Добавил:
Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:
Учебный год 22-23 / Finch - Corporate Insolvency Law - Perspectives and Principles.pdf
Скачиваний:
7
Добавлен:
14.12.2022
Размер:
7.09 Mб
Скачать

administration

439

the PIP system is that greater or lesser roles can be given to directors according to assessments of their powers of judgement and expertise that are carried out by an independent generalist familiar with insolvency situations.

Fairness and accountability

If expert judgements concerning responses to corporate distress are to merit approval, they have to be made fairly and accountably. Here the post-EA regime might be expected to score high marks as it places an independent ofcer of the court in control.343 It also sets up open procedures that are designed to allow reasonable input to creditors344 and which hold administrators to account through creditorsmeetings345 as well as through the imposition of a series of legal duties.346 Such creditorsmeetings allow unsecured creditors to hold administrators to account in a way that was not possible in administrative receivership. It should be noted, however, that accountability to the creditorsmeeting is avoided where the administrator acts without reference to such a meeting in accordance with the terms of Schedule B1, paragraph 52(1)347 or acts in advance of such a meeting subject to any court directions given under paragraph 68(2) of Schedule B1. In the former instances (which would occur when the administrator thinks, for example, that there are insufcient funds for a distribution to unsecured creditors) there would be no requirement of court approval and aggrieved creditors would only be able to hold that administrator to account by commencing proceedings in court.348 Some practitioners have, as noted, voiced particular

343The administrator, as noted, is an ofcer of the court and thus subject to the ethical requirements of the rule in Ex parte James (1874) 9 Ch App 609: see D. Milman, The Administration Order Procedure(2002) 17 Company Law Newsletter 1, 3.

344See Hahn, Concentrated Ownership.

345See Insolvency Act 1986 Sch. B1, paras. 517.

346See J. Armour and R. Mokal, Reforming the Governance of Corporate Rescue: The Enterprise Act 2002[2005] LMCLQ 28. On accountability in the new administration process see further Brupbacher, Functional Analysis, pp. 12638.

347Under which, as noted, an administrator is not obliged to call a creditorsmeeting if he thinks that creditors can be paid in full; there is insufcient property for a distribution to unsecured creditors; or that it will not be possible to rescue the company as a going concern or achieve a better result for the companys creditors as a whole than would be likely if the company were wound up.

348Sch. B1, para. 74 governs challenges to the administrators conduct of the company by creditors or members. Para. 75 allows misfeasance actions against administrators by, inter alia, a creditor and the company does not have to be in liquidation for such an action to be commenced.

440

the quest for turnaround

worries about the process in which a company can be put into administration out of court and then be converted into a creditorsvoluntary liquidation.349 As one expressed the concern: Companies are put into administration for no other reason than to take advantage of the opportunity to put them into liquidation later without holding a creditorsmeeting.350 In such scenarios another worry is that only a liquidator has a complete set of powers for dealing with wrongful and fraudulent trading and that use of the administration route may inhibit investigation of directorial actions because the directors may appoint an administrator out of court to realise and distribute assets and exit administration all without the need to hold a meeting of creditors.351

In the modern distressed debt market, moreover, it can be argued that there are numbers of actors who are not so much interested in rescue as a fast return. As John Verrill, former president of R3, has stated:

The modus operandi of the new-style entrants into the distressed debt market is that they fund the administrator and provide the stock. Normally under the old regime the administrator would have to show the court that he had the nancial backing or funding to achieve the purpose for which he was seeking the order Now if a oating charge holder wants to appoint an administrator, he can do so without the old checks and balances and no independent verication by the court. A company can now buy the debenture off a creditor who would otherwise

be whistling for the money and then say to the administrator: Do you want the job or not?352

A system of practitioner in possession, as found in administration, could, however, be supported as avoiding the danger of unfairness or bias that comes from shareholder manipulation and which has been said to be

349A mechanism for converting new-style administration to a CVL is found in Sch. B1, para. 83. Alternatively, in less complex cases, the IP may wish to take advantage of the ability to pay all creditors whilst the company is in newadministration rather than moving to liquidation: see further Todd, Administration Post-Enterprise Act. See pp. 3967 above.

350Nick Hood of Begbies Traynor, quoted in Accountancy Age, 18 December 2003, p. 11. See also Linklater, New Style Administration. See pp. 3967 above.

351At which meeting creditors would have had the opportunity to question the directors on the companys demise. Administrators are entitled, however, to institute proceedings to have transactions at undervalue and preferences adjusted: IA 1986 ss. 2389. The administrationliquidation route could, moreover, reduce costs and time and allow directors to have more input during the process: see further Keay, What Future for Liquidation?, pp. 1525.

352Quoted in J. Robins, The Enterprise Act Has Failed to Earn Respect(2005) Finance Week (25 May).

administration

441

associated with DIP regimes the risk that, where ownership is concentrated, shareholders will tend to encourage the management to engage in risky projects during troubled times since they are gambling with creditorsmoney.353 Here there is a trade-off to be considered. A DIP regime might be expected to place rescue in the hands of directors who are the parties with best knowledge of the business and its prospects but it brings dangers of shareholder manipulation. A PIP system would be expected to involve lower levels of business-specic knowledge but greater resistance to such shareholder pressure.

In deciding whether DIP or PIP brings the preferable trade-off a number of considerations may be relevant. A rst is the severity of the risks of bias through potential shareholder manipulation. On this point Hahn argues that concentration of ownership conduces to such manipulation but that, in the UK, the shareholding of listed corporations tends to be widely dispersed.354 If risks of manipulation tend to be low, this militates, according to Hahn, in favour of DIP rather than PIP as the fairer regime. Such an analysis, however, focuses on the relationship between manager-directors and shareholders and may understate the dangers of manipulation by other interests. In the case of many troubled UK companies there will be a degree of creditor concentration and creditor power (as where the company is in debt to a bank that holds a oating charge). This, as already indicated, may lead the bank to press those in charge of the company to develop and apply strategies that principally protect bank interests. On this count, it is arguable that, although administrator-IPs may not be immune to such pressures (a point made above), they are likely to be more resistant than the companys directors, who will not only be predisposed to keeping their major creditors happy,355 but may well be conditioned by their troubled experiences to give way to bank pressure.

Even within PIP, however, it should be emphasised that the importance of eleventh-hour funding in rescue operations may enhance the banksalready strong positions to manipulate. In times of corporate distress it is common for the banks to supply rescue funds under terms

353Ibid.; Scott, Relational Theory, p. 909.

354Hahn, Concentrated Ownership, p. 134. It should be emphasised, of course, that Hahns argument relates to listed corporations. Private companies would not offer the same dispersion of shareholding and, accordingly, risks of shareholder manipulation would be higher, and the attractions of DIP lower.

355Directorstendency to align their decision-making to the banks interests is likely to be the greater if the directors have also given the bank personal guarantees.

442

the quest for turnaround

that give them very considerable powers to inuence strategy.356 Covenants in restructured lending agreements will frequently impose restrictions on such matters as: operating activities (e.g. maximum outlays on administration); new investments (e.g. on levels and kinds of investment); dispositions of assets; payouts to shareholders; and nancial activities (e.g. levels of borrowing; levels of working capital).357 When banks supply new rescue funds they may increase their equity share in the corporation and accordingly may exercise considerable power as shareholders as well as creditors. They may also negotiate representation on the board which allows them, for example, to put turnaround specialists in place and gives de facto, if not formal, inuence over the strategy formulation process.358 The effect of such bank power is that, within the post-EA regime, the administrator is supposed to advert to the interests of creditors as a whole (a contrast with receivership) but, in doing so, will have to co-ordinate closely with the bank. There are dangers of both friction and manipulation (and hence of unfairness to some creditors) in such arrangements.

Turning to accountability through judicial oversight, this can be assessed by considering the courtsrole in shaping the administration regime. That shaping may involve the judges in inuencing interactions between a variety of different actors by, for example, adjusting incentives to resort to law and detailing areas of expertise within which certain actorsjudgements will be deferred to. In order to explore the potential judicial role it is necessary, rst, to outline the main ways in which the EA 2002 reforms allow the judges to impact on the new administration process and, second, to indicate how the judiciary might make best use of their potential impact in accordance with a co-ordination perspective that focuses on key rescue tasks.

The EA revises the involvement of the judiciary in the process of administration in a number of ways.359 In some respects, judicial supervision is weakened as over the appointment process, where Schedule

356See e.g. J. Day and P. Taylor, Financial Distress in Small Firms: The Role Played by Debt Covenants and Other Monitoring Devices[2001] Ins. Law. 97.

357See e.g. Gilson, Bankruptcy, Boards, Banks and Blockholders, p. 367.

358Ibid., pp. 3805. See also D. Baird and R. Rasmussen, The End of Bankruptcy(2003) 55 Stanford L Rev. 751, 7845. On the role of turnaround specialists in insolvency see V. Finch, Doctoring in the Shadows of Insolvency[2005] JBL 690 and ch. 5 above.

359On the role of the judiciary in relation to the newadministration see also Armour and Mokal, Reforming the Governance of Corporate Rescue; Finch, Re-invigorating Rescueand Control and Co-ordination in Corporate Rescue.

administration

443

B1, paragraphs 14 and 22 involve a dramatic shift to out-of-court activity. Holders of qualifying oating charges as well as the company and its directors are able to appoint an administrator without going to court by ling a notice of appointment accompanied by a statement from the identied administrator that he consents to the appointment and that, in his opinion, the purpose of the administration is reasonably likely to be achieved.360 The route to appointment of an administrator via court order is retained by paragraph 10 of Schedule B1 which requires an administration application to court by either the company, its directors or one or more creditors.361

On some issues, however, the courts are given new areas of judgement by the EA. Paragraph 13(1)(e) of Schedule B1 now empowers the court to treat an application for administration as a winding-up petition, carrying associated winding-up powers. The court is thus given a wide discretion to make the order it thinks most appropriate and it is likely to treat the application as a winding-up petition if the company is revealed to be hopelessly insolvent and the interests of creditors as a whole require an immediate investigation of its affairs by a liquidator and if this consideration outweighs any likely advantage to be achieved by realisation of assets in administration.362

Another area in which there is at least the potential for considerable judicial input is in reviewing the exercise of the administrators powers as deployed in pursuit of the Schedule B1 paragraph 3 objectives. As noted above, a central issue here is whether the administrator should act to rescue the company as a going concern (paragraph 3(1)(a)); to achieve a better result than on winding up for creditors as a whole (paragraph 3(1)(b)); or to realise property in order to make a distribution to one or more secured or preferential creditors (paragraph 3(1)(c)). Selecting between these objectives is governed by paragraph 3(3), which is phrased in subjective terms and, to repeat, states that the administrator must act to rescue the company as a going concern unless he thinks either that this

360The company or its directors will also need to declare that the company is or is likely to become unable to pay its debts as a precondition to the appointment of an administrator. This contrasts with the holder of the qualifying oating charge who is not required to demonstrate this inability or likely inability: see pp. 3812 above. On inability to pay debts and denitions of insolvency see ch. 4 above.

361The company has to be or be likely to become unable to pay its debts and the court must be satised that the administration order is reasonably likely to achieve the purpose of administration: Sch. B1, para. 11(b).

362The court may also make an interim order to restrict the exercise of directorial powers or to make these subject to supervision by an IP or the court (paras. 13(3)(a) and (b)).

444

the quest for turnaround

course is not reasonably practicable or that a better result for creditors as a whole can be achieved by pursuing the second of the listed objectives.363 Paragraph 3(2) overlays a general duty on the administrator to perform his functions in the interests of the companys creditors as a whole.364 The administrator, moreover, is subject to a duty, under paragraph 4, to perform his functions as quickly and efciently as is reasonably practicable. Under paragraph 74(1) a creditor or member can challenge the administrator by claiming that he is acting or has acted or proposes to act so as to harm their interests unfairly. Paragraph 74(2) allows the same parties to mount a challenge on the grounds that the administrator is not performing his functions as quickly or as efciently as is reasonably practicable.365

Do these provisions offer the judges an opportunity to render administrators accountable through the exercise of energetic supervision? It would appear that the subjective phrasing of paragraph 3(3) (which was inserted late in the passage of the Enterprise Bill through Parliament) evidences a Government intention that administratorsbusiness judgements should not be interfered with lightly by the courts and not without evidence of irrationality.366 Both Lord Hoffmann and Sir Gavin Lightman have stated extrajudicially that such subjective phrasing

363On the use of thinkssee M. Simmons, Some Reections on Administrations, Crown Preference and Ring Fenced Sums in the Enterprise Act[2004] JBL 423, 4268.

364For arguments that this means that administrators should act to maximise total expected net recoveriessee Armour and Mokal, Reforming the Governance of Corporate Rescue, pp. 467.

365As has been noted, misfeasance actions (by, inter alia, a creditor) can be brought against administrators (or purported administrators) under para. 75 and the company does not have to be in liquidation for such an action to be commenced. On administrators owing no general common law duty of care in relation to their conduct of the administration to unsecured creditors see Kyrris v. Oldham [2004] BCC 111 (CA) and on duties of care to the company see Re Charnley Davies Ltd (No. 2) [1990] BCLC 760 where Millett J noted that the distinction between misconductand unfairly prejudicial managementdoes not lie in the particular acts or omissions of which the complaint is made but in the nature of the complaint and the remedy necessary to meet it: p. 783. As noted above, there is, to date, a conspicuousabsence of case law where administrators have been sued for breach of duty: see Keay and Walton, Insolvency Law, p. 118. This situation is unlikely to pertain as administration takes over from administrative receivership and actions under para. 75 for breach of equitable or common law duties become more frequent.

366See Simmons, Some Reections, pp. 4278; Mokal and Armour, New UK Corporate Rescue Procedure, p. 138; HL Debates, 21 October 2002, vol. 391, col. 1101 (on the Governments expectation that the courts will review the rationality of the administrators decision).

administration

445

makes it virtually impossible for a court to interfere with the administratorscommercial judgements provided that they are made in good faith,367 and, as noted above, the cases of Re Transbus International Ltd368 and Re Ballast plc369 support the view that the courts are content to defer to the judgements of administrators.

It should be noted, however, that the paragraph 3(2) duty to act in the interests of the companys creditors as a whole is not similarly phrased in subjective terms the obligation is to act objectively in pursuit of such interests, not in a manner that the administrator thinks is in the interests of creditors as a whole. The resultant tension between the subjectivity of paragraph 3(3) and the objectivity of paragraph 3(2) may open the way for judicial intervention. Thus a party challenging an administrators decision to act in pursuit of a better than winding-up result for creditors (under paragraph 3(1)(b)) rather than a going-concern rescue (paragraph 3(1)(a)) not only would be able to contest the administrators subjective estimation of what was reasonably practicable or in the interests of creditors as a whole but would be able to take issue on the grounds that the course chosen was not in fact in the interests of creditors as a whole.370 There is a similar combination of subjective and objective elements in paragraph 3(4) which empowers the administrator to realise property for distribution to secured or preferential creditors (paragraph 3(1)(c)) if he thinks it is not reasonably practicable to achieve either of the paragraph 3(1)(a) or 3(1)(b) objectives and he does not unnecessarily harm the interests of the creditors of the company as a whole(paragraph 3(4)(b)).371 These provisions are liable to come into play when an administrator might have a choice of ways to realise assets, one of which involves a quick break-up sale, payment of the oating charge

367See Swain, Move Towards a Stakeholder Society; Editorial (2002) IL&P 1212. See also Insolvency Service Guide, para. 4.1.6 and DTI Explanatory Notes, para. 648 which suggest that the court will only interfere if bad faith can be established or the decision was one that no reasonable administrator would have taken. On the facilitative attitude of the courts see Walters, Corporate Restructuring under Sch. B1.

368[2004] 1 WLR 2654, [2004] BCC 401. 369 [2005] 1 WLR 1928, [2005] BCC 96.

370Mokal and Armour, New UK Corporate Rescue Procedure, p 137.

371See Simmons, Some Reections; Simmons, Enterprise Act and Plain English(2004) 17 Insolvency Intelligence 76 (considering the use of the words thinksand harmin the statutory provisions). See also Unidare plc v. Cohen [2006] 2 WLR 974 and Lewison Js reasoning (at p. 991) on the administrators thinkingapropos Sch. B1, para. 83, discussed by Lightman and Moss, Law of Administrators, pp. 2512; L. C. Ho, Connected Persons and AdministratorsDuty to Think: Unidare v. Cohen[2005] JIBLR 606.

446

the quest for turnaround

holders debt and a low return to unsecured creditors, and the other of which involves greater delay, more considered marketing and a higher return to unsecured creditors after the debt secured by the oating charge has been paid.

The status of the administrator as an ofcer of the court372 means that, in addition to being expected to act fairly and honourably, the courts may potentially treat administratorsactivities as reviewable on the usual public law grounds of illegality, irrationality and procedural impropriety.373 As an alternative to judicial review on public law grounds, it has been argued that the courts will draw on the case law providing substance to the rationality test in the context of other duciary relationships.374

Even, accordingly, where the subjective phrasing of paragraph 3(3) is used, the administrator may be open to attack on irrationalitygrounds where he fails to take a relevant consideration into account in making a decision or takes into account an irrelevant consideration. The potential role for the courts is, accordingly, to rule on whether, in considering different possible courses of action (for example, to aim for rescue as a going concern or to achieve a better than winding-up outcome; or to realise property and distribute to secured or preferential creditors), the administrator has taken relevant factors into account, has avoided reference to irrelevant factors and has avoided taking actions that are so unreasonable that no reasonable administrator would take them.375 For an administrator subject to such potential review, this means that care should be taken to make it clear on the record that all creditorsinterests

372Sch. B1, para. 5; Ex parte James (1874) 9 Ch App 609; D. Milman, A Question of Honour[2000] Ins. Law. 247.

373See Lord Diplock in Council of Civil Service Unions v. Minister for the Civil Service

[1985] AC 374, 41114. On the status of a decisionor policy-maker as publicfor the purposes of judicial review see e.g. R v. Panel on Takeovers and Mergers ex parte Datan plc [1987] QB 815; M. Beloff, Judicial Review 2001: A Prophetic Odyssey(1995) 58 MLR 143.

374See Mokal and Armour, New UK Corporate Rescue Procedure, pp. 1378. The duty to act rationally has its roots in the law governing duciaries and can be seen as analogous to the public law concept of reasonableness: see Lightman and Moss, Law of Administrators, p. 246. Here the tests applied to trustees, according to the rule in Re Hasting-Bass [1975] Ch 25, are similar to those applied to public bodies according to

Associated Provincial Picture Houses Ltd v. Wednesbury Corporation [1948] 1 KB 223. On the rule in Hasting-Bass see Stannard v. Fisons Pensions Trust Ltd [1992] IRLR 27 (trustees were bound to give properly informed consideration to the value of a trust fund in calculating the just and equitable level of funds required to be transferred).

375Associated Provincial Picture Houses Ltd v. Wednesbury Corporation [1948] 1 KB 223.

 

 

 

 

 

administration

 

 

 

447

 

have

been

ta

ken

into

account

in

assessing

the array

o f

possib le

ac

the

basis

of

th e

info

rmation

that

is

reasona

bly

to

be expected

assessed. This

will

be

c

entral

to the

a

dminis

trators

showing

tha

have acted in a ccordance with their duty and have identied the r

considerations

and

used

a ll

proper

care

and

diligence

in

obtain

adv ic

376

The

a dministrator,

moreover,

is

377

 

 

making a

 

e.

oblig(whened

 

sta te ment setting out proposals for

a

chieving

the

purposes

of

a d

tration)

to

exp l

ain

why

he

thinks

the objectiv e ment ioned in pa

3( 1)

(a)

 

or

3(1

)(

b)

 

ca

nnot

dbe.

Administrachieve

ators,

accordingly,

 

should be

prepared

to

disclose

their

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

378

 

 

proposals and reasons fo r actio

The above considerations suggest that

 

the

judges,

if

inclined,

c o

boost th e accountability of administrators

by

exercising

inte

nsive

rev

ove r

administra tors

ac

ti v

it

i es.

W

hether

they

will

be

so

inclin

point. On one view, th e judges are likely to prove reluctant to en

interventions

that

amount

to

second-guessing

th

e

commerc

ia

l

jud

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

37

9

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

publi c law terms, to

 

ments of administrators or, w hen thinking in

 

other

than

 

defer

to

the

judgements

of

those

actors

to

w

hom

Parlia

has

e

nt

r

usted

spe

cialis

ed

38

 

0

ti

ons .

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

f

 

unc

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

In support of this view, it might be argued that the judges have

 

themselves

to

 

be

slow

to

second-guess

directors

on

issues

involved

wrongful

trading

(which

involves

 

objecti

ve

and

su

bjective

381

 

 

 

 

elements)

and that consistency should produce

a

similar

judicial

r

eluctance

r eg

ing

admin

istrators.

There

a

re

,

 

however ,

a

number

of

differences

 

in

mind

 

betw

een

 

the

parties

 

 

 

and

roles

 

involved

 

in

the

compar

Ad

ministrators

are

quasi-

public

o

fc

i

als.

D

i re

ctors

i

nhabit

 

o f p r iv a t e l a w . T h e c o ns e q u e n c e s o f i n t

 

Reviewing

an

a

dminis

trator

s

 

 

action

under

 

paragraph

74

is

most

 

to

result

 

in

th

e

court

making

 

an

order

 

to

r

egulate

the

a

dmini

37 6 Lightman

J

i n

Re

Bar

r

s

Settlement

T

rusts

[200

3]

Ch

4

09;

G.

Lightman

s

(2002)

 

IL&P

121

, 122.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

37 7 Para.

 

49(2

)(b) .

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

37 8 I.e. a

t

cr

editors

meeting s, i

f

u

 

 

nder

a

duty

to

call

them

(

see

 

par

a.

52(1)

 

37 9 See

S

wain

,

M

o

v

e

T

o

wa

r

d

 

s

a

St

a k e

h

o

l d

e r

S

o

c

i

e t

y

;

Ed

i

380See R v. Independent Television Commission, ex parte TSW Broadcasting Ltd [1996] EMLR 291 (the House of Lords stated that courts would be most reluctant to secondguess regulatory bodies on substantive issues) but cf. Mercury Communications Ltd v.

Director General of Telecommunications [1996] 1 All ER 575 (HL) criticised in A. McHarg, Regulation as a Private Law Function[1995] PL 539. On judicial reluctance to second-guess decisions on budgetary allocation see R v. Cambridge Health Authority ex parte B [ 1 995 ] 2 A l l E R 12 9, 137 .

381See Insolvency Act 1986 s. 214(4)(a) and (b); see also ch. 16 below.

448

the quest for turnaround

exercise of his functions or to vary procedures adopted. This can be seen as less dramatic than making a nding of wrongful trading which may involve a director in substantial personal liability and arguably a degree of stigma.382 For both these reasons, it might be contended that the courts will be more inclined to interfere with administratorsactions under paragraph 74 challenges than they would be to second-guess directorial behaviour for the purposes of wrongful trading.

If, however, it is assumed, for the moment, that the courts will exert a degree of control over administrators, how might they best use that control to serve the interests of rescue? One way to do this would be to exercise their powers so as to enhance expertly and efciently co-ordinated actions between the various actors involved in a rescue process while, of course, protecting the legal interests of those actors and holding the ring fairly between them. When seeking to enhance such co-ordination, furthermore, the judges might have in mind the need for key rescue decisions and actions to be based on good information, to incorporate sound judgements and to be implemented in a timely fashion.

On the generation of a good information base, the judicial role is likely to come into play when the administrators duty to garner and consider information from different parties is placed at issue. That administrator will be obliged, inter alia, to take all relevant considerations into account when devising a policy or making a decision.383 The stance of the prorescue judiciary might be to insist that administrators make all reasonable attempts to secure inputs from all of those actors who are well placed to contribute information relevant to the pursuit of the administrators statutory objectives. The administrator, accordingly, would be obliged to consult with, and take into account, the representations of such parties as directors, banks, unsecured creditors and any others who can provide relevant information. Such a judicial stance might demand of administrators that they do more than provide an opportunity for various actors to participate in the administration process it might call for administrators actively to take all reasonable steps to seek out relevant information and to consider this.

It has, however, been stressed above that inclusive processes involve considerable dangers of inefciency and losses of expertise through stultication, delay and confusion. Bearing this in mind, the judges

382See ch. 16 below.

383See e.g. Associated Provincial Picture Houses v. Wednesbury Corporation [1948] 1 KB 223; Council of Civil Service Unions v. Minister for the Civil Service [1985] AC 374.

administration

449

might make it clear in their decisions that administrators only have to seek out information and process it in so far as this is reasonable within the practical constraints of time and resourcing that they are faced with.384 In subjecting administrators to reasonableness-testing, accordingly, the judges should take the view that challenges to administratorsdecisions will only be successful where they have been shown clearly to have gone beyond the bounds of reasonableness (for example by refusing to receive inputs from parties where patently relevant information is involved). The general stance of the judiciary should be to ensure accountability and fairness through protecting the procedural rights of the various parties but, above all else, to further efciency and expertise by shielding administrators from legal delays and second-guessing and to do so sufciently to allow them to pursue their statutory objectives expeditiously. If this is not done the danger is that the administration process will prove generally too slow-moving and indecisive ever to serve the interests of rescue. The stance described may demand that the judges show a degree of deference to the administratorsjudgements on such matters as whether the need for action means that they should not carry out further investigations and consultations.

On the encouragement of sound judgements, this will, to a degree, be served by judicial actions to encourage expertise by ensuring that relevant information is considered and irrelevant matters are not taken into account. Closely related to the exclusion of irrelevancies is, moreover, protection against unfairness through bias and here it might be suggested that the judiciary should be ready to counter a number of predictable risks.

A rst such risk is, as noted above, that banks holding qualifying oating charges and acting as potential suppliers of rescue funds will use their legal and nancial muscle to induce administrators to act in their favour rather than in the interests of the body of creditors as a whole.385 Manipulation of this kind may occur through open negotiations between bank and administrator but a second risk may be that such inuence, or capture, may occur in less visible ways as where administrators adopt strategies that are excessively low risk and do so for fear of offending powerful actors, such as banks, who might contest their actions.

384See the references to reasonableness in the para. 4 duty to perform functions as quickly and efciently as is reasonably practicable.

385That is on he who pays the piper calls the tuneprinciples: see Swain, Move Towards a Stakeholder Society.

450

the quest for turnaround

The judiciary, however, may face a difcult task in exercising review so as to control the above kinds of manipulation or bias. It is one thing to ensure that administrators adopt the fair and correct procedures, and consider the relevant matters and exclude irrelevant factors, it is another to assess whether the substantive strategies or actions effected by administrators are calculated, or likely, to involve a favouring of a certain creditor or class of creditors. It is true that the paragraph 3(2) duty to act in the interests of the companys creditors is, as noted, objectively phrased, but ruling against an administrator under this paragraph demands, rst, that the court is prepared to make a judgement on business risks and, second, that the court is willing to substitute its own judgement for that of the administrator.

What, then, would a rescue-friendly judicial stance look like when faced with this dilemma whether to pursue fairness by protecting weaker creditor interests or to promote efciency by leaving administrators free enough in their judgements to be able to act expeditiously? The analysis here suggests that the role of the judge should be to exercise their review powers so as to maximise the extent to which administrators are induced to serve the interests of all creditors, and to do so by counterbalancing those risks of bias that are likely within the post-EA regime. That regime places an IP in power and so the dangers of shareholder manipulation that are encountered in DIP systems are, as noted above, replaced by risks of bank manipulation. The aim of the judiciary, accordingly, can be envisaged as ensuring that the administrator performs on a level playing eld and they can do so by offering a counter-balance to the administrators natural inclination to err in favour of the banks. That counter-balance can be seen in the shape of the prospect of judicial interference where a bias is sufciently grave to take the administrator out of his protectedarea of judgement and to constitute a patent breach of paragraph 3(2).

Turning to the judgesrole in ensuring that actions and decisions are taken in a timely fashion, a rst contribution, as indicated, is judicial action to ensure that the administrators ability to act quickly is not prejudiced by excessive legal attack and second-guessing. A second judicial task is to do what can be done to ensure that directors do not delay the instigation of insolvency processes unduly. It was noted above that disincentives to delay, through wrongful trading or disqualication provisions,386 may be of dubious value and, accordingly, the courts might

386 See IA 1986 s. 214; CDDA 1986; see also ch. 16 below.