all city-type financial services in the EU’.52 In 2005, HM Treasury reported that:
the UK financial services sector also contributes directly to output, employment, trade and productivity in the UK. It accounts for over 5 per cent of UK gross value added, one million jobs and a trade surplus of 1.6 per cent of GDP. Moreover, there is evidence that it is a source of higher-than-average productivity within the UK, and that productivity within the sector is growing faster than in the economy as a whole.53
The British Bankers Association (BBA) reported that ‘the UK’s financial industry has grown faster than any other business sector over the past ten years’.54 The Chief Executive of the BBA, Angela Knight, stated that ‘financial services are the powerhouse of the UK economy: a massive contributor to the Exchequer through tax, an employer of more than a million people directly and one of the UK’s last acknowledged world-leading industries’.55
In light of the above evidence, it is essential that the United Kingdom has an effective financial regulatory environment that protects investors and safeguards a significant contributor to the economy.
45 HM Treasury Financial Services Report, above n. 41, at 5.â 46â Blair, above n. 8, at 14.
47International Financial Services, International Financial Markets in the UK (London, 2004).
48Blair, above n. 8, at 7.
49HM Treasury Financial Services Report, above n. 41, at 9.
50Ibid.â 51â Ibid. 10.
52Centre for Economics and Business Research, The City’s Importance to the EU Economy 2005 (Corporation of London, 2005) 35.
53HM Treasury Financial Services Report, above n 41, at 18.
54British Bankers Association Press Release, ‘Financial services sector tops UK growth tables’; 18 January 2008, available at www.bba.org.uk. See also National Statistics News Release ‘Financial services top growth sector 1996 to 2006’, Economic and Labour Market Review, 14 January 2008, available at www.statistics.gov.uk.
55BBA Press Release, above n. 54.
413 |
3â New Labour and a new policy |
|
|
|
|
|
Q1 What was the former Labour government’s policy towards banking regula- |
|
|
tion between 1997 and 2010? |
|
|
(b)â Ineffective legislative framework |
|
|
The regulatory system under the FSA 1986 was extremely fragmented and often |
|
|
confusing for consumers and the financial services sector. The high level of |
|
|
fragmentation is illustrated by the fact that there were several pieces of legisla- |
|
|
tion relating to the regulation of the financial services and banking sector. This |
|
|
caused uncertainty and an unsatisfactory division of responsibility between |
|
|
the regulators.56 Blair commented that ‘the proliferation of agencies was over- |
|
|
complex’.57 Similarly, McDowall noted that ‘the structure of financial services |
|
|
regulation was certainly confusing given that there are twenty bodies conduct- |
|
|
ing financial services regulation’.58 The problems resulting from this fragmen- |
|
|
tation were graphically highlighted by the lack of action, co-operation and |
|
|
communication between the regulatory agencies during the pensions mis- |
|
|
selling |
crisis in the 1990s.59 Therefore, the creation of a single agency would pre- |
|
sent ‘opportunities for developing a rational and coherent regulatory system’.60 |
|
|
It has also been argued that the creation of a single regulatory agency ‘brings |
|
|
with it the obvious benefits of economies of scale’.61 Lomnicka concluded ‘it is |
|
|
clear that regulatory functions which affect the whole financial sector can best |
|
|
be undertaken on a unified and co-ordinated basis’.62 |
|
|
There are numerous examples of the failures of the FSA 1986 regulatory sys- |
|
|
tem. For example, the level of supervision and the enforcement policies of the |
|
|
SROs and the SIB were inconsistent,63 which clearly indicated the failings of the |
|
|
system and damaged the confidence of investors.64 |
|
|
One of the most important innovations introduced by the FSA 1986 was the |
|
|
creation of the SIB. The FSA 1986 introduced a higher level of regulation, which |
|
|
imposed more obligations on the regulated sector. To enforce these higher |
|
|
standards of behaviour, the SIB was given enhanced statutory enforcement |
56HM Treasury, Financial Services and Markets Bill: A Consultation Document, Part 1, Overview of Financial Regulatory Reform (London, 1998) 1. See also see R. McDowall, ‘Financial services authority: progress or pragmatism?’ (1998) 13(4) Journal of International Banking Law 123, 124. The relevant agencies were the Building Societies Commission, Friendly Societies Commission, Insurance Directorate of the Department of Trade and Industry, Investment Management Regulatory Organisation, Personal Investment Authority, Registry of Friendly Societies, Securities and Futures Authority, SIB and the Supervision and Surveillance Division of the Bank of England.
57See Blair, above n. 43, at 45.â 58â See McDowall, above n. 56, at 124.
59See Lominicka, above, n. 40, at 488. For a more detailed discussion of the pensions mis-selling crisis, see R. Nobles, and J. Black, ‘Personal pensions misselling: the causes and lessons from regulatory failure’ (1998) 61(6) Modern Law Review 789 and J. Virgo, and P. Ryley, ‘Mis-selling of personal pension plans: a legal perspective’ (1999) 5(1) Journal of Pensions Management 18.
60 See Lominicka, above n. 40, at 486.â 61â Ibid.â 62â Ibid. 488.
63See HM Treasury Consultation document, above n. 56, at 124..
64See Bazley, above n. 28, at 423.
414 |
|
Government policy |
|
|
|
|
|
||
|
|
powers combined with tougher criminal sanctions.65 As pointed out by Grey, |
||
|
|
‘in order to ensure efficacious enforcement of the FSA [1986], the SIB had an |
||
|
|
impressive range of investigatory powers’.66 The SIB could apply for either an |
||
|
|
injunction or a restitution order against unauthorised investment businesses |
.67 |
|
|
|
The SIB had the power to bar financial practitioners from operating in the |
||
|
|
financial services industry.68 FSA 1986, section 61 provided comparable powers |
||
|
|
to those in section 6 to act against unacceptable ways of carrying our invest- |
||
|
|
ment business.69 Finally, the SIB could apply to the court to wind up either an |
||
|
authorised person or an appointed representative.70 However, the prosecutor- |
|||
|
|
ial role of the SIB was limited to breaches relating to the authorisation to con- |
||
|
|
duct investment business and insider dealing.71 Its enforcement performance |
||
|
|
was hampered by its unwillingness to take on a larger prosecutorial role.72 The |
||
|
|
enforcement performance of the SIB can be criticised because it paid little or no |
||
|
|
attention to supervision or improving its statutory investigatory mechanisms |
||
|
|
and it did little to tackle or prevent commercial fraud.73 Conversely, it has been |
||
|
|
argued that during its lifespan, the SIB did ensure that the financial sector and |
||
|
|
markets were effectively regulated.74 |
|
|
|
|
|
In summary, the regulatory system under the FSA 1986 had several funda- |
|
|
|
mental flaws. First, the Act created too many financial regulatory agencies.75 |
||
|
65 |
J. Fishman, ‘A comparison of enforcement of securities law violations in the UK and US’ (1993) |
||
|
|
|
14(9) Company Lawyer 163. |
|
|
66 |
For a more detailed commentary on these provisions of the FSA 1986 see J. Grey,‘Financial |
|
|
|
|
|
Services Act 1986 Reforms: Part 2’ (1991) 9(9) International Banking Law 412, 415. |
|
|
67 |
FSA 1986, s.6. |
|
|
|
68 |
Ibid. s.59. For a critical commentary on these powers see R. Davies, ‘Powers granted to the SIB |
|
|
|
|
|
under FSA 1986, s.59’ (1994) 15(4) Company Lawyer 119. |
|
|
69 |
For a more detailed commentary of these powers see H. McVea, ‘Fashioning a system of civil |
|
|
|
|
|
penalties for insider dealing: sections 61 and 62 of the Financial Services Act 1986’ (1996) |
|
|
|
|
Journal of Business Law (July) 344 and D. Capps, ‘The UK Securities and Investments Board: how |
|
|
|
|
it can and does protect investors’ (1993) 8(6) Journal of International Banking Law 248. |
|
|
70 |
FSA, ss.71 and 72. For a more detailed discussion and analysis of the powers of the SIB see R. |
|
|
|
|
|
Harwood, ‘The SIB’s exercise of its enforcement powers’ (1995) 16(9) Company Lawyer 271 |
|
|
|
|
and C. Currie, ‘Civil enforcement as a regulatory device: the use of the civil law as a means of |
|
|
|
|
enforcing securities law violations’ (1996) 17(5) Company Lawyer 139. |
|
|
71 |
For a more detailed discussion of the enforcement of the insider dealing provisions of the |
|
|
|
|
|
FSA 1986, see E. Lomnicka, ‘Curtailing section 62 accountability’ (1991) Journal of Business |
|
|
|
|
Law (July) 353 and A. Alcock, ‘Insider dealing: how did we get here’ (1994) 15(3) Company |
|
|
|
|
LawyerÂ67. |
|
|
72 |
It should be noted that the FSA 1986 did provide the SIB with fraud enforcement powers under |
||
|
|
|
s.47. For a more detailed analysis see W. Barnett, ‘Fraud enforcement in the Financial Services |
|
|
|
|
Act 1986: an analysis and discussion of section 47’ (1996) 17(7) The Company Lawyer 203. |
|
|
73 |
See B. Rider, ‘Policing the city: combating fraud and other abuses in the corporate securities |
|
|
|
|
|
industry’ (1988) 41 Current Legal Problems 47 and J. Long, ‘Policing the markets: SIB’s role’ |
|
|
|
|
(1994) 15(3) Company Lawyer 83. |
|
|
74 |
See Blair, above n. 43, at 49. This view is also supported by I. MacNeil, ‘The future for financial |
|
|
|
|
|
regulation: the financial services and markets bill’ (1999) 62(5) Modern Law Review 725 and M. |
|
|
|
|
Taylor, ‘Redrawing the regulatory map: why the Financial Services Act must not be reformed in |
|
|
|
|
isolation’ (1996) 11(10) Journal of International Banking Financial Law 463. |
|
|
75 |
Fishman, in particular, noted that the approach adopted towards the enforcement of the FSA 1986 |
||
|
|
|
has been ‘marked by overlapping authority and lack of co-ordination’. See above n. 65, at 171. |
|
415 |
3â New Labour and a new policy |
|
|
|
|
|
Secondly, the provisions of the Act were not effectively enforced. Thirdly, this |
|
|
period of financial regulation was blighted by a number of high profile financial |
|
|
scandals. Fourthly, the FSA 1986 was poorly drafted and very difficult for con- |
|
|
sumers to understand.76 |
|
|
Q2 Briefly outline some of the criticisms of the Financial Services Act 1986. |
|
|
(c)â Independence of the Bank of England |
|
|
The Labour government adopted a two-stage legislative approach towards |
|
|
reforming financial services regulation. In May 1997, Gordon Brown announced |
|
|
the first part of the reform process: changes to the role, powers and function of |
|
|
the Bank of England.77 The Bank of England was to concentrate upon its role |
|
|
of curbing inflation, which according to Arora ‘would bring it in line with the |
|
|
Bundesbank and the Federal Reserve Bank’.78 The Bank of England Act 1998 |
|
|
gave the Bank of England independence in determining the United Kingdom’s |
|
|
monetary policy.79 The objectives of the monetary policy of the Bank of England |
|
|
are to maintain price stability, and to support the economic policy of the gov- |
|
|
ernment through growth and employment.80 The legislation also created a |
|
|
Monetary Policy Committee, which has the responsibility of formulating monet- |
|
|
ary policy.81 McDowall took the view that ‘the creation of the Financial Services |
|
|
Authority was the flipside of UK Chancellor Gordon Brown’s announcement that |
|
|
UK interest rate and money supply management would devolve from the UK |
|
|
Treasury to the Bank of England’.82 He added ‘the changes are progress but they |
|
|
do seem to have come from a desire to change the role of the Bank of England |
|
|
rather then an altruistic desire to improve financial services regulation’.83 Blair et |
|
|
al. took the view that the ‘1998 Act reflects a new policy consensus in favour of |
|
|
taking the conduct of monetary policy out of direct political control’.84 |
|
|
|
The second stage was the formal transfer of banking supervision from the |
|
Bank of England to the FSA. Since the Bank of England Act 1696 ‘the Bank |
|
|
has had a virtual monopoly as regards the carrying on of fully fledged banking |
|
|
business by a corporation’.85 The Banking Acts 1979 and 1987 granted the Bank |
|
|
76 |
Justice compared attempting to understand the Act to ‘wading through blancmange’. See Justice, |
|
|
The Protection of the Small Investor (Cambridge, 1992). |
|
77 |
HM Treasury, ‘The Chancellor’s statement to the House of Commons on the Bank of England’, |
|
|
49/97, 20 May 1997, available at www.hm-treasury.gov.uk. |
|
78 |
A. Arora, ‘Changes to the powers of the Bank of England’ (1997) 16(3) Journal of International |
|
|
Banking and Financial Law 21. For a more detailed discussion of this see M. Blair, R. Cranston, |
|
|
C. Ryan, and M. Taylor, Blackstone’s guide to the Bank of England Act 1998 (London, 1998) 13–18. |
|
79 |
This amended the provision under the Bank of England Act 1946 that HM Treasury were able |
|
|
to direct the Bank of England where the public interest demanded it. Bank of England Act 1946, |
|
|
s.4(1). |
|
80 |
Bank of England Act 1998, s.11.â 81â Bank of England Act 1998, s.13. |
82 See McDowall, above n. 56, at 123.â 83â Ibid. 127.â 84â M. Blair et al., above n. 78, 10.
85E. Ellinger, E. Lomnicka, and R. Hooley, Modern Banking Law (Oxford University Press, 2002)Â29.
416 |
Government policy |
|
|
|
|
|
of England the power and the duty to supervise the banks authorised by it to |
|
|
carry on a deposit-taking business in the United Kingdom.86 Part III of the 1998 |
|
|
Act transferred the Bank of England’s powers and responsibilities for the super- |
|
|
vision of the banking sector and wholesale money market institutions to the |
|
|
FSA.87 The FSA inherited the regulatory function of the Insurance Directorate |
|
|
of HM Treasury, the Building Societies Commission, the Friendly Societies |
|
|
Commission and the Registry of Friendly Societies. Arora concluded that the |
|
|
‘the changes announced … will have an unprecedented effect on the powers of |
|
|
the Bank of England’.88 Taylor took the view that ‘the Bank of England Act 1998 |
|
|
amounts to one of the most significant changes to the Bank’s governance, role |
|
|
and functions in its 300-year history. It is certainly the most significant legisla- |
|
|
tive change to affect the Bank since nationalisation in 1946.’89 |
|
|
(d)â Ineffective consumer protection and financial scandals |
|
|
One of the most important reasons why the Labour government created the |
|
|
FSA was the lack of protection afforded to investors. Banking regulation under |
|
|
the stewardship of the Bank of England was beset with financial scandals, |
|
|
including the secondary banking crisis, and the banking collapses of Johnson |
|
|
Matthey Bank, Barlow Clowes, Bank of Credit and Commerce International |
|
|
(BCCI) and Barings Bank, and of Equitable Life. The Labour government felt |
|
|
that there was a genuine need for effective regulation because these scandals |
|
|
undermined confidence within the banking and financial services industry. The |
|
|
collapse of any financial institution will have a major impact on customers, both |
|
|
individual and businesses, and it is therefore unsurprising that successive gov- |
|
|
ernments have attempted to safeguard the stability of the banking and financial |
|
|
services system by imposing tougher regulation. The next section briefly high- |
|
|
lights the inadequacies of the performance of the Bank of England and how |
|
|
these contributed towards the change of policy by the Labour government. |
|
|
(i)â The secondary banking crisis |
|
|
The secondary banking crisis of the 1970s was preceded by a ‘period of UK |
|
|
financial liberalisation, [during which] a number of smaller or “secondary” |
|
|
86 |
For a more detailed commentary on how the Bank of England regulated the banking sector, see |
|
|
D. Singh, Banking Regulation of UK and US financial markets (Ashgate, 2007) 8–17 and more |
|
|
specifically on its role under the Banking Act 1987, see A. Arora, ‘The Banking Act 1987: Part 1’ |
|
|
(1988) 9(1) The Company Lawyer, 8. |
|
87 |
Bank of England Act 1998, s.21. The Act transferred to the FSA the Bank of England’s |
|
|
supervision powers under the Banking Act 1987, the Banking Coordination (Second Council |
|
|
Directive) Regulations 1992, SI 1992/3218 Building Societies Act 1985, s.101(4) FSA 1986, s.43 |
|
|
and the Investment Services Regulations 1995, SI 1995/3275. |
|
88 |
Arora, above n. 78, 21. |
|
89 |
Ibid., 17. For a more detailed commentary of the history of the Bank of England, see J. Wood, A |
|
|
History of Central Banking in Great Britain and the United States (Cambridge University Press, |
|
|
2005) 32–116. |

417 3â New Labour and a new policy
banks rapidly expanded their lending to property companies in the early 1970s’.90 However, the growth was short lived when the government decided to implement a restrictive financial policy in 1973. As a result, the public’s confidence in the secondary banking sector began to wane, and depositors began to withdraw their savings. The Bank of England responded by creating the ‘Control Committee of the Bank of England and the English and Scottish Clearing Banks’, which provided financial support and became known as the ‘lifeboat’.91 In practice, this meant that any lending risks were equally shared amongst all members of the Committee. Dale pointed out that ‘by August 1974 total lifeboat support approached £1.2 billion, representing 40 per cent of the participating banks’ capital. Beyond this, the banks were not prepared to go, with the result that any further assistance had to be provided by the Bank of England at its own risk. During this period some banks that had received liquidity support now faced insolvency.’92
(ii)â Johnson Matthey Bank
Johnson Matthey Bank faced collapse in 1984 and highlighted the inadequacies of banking regulation under the Banking Act 1979.93 This bank began to have financial problems in 1984 after it decided to lend to a small number of customers who faced financial problems.94 The Bank of England became aware of the difficulties in 1984 when it was informed that the bank needed extensive financing to prevent its collapse. The Bank of England decided that this bank could not be allowed to collapse and it formulated a financial rescue package of £245 million. Additionally, Johnson Matthey Bank was able to raise £130 million from its own diminishing resources.95 The light-touch approach adopted by the Bank of England had resulted in Johnson Matthey Bank being able to breach the safeguards put in place by the Banking Act 1979 by distracting the Bank of England’s attention away from its financial problems.96 Ellinger et al. took the view that ‘if JMB had been subjected to the more stringent supervision which applies to licensed deposit-takers, its financial difficulties would have been discovered earlier’.97 They added that ‘following the JMB affair, the question of bank supervision was reviewed by a Committee set up by the Chancellor in 1984 and chaired by the governor of the Bank of England’.98 It is important to note that Johnson Matthey Bank’s difficulties led to the enactment of the Banking Act 1987.
90R. Dale, ‘Bank crisis management: the case of the United Kingdom’ (1995) 10(8) Journal of International Banking Law 326, 327.
91Ibid.â 92â Ibid.
93E. Ellinger, E. Lomnicka, and R. Hooley, Ellinger’s Modern Banking Law (Oxford University Press, 2006) 33.
94 Dale, above n. 90, at 327.â 95â Ibid. 328.
96D. Lewis, ‘The Banking Bill: between Charybdis and Scylla’ (1987) 2(1) Journal of International Banking Law 49, 50.
97Ellinger et al., above n. 85, at 98.
98Ibid. 33.
418 |
Government policy |
|
|
(iii)â Barlow Clowes
A graphic illustration of the inadequacies of the approach towards financial regulation was the collapse of Barlow Clowes. The company was created in 1973 by Peter and Elizabeth Clowes,99 and operated out of Jersey due to a loophole in the UKs tax regime. When the loophole was closed by the Finance Act 1985, the company was renamed Barlow Clowes International and moved to Gibraltar. Barlow Clowes International offered investors a tax efficient and low risk scheme which proved to be extremely popular, more so than its predecessor. A large percentage of the money that was invested in Barlow Clowes International ‘found its way into loans made to companies connected with Clowes and his associates or was used to buy yachts and property’.100 The Department of Trade and Industry (DTI) appointed inspectors to investigate the operations of Barlow Clowes International when it became disturbed about its activities.101 The evidence collected by the inspectors resulted in the SIB obtaining a court order that compelled Barlow Clowes International to be wound up and it was subsequently placed into liquidation in 1988.102 Johnson described the incident as ‘a sorry tale of how thousands of investors, many of them elderly and retired, stand to lose substantial sums of money’.103 The two companies had amassed £190 million from approximately 20,000 misled investors.
Following the collapse of the company, many MPs referred complaints from local constituents to the Parliamentary Commissioner for Administration (Ombudsman).104 The nature of the complaints related to actions by the DTI under the Prevention of Fraud (Investments) Act 1958.105 The report by the Parliamentary Ombudsman highlighted several areas ‘in which there had been significant maladministration by the DTI’.106 These included an error by the DTI, who on four separate occasions allowed Barlow Clowes to continue operating without a licence as required under the Prevention of Fraud (Investments) Act 1958.107 By 1984, when the DTI had finally accepted that Barlow Clowes
International had been operating without a licence, its decision to allow the company to continue trading also amounted to maladministration.108 In
99G. Drewry, and R. Gregory, ‘Barlow Clowes and the Ombudsman: Part 1’ (1991) Public Law (Summer) 192, 193.
100Ibid.
101The inspectors were appointed under the FSA 1986, s.106.
102Drewry and Gregory, above n. 99, at 193.
103H. Johnson, ‘The Barlow Clowes affair and government regulation’ (1989) 7(8) Journal of International Banking Law 114 114.
104V. Younghusband, ‘Financial regulation: the Barlow Clowes affair’ (1990) 5(3) Journal of International Banking Law 7676. For a full commentary on the findings of the Parliamentary Ombudsman, see Parliamentary Commissioner for Administration, Second Report of the PCA: the Barlow Clowes Affair, HC 76 (London, 1989/1990).
105For a more detailed discussion of the potential liability of the DTI, see S. Vaughan, and P. May, ‘The Barlow Clowes affair’ (1988) 7(3) International Banking Law 34, 36–7.
106Younghusband, above n. 104, at 76.
107Prevention of Fraud (Investments) Act 1958, s.1.
108Younghusband, above n. 104, at 76.

419 3â New Labour and a new policy
December 1989, the then Conservative government, without admitting liability, announced that it was prepared to make significant payments to those people who had lost money after investing in the two companies.109
(iv)â BCCI
One of the most infamous banking collapses in the United Kingdom was Bank of Credit and Commerce International (BCCI) in 1991. The bank was established in Pakistan, incorporated in Luxembourg in 1972 and in 1976 it opened its first office in the United Kingdom.110 BCCI applied to the Bank of England to be legally recognised as a bank under the Banking Act 1979. The Bank of England refused to do so, but nonetheless granted it a licence as a deposit-taking institution under the Banking Act 1979.111 The Bank of England mistakenly relied on regulation provided by the Luxembourg regulatory authorities and decided not formally to regulate BCCI itself.112 Arora pointed out that during this period further memoranda passed between the officials of the bank, drawing attention to the fact that the real place of business of BCCI SA was London and that the Bank of England should be its primary supervisor.113
The first concerns regarding the operations of BCCI were raised by an international group called ‘the College’. According to Arora ‘this group expressed concerns about a large concentration of exposures due to the group’s lending and the effect on the group’s activities of the arrest of seven of its officials in Tampa, Florida, in October 1988, on charges of drug trafficking, conspiracy and money laundering’.114 The Bank of England was informed by Price Waterhouse Coopers (PWC) that the auditors were unable to sign BCCI’s 1989 accounts due to financial irregularities.115 Towards the end of 1990, PWC became aware of the fraudulent activities of BCCI’s directors and were asked by the Bank of England to investigate the allegations.116 Some seven months later, the Bank of England sought to close down
BCCI,117 and in 1991 the bank collapsed, leaving a vast amount of debt under a shadow of allegations of fraud. Hemraj noted that ‘BCCI was deliberately rigged to avoid effective regulation. Generally speaking, despite being an
109For a more detailed commentary on the government’s response to the findings of the Parliamentary Ombudsman, see G. Drewry, and R. Gregory, ‘Barlow Clowes and the Ombudsman: Part 2’ (1991) Public Law (Autumn) 408, 415.
110A. Arora, ‘The statutory system of bank supervision and the failure of BCCI’ (2006) Journal of Business Law (August) 487, 490.
111Ibid. 490.
112This was permitted under the Banking Act 1979, s.3(5). This was amended by the Banking Act 1987, s.9(3), which however, continued to allow the Bank of England to rely upon the regulators in Luxembourg.
113 Arora, above n. 110, at 490–1.â 114â Ibid.â 115â Ibid. 490–2.
116Price Waterhouse Coopers were asked to investigate the activities of BCCI under the Banking Act 1987, s.41.
117Arora, above n. 110, at 492.
420 |
|
Government policy |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
international financial centre, Britain has failed to create an effective regu- |
|
|
|
latory structure.’118 Arora added that ‘the failure of BCCI was clearly a fail- |
|
|
ure of both domestic and international banking regulation. Rarely was BCCI |
||
|
hindered by regulators or law enforcement officials: even after the bank was |
||
|
shut down, response from bank regulators was sluggish’.119 Indeed, in his |
||
|
|
report on the collapse of BCCI, Lord Bingham concluded that ‘on more than |
|
|
|
one occasion the Bank’s supervision was not up to scratch’.120 The collapse of |
|
|
BCCI ‘in July 1991 sent shockwaves around the banking world and left thou- |
||
|
sands of depositors out of pocket with little prospect of seeing their money |
||
|
again’.121 |
||
|
|
|
In 1993, over 6,000 claimants sued the Bank of England. According to Grey, |
|
|
‘the liquidators’ claim related to the Bank of England’s discharge of supervis- |
|
|
|
ory and regulatory responsibilities over the United Kingdom operations of the |
|
|
|
BCCI banking group over a period which spanned 1980 through to 1991 when |
|
|
|
action was taken by the Bank of England’.122 The claimants alleged that the Bank |
|
|
|
of England had committed the tort of misfeasance and were liable for negli- |
|
|
|
gence in a public office.123 Zuckerman noted that when the case ended in 2005, |
|
|
|
‘the claimants abandoned their action on day 256 of the trial. In the intervening |
|
|
|
12 years a great deal of litigation took place requiring numerous court hear- |
|
|
|
ings occupying an extraordinary amount of judicial time in the High Court, |
|
|
|
Court of Appeal and House of Lords (involving at least 63 days of hearings) |
|
|
|
and costing the defendants some £80 million.’124 The case was lengthy and the |
|
|
|
costs of both parties spiralled. It has been estimated that Deloitte spent approxi- |
|
|
|
mately £38 million, while the Bank of England spent around £170 million on |
|
|
|
the case.125 The collapse of BCCI influenced the decision by the government to |
|
|
create a new financial services regulatory regime and tarnished the regulatory |
||
|
reputation of the Bank of England. |
||
|
118 |
M. Hemraj, ‘The regulatory failure: the saga of BCCI’ (2005) 8(4) Journal of Money Laundering |
|
|
|
|
Control 346, 350. |
|
119 |
Arora, above n. 110, at 509. |
|
|
120 |
K. McGuire, ‘Banking supervision after the Bingham Report on BCCI: the end of an era?’ |
|
|
|
|
(1993) 4(3) Journal of International Company and Commercial Law 118. For a commentary |
|
|
|
on the response of the Bank of England to the collapse of BCCI, see M. Stallworthy, ‘BCCI: |
|
|
|
Bank of England response’ (1992) 11(4) Journal of International Banking and Financial |
|
|
|
LawÂ44. |
|
121 |
Ibid. |
|
|
122 |
J. Grey, ‘Lessons from BCCI saga for the current accountability debate surrounding Northern |
|
|
|
|
Rock?’ (2008) 23(2) Journal of International Banking Law and Regulation 37, 38. |
|
123 |
See M. Andenas, ‘Liability for supervisors and depositor’s rights: the BCCI and the Bank of |
|
|
|
|
England in the House of Lords’ (2001) 22(8) The Company Lawyer 226. |
|
124 |
M. Zuckerman, ‘A colossal wreck– the BCCI– Three Rivers litigation’ (2006) 25 Civil Justice |
|
|
|
|
Quarterly (July) 287. |
|
125 |
Editorial, ‘BCCI liquidators drop Bank of England claim’ (2006) 27(3) Company Lawyer 91. For |
|
|
|
|
a more detailed commentary regarding the potential liability of the FSA, see E. Cavalli, and T. |
|
|
|
Blyth, ‘The liability of the Financial Services Authority after Three Rivers’ (2001) 3(5) Journal of |
|
|
|
International Financial Markets 199. |
421 |
3â New Labour and a new policy |
|
|
(v)â Barings Bank
The collapse of Barings Bank in 1995, one of the United Kingdom’s oldest banks,126 with approximately £927 million in losses, is associated with the illegal actions of Nicholas Leeson, otherwise known as the ‘rogue trader’. Nicholas Leeson opened the famous ‘88888’ account to offset losses and unauthorised transactions he made whilst undertaking unlicensed trading on the Singapore, Osaka and Tokyo Stock Exchanges between 1992 and 1995.127 Kane and DeTrask took the view that proprietary trading by Nicholas Leeson destroyed Barings Bank.128 Kornert stated that ‘the Barings crisis of 1995 is regarded as one of the most spectacular international events in the banking world in recent years’.129 According to Dale, ‘[a]t the end of February 1995 Barings, an old-established United Kingdom merchant banking group with total assets of around £6 billion and deposits of some £3 billion, faced collapse, having incurred massive losses on unauthorised derivatives transactions undertaken through its Singapore trading unit’.130 The outcome for Barings can be contrasted with the collapse of Johnson Matthey Bank because the Bank of England refused to bail out the bank. Following its collapse it was sold to the Dutch bank ING in 1995 for a symbolic £1.
Barings Bank was regulated by the Bank of England under the Banking Act 1987 and although it was not directly responsible for regulating the overseas subsidiaries of Barings, the Bank of England had to rely upon the reputation and the financial stability of the parent company.131 The Bank of England can be criticised because it ‘knew about Barings’ extraordinary profitable activities in Asia, [but] it accepted the bank’s explanation of volatile arbitrage trading between the Asian Exchanges’.132 Dale argued that ‘there could be no doubt that the collapse of Barings, with ensuing losses to depositors, would inflict considerable damage both on London’s reputation as a banking centre and onÂthe credit standing – and therefore competitiveness – of UK merchant banks’.133 TheÂcollapse of Barings Bank clearly demonstrated fundamental weaknesses in the regulatory approach of the Bank of England.
(vi)â Equitable Life
The near collapse of Equitable Life straddles the regulation of the Bank of England and the FSA. The firm misled its policy-holders over a ten-year period
126J. Kornert, ‘The Barings crisis of 1890 and 1995: causes, courses, consequences and the danger of domino effects’ (2003) 13(3) International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money 187, 189.
127Ibid. 197.
128E. Kane, and K. DeTrask, ‘Breakdown of accounting controls at Barings and Daiwa: benefits of using opportunity-cost measures for trading activity’ (1999) 7(3–4) Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 203, 206.
129See Kornert, above n. 126, at 196.â 130â See Dale, above n. 90, at 330–1.
131See Kornert, above n. 126, at 204.
132Ibid. 204. For a more detailed discussion of the regulatory failure behind the collapse of Barings Bank, see L. Proctor, ‘The Barings collapse: a regulatory failure, or a failure of supervision’ (1997) 22 Brooklyn Journal of International Law 735.
133See Dale, above n. 90, at 330–1.