
- •Isbn 0-19-926063-X (hbk.) isbn 0-19-926064-8 (pbk.)
- •1.1 Introduction
- •1.2 What is a corporation?
- •15 See Hansmann and Kraakman, supra note 2.
- •1.2.2 Limited liability
- •1.2.3 Transferable shares
- •1.2.4 Delegated management with a board structure
- •24 Sec Eugene Fama and Michael Jensen, Agency Problems and Restdual Claims, 26 journal of law and economics 327 (1983).
- •1.2.5 Investor ownership
- •1.3.2 Additional sources of corporate law
- •2.2.1.2 Setting the terms of entry and exit
- •13 The withdrawal right is a dominant governance device for the regulation of some non-corporate
- •2.2.2.2 Initiation and ratification
- •2.2.2.3 Trusteeship and reward
- •16 See infra 3.1.2.1.
- •2.2.3 Ex post and ex ante strategies
- •3.1.1.3 The decision-making structure of the board
- •3.1.2.2 The trusteeship strategy
- •3.1.2.3 The reward strategy
- •3.1.2.5 The affiliation rights strategy
- •3.1.2.6 Reflecting on the shareholder—manager conflict
- •3.2.1 The appointment rights strategy
- •10* See also mfra 4.1.2 (discussing corporate groups).
- •3.2.4 The reward, constraints, and affiliation rights strategies
- •3.3.1 The appointment rights strategy
- •14Fi Pistor, supra note 126, 190 (Germany); Bratton and McCahery, supra note 12, §3.2 (the Netherlands).
- •4.1.2 Corporate groups
- •4.1.3 Involuntary creditors
- •4.2.2 Rules governing legal capital and corporate groups
- •4.2.3 Fiduciary duties—The standards strategy
- •4.2.3.2 Auditor liability
- •4.2.3.4 Liability of third parties
- •4.2.3.5 Reflecting upon the standards strategy
- •4.3.2 The importance of divergence
- •5.1.2 Disinterested board approval: The trusteeship strategy
- •5.1.2.3 Costs and benefits of board approval
- •5.2 Transactions involving controlling shareholders
- •5.2.1 Mandatory disclosure: The affiliation strategy
- •5.2.2 Board and shareholder ratification: The trusteeship and decision rights strategies
- •5.3 Explaining differences in the regulation of related party transactions
- •6.1 What are significant corporate actions?
- •1 See supra 3.1.2,1. 2 See supra 5.1.2 and s.2.2.
- •6.2.1 The management-shareholder conflict
- •§122 Aktiengesetz (5% of ag capital or par value of €500,000, Germany); 5376 Companies Act (5%
- •6.2.2.2 Controlled organic changes (including freezeout mergers)
- •7.1.2.3 Agency problems of non-shareholders
- •7.3.1 Information asymmetry: The affiliation strategy
- •7.3.3 The mandatory bid rule: The exit strategy90
- •7.3.4 Competing bids
- •7.5 Agency problems of non-shareholder groups
- •8.1 Two objectives of investor protection
- •8.2 The entry strategy: mandatory disclosure
- •8.2.1.1 The threshold(s) for disclosure
- •8.2.2 Accounting methodology
- •8.2.4.1 The underproduction of information
- •8.3 Quality control: the trusteeship strategy
- •8.4.2 The standards strategy
- •8.5 Explaining differences in investor protection
- •9.2 Putting our results into context
- •Incentive strategy 26-7
1.3.2 Additional sources of corporate law
There are bodies of law that, at least in some jurisdictions, are incorporated in statutes or decisional law that are separate from basic corporate law, and from the alternative forms just described, but that are nonetheless exclusively concerned with particular core characteristics of the corporate form as we define them here.
To begin, the well-known German law of groups, or Konzernrecht, qualifies limited liability and limits the discretion of boards of directors in corporations that are closely related through cross ownership, seeking to protect the creditors and minority shareholders of corporations with controlling shareholders. Where subsidiaries are organized under the open corporation statute (Aktiengesetz), the rights of controlled companies are deh'mited by this statute itself, which provides for the regulation of both contractually formalized group relationships and de facto control relationships among corporations. Where subsidiaries are organized under the close corporation statute (GmbH-Gesetz), the parallel law of corporate groups is judge-made rather than statutory. Either way, however, Konzernrecht is clearly an integral part of German corporate law. (We describe the German Konzernrecht in greater detail in Chapter 4.)
Similarly, the statutory rules in many jurisdictions that require employee representation on a corporation's board of directors—such as, conspicuously, the German or Dutch law of codetermination—qualify as elements of corporate law even though they occasionally originate outside the principal corporate law statutes, because they impose a detailed structure of employee participation on the boards of directors of large corporations. American securities law, which applies to large corporations, importantly structures board representation by establishing elaborate election procedures, regulating transferability of shares in various contexts, and imposing detailed disclosure rules. Stock exchange rules, which can regulate numerous aspects of the internal affairs of exchange-listed firms, can also serve as an additional source of corporate law, as can other forms of self-regulation, such as the UK's City Code rules on takeovers and mergers.30
These supplemental bodies of law are necessarily part of the overall structure of corporate law, and we shall be concerned here with all of them.
30 We term such self-regulation a source of 'law' in part because it is commonly supported, directly or indirectly, by law in the narrow sense. The self-regulatory authority of the American stock exchanges, for example, is both reinforced and constrained by the U.S. Securities Exchange Act and the administrative rules promulgated by the Securities and Exchange Commission under that Act.
1.3.3 Non-corporate law constraints
There are, of course, many constraints imposed on companies by bodies of law designed to serve objectives that are largely unrelated to the core characteristics of the corporate form, and therefore do not fall within the scope of corporate law as we define it here.
Bankruptcy law, or 'insolvency law,' as it is termed in the UK, is an example. As we have noted, a major contribution of the corporation as a legal form is the ability to partition assets for purposes of pledging them as security to different groups of creditors. Bankruptcy law plays an important role in enforcing the claims that derive from this partitioning. Nevertheless, the problems of bankruptcy presented by corporations are often shared by other types of legal entities, and the elements of bankruptcy law that address those problems are not, in many jurisdictions, confined to entities formed as business corporations.31 Consequently, we do not treat most aspects of bankruptcy law here as part of corporate law.
Similarly, although the types of firms that typically organize as corporations present particular problems for tort liability—especially when it comes to the liability of the corporation for the acts of corporate employees—these and other problems addressed by tort law are often presented by other types of entities, and we do not address them here directly. Much the same is true, moreover, for the types of issues traditionally considered within the realm of contract law, criminal law, and labor law. While, in each of those areas, firms organized as corporations present, to some degree, particular problems, those problems are not so distinctively connected to the core features of a corporation as to lead us to address them here as part of what we consider basic corporate law.
There are, however, some exceptions. For example, the UK doctrine of 'wrongful trading' in insolvency, while formally an aspect of bankruptcy law, focuses specifically on the duties of corporate directors. The problems of labor contracting presented by large firms are, in some jurisdictions, addressed by specific regulation of the basic elements of the corporate form as we have described them here, such as the composition of the firm's board of directors. The extension of limited liability beyond contract to tort, which has come to be considered a basic feature of the corporate form nearly everywhere, is another exception. In cases such as these, there is a blurring of the boundaries between corporate law and other fields of law—bankruptcy, labor, or tort law—that must be addressed here.
1.4 WHAT IS THE GOAL OF CORPORATE LAW?
What is the goal of corporate law, as distinct from its immediate functions of defining a form of enterprise and containing the conflicts among the participants
31 For example, the reorganization provisions under Chapter 11 of the U.S. Bankruptcy Code, while most commonly invoked by companies, are not confined to such entities, but apply as well to partnerships and even individuals.
in this enterprise? As a normative matter, the overall objective of corporate law—as of any branch of law—is presumably to serve the interests of society as a whole. More particularly, the appropriate goal of corporate law is to advance the aggregate welfare32 of a firm's shareholders, employees, suppliers, and customers without undue sacrifice—and, if possible, with benefit—to third parties such as local communities and beneficiaries of the natural environment. This is what economists would characterize as the pursuit of overall social efficiency.
It is sometimes said that the goals of corporate law should be narrower. In particular, it is sometimes said that the appropriate role of corporate law is simply to assure that the corporation serves the best interests of its shareholders or, more specifically, to maximize financial returns to shareholders or, more specifically still, to maximize the market price of corporate shares. Such claims can be viewed in two ways.
First, these claims can be taken at face value, in which case they neither describe corporate law as we see it, nor do they offer a normatively appealing aspiration for that body of law. There would be little to recommend a body of law that, for example, permits corporate shareholders to enrich themselves through transactions that make creditors or employees worse off by $2 for every $1 that the shareholders gain.
Second, such claims can be understood as saying, more modestly, that focusing principally on the maximization of shareholder returns is, in general, the best means by which corporate law can serve the broader goal of advancing overall social welfare. In general, creditors, workers, and customers will consent to deal with a corporation only if they expect to be better off themselves as a result. Consequently, the corporation—and, in particular, its shareholders—has a direct pecuniary interest in making sure that corporate transactions are beneficial, not just to the shareholders, but to all parties who deal with the firm. We believe that this second view is—and surely ought to be—the appropriate interpretation of statements by legal scholars and economists asserting that shareholder value is the proper object of corporate law.
Whether, in fact, the pursuit of shareholder value is generally an effective means of advancing social welfare is an empirical question on which reasonable minds can differ. While each of the authors of this book have individual views on this claim, we do not take a strong position on it in the Chapters that follow. Rather, we undertake the broader task of offering an analytic framework within which this question can be explored and debated.
32 When we speak here of advancing or maximizing the 'aggregate welfare' of society we are using a metaphor that is conceptually a bit loose. There is no coherent way to put a number on society's aggregate welfare, much less to maximize that number—and particularly so when many benefits are in appreciable part non-pecuniary. What we are suggesting here might be put more precisely in the language of welfare economics as pursuing Kaldor-Hicks efficiency within acceptable patterns of distribution.
To say that the pursuit of aggregate social welfare is the appropriate goal of corporate law is not to say, of course, that the law always serves that goal. Legislatures and courts are sometimes less attentive to overall social welfare than to the particular interests of some influential constituency, such as corporate managers, controlling shareholders, or organized workers. Moreover, corporate law everywhere continues to bear the imprint of the historical path through which it has evolved, and reflects as well various non-efficiency-oriented intellectual and ideological currents that have sometimes influenced its formation. The corporate law of all jurisdictions clearly shows, to a greater or lesser degree, the weight of these various influences.
2
Agency Problems and Legal Strategies
HENRY HANSMANN and REINIER KRAAKMAN
2.1 THREE AGENCY PROBLEMS
As we explained in the preceding Chapter,1 corporate law performs two general functions: first, it establishes the structure of the corporate form as well as ancillary housekeeping rules necessary to support this structure; and, second, it attempts to control conflicts of interest among corporate constituencies, including those between corporate 'insiders,' such as controlling shareholders and top managers, and 'outsiders,' such as minority shareholders or creditors. These conflicts all have the character of what economists refer to as 'agency problems' or 'principal-agent' problems. For readers unfamiliar with the jargon of economists, an 'agency problem'—in the most general sense of the term—arises whenever the welfare of one party, termed the 'principal,' depends upon actions taken by another party, termed the 'agent.5 The problem lies in motivating the agent to act in the principal's interest rather than simply in the agent's own interest. Viewed in these broad terms, agency problems arise in a broad range of contexts that go well beyond those that would formally be classified as agency relationships by lawyers.
In particular, almost any contractual relationship, in which one party (the 'agent') promises performance to another (the 'principal'), is potentially subject to an agency problem. The core of the difficulty is that, because the agent commonly has better information than does the principal about the relevant facts, the principal cannot costlessly assure himself that the agent's performance is precisely what was promised. As a consequence, the agent has an incentive to act opportunistically,2 skimping on the quality of his performance, or even diverting to himself some of what was promised to the principal. This means, in turn, that the value of the agent's performance to the principal will be reduced, either directly or because, to assure the quality of the agent's performance, the principal must engage in costly monitoring of the agent. The greater the
1 Supra 1.1.
2 We use the term 'opportunism' here, following the usage of Oliver Williamson, to refer to self-interested behavior that involves some element of deception, misrepresentation, or bad faith. See Oliver Williamson, THE ECONOMIC iNsnTunoNS OF CAPITALISM 47-49 (1985).
complexity of the tasks undertaken by the agent, and the greater the discretion the agent must be given, the larger these 'agency costs' are likely to be.3
As we noted in Chapter 1, three generic agency problems arise in business firms. The first involves the conflict between the firm's owners and its hired managers. Here the owners are the principals and the managers are the agents. The problem lies in assuring that the managers are responsive to the owner's interests rather than simply to the managers' own personal interests. The second agency problem involves the conflict between, on the one hand, owners who possess the majority or controlling interest in the firm and, on the other hand, the minority or noncontrolling owners. Here the noncontrolling owners are the principals and the controlling owners are the agents, and the difficulty lies in assuring that the former are not expropriated by the latter. The third agency problem involves the conflict between the firm itself (including, particularly, its owners) and the other parties with whom the firm contracts, such as creditors, employees, and customers. Here the difficulty lies in assuring that the firm, as agent, does not behave opportunistically toward these various other principals— such as by expropriating creditors, exploiting workers, or misleading consumers.
Law can play an important role in reducing agency costs. Obvious examples are rules and procedures that enhance disclosure by agents or facilitate enforcement actions brought by principals against dishonest or negligent agents. Paradoxically, in protecting principals against exploitation by their agents, the law can benefit agents as much as—or even more than—it benefits the principals. The reason is that a principal will be willing to offer greater compensation to an agent when the principal is assured of performance that is honest and of high quality. To take a conspicuous example in the corporate context, rules of law that protect creditors from opportunistic behavior on the part of corporations should reduce the interest rate that corporations must pay for credit, thus benefiting corporations as well as creditors. Likewise, legal constraints on the ability of controlling shareholders to expropriate minority shareholders should reduce the cost of outside equity capital for corporations. And rules of law that inhibit insider trading by corporate managers should increase the compensation that shareholders are willing to offer the managers. In general, reducing agency costs is in the interests of all parties to a transaction, principals and agents alike.
It follows that the normative goal of advancing aggregate social welfare, as discussed in Chapter l,4 is generally equivalent to searching for optimal solutions to the corporation's agency problems, in the sense of finding solutions that maximize the aggregate welfare of the parties involved—that is, of both principals and agents taken together.
1 See, e.g., Steven Ross, The Economic Theory of Agency: The Principal's Problem, 63 AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW 134 (1973); John W. Pratt and Richard J. Zeckhauser (eds.), PRINCIPALS AND AGENTS: THE STRUCTURE OP BUSINESS (1984); Paul Milgrom and John Roberts, ECONOMICS, ORGANIZATION AND MANAGEMENT (1992).
4 Supra 1.4.
Agency Problems and Legal Strategies 23 2.2 LEGAL STRATEGIES FOR REDUCING AGENCY COSTS
In addressing agency problems, the law turns repeatedly to a basic set of legal strategies. By 'legal strategy,' we mean a generic method of deploying substantive law to mitigate the vulnerability of principals to the opportunism of their agents. These strategies can be divided into two subsets, which we term, respectively, 'regulatory strategies' and 'governance strategies.' Regulatory strategies are prescriptive; they dictate substantive terms that govern either the content of the agent-principal relationship, or the formation or dissolution of that relationship. By contrast, governance strategies build on the elements of hierarchy and dependency that commonly characterize agency relationships; they attempt to protect principals indirectly, either by enhancing their power or by molding the incentives of their agents.
Table 2-1 sets out ten strategies—four regulatory strategies and six governance strategies—that, taken together, span the law's principal methods of dealing with agency problems. These strategies are not limited to the corporate context. They can be deployed to protect nearly any vulnerable principal-agent relationship. Our focus here, however, will naturally be on the ways that these strategies are deployed in corporate law.
2.2.1 Regulatory strategies
Consider first the regulatory strategies on the left hand side of Table 2-1. 2.2.1.1 Rules and standards
The most familiar pair of regulatory strategies constrains agents by commanding them not to make decisions, or undertake transactions, that would harm the interests of their principals. Lawmakers can frame such constraints as rules, which require or prohibit specific behaviors, or as general standards, which leave the precise determination of compliance to adjudicators after the fact.
Both rules and standards attempt to regulate the substance of agency relationships directly. Rules, which prescribe behaviors ex ante,5 are commonly used in
the corporate context to protect a corporation's creditors and public investors. Thus corporation statutes universally include creditor protection rules such as dividend restrictions, minimum capitalization requirements, or capital maintenance requirements.6 Similarly, capital market authorities frequently promulgate detailed rules to govern tender offers and proxy voting.7
By contrast, few jurisdictions rely on the rules strategy as a principal device for regulating complex, intra-corporate relations, such as, for example, self-dealing transactions initiated by controlling shareholders. Such matters are, presumably, too complex to regulate with a matrix of prohibitions and exemptions, which threaten to codify loopholes and create pointless rigidities. Rather than rule-based regulation, then, intra-corporate topics such as insider self-dealing tend to be governed by open standards that leave discretion for adjudicators to determine ex post whether violations have occurred.8 Standards are also used to protect creditors and public investors, but the paradigmatic examples of standards-based regulation relate to the company's internal affairs, as when the law requires directors to act in 'good faith' or mandates that self-dealing transactions must be 'entirely fair.'9
The importance of both rules and standards depends in large measure on the vigor with which they are enforced. In principle, well-drafted rules can be mechanically enforced. Standards, however, inevitably require courts (or other adjudicators) to become deeply involved in evaluating and sometimes molding corporate decisions ex post. In this sense, standards lie between rules (which simply require a decision maker to determine compliance) and another strategy that we will address below—the trusteeship strategy, which requires a neutral decision maker to exercise his or her own unconstrained best judgment in making a corporate decision.10