
- •Contents
- •Acknowledgements
- •Table of cases
- •Abbreviations
- •Introduction to the second edition
- •1 The roots of corporate insolvency law
- •Development and structure
- •Corporate insolvency procedures
- •Administrative receivership
- •Administration
- •Winding up/liquidation
- •Formal arrangements with creditors
- •The players
- •Administrators
- •Administrative receivers
- •Receivers
- •Liquidators
- •Company voluntary arrangement (CVA) supervisors
- •The tasks of corporate insolvency law
- •Conclusions
- •2 Aims, objectives and benchmarks
- •Cork on principles
- •Visions of corporate insolvency law
- •Creditor wealth maximisation and the creditors’ bargain
- •A broad-based contractarian approach
- •The communitarian vision
- •The forum vision
- •The ethical vision
- •The multiple values/eclectic approach
- •The nature of measuring
- •An ‘explicit values’ approach to insolvency law
- •Conclusions
- •3 Insolvency and corporate borrowing
- •Creditors, borrowing and debtors
- •How to borrow
- •Security
- •Unsecured loans
- •Quasi-security
- •Third-party guarantees
- •Debtors and patterns of borrowing
- •Equity and security
- •Equity shares
- •Floating charges
- •Improving on security and full priority
- •The ‘new capitalism’ and the credit crisis
- •Conclusions
- •4 Corporate failure
- •What is failure?
- •Why companies fail
- •Internal factors
- •Mismanagement
- •External factors
- •Late payment of debts
- •Conclusions: failures and corporate insolvency law
- •5 Insolvency practitioners and turnaround professionals
- •Insolvency practitioners
- •The evolution of the administrative structure
- •Evaluating the structure
- •Expertise
- •Fairness
- •Accountability
- •Reforming IP regulation
- •Insolvency as a discrete profession
- •An independent regulatory agency
- •Departmental regulation
- •Fine-tuning profession-led regulation
- •Conclusions on insolvency practitioners
- •Turnaround professionals
- •Turnaround professionals and fairness
- •Expertise
- •Conclusions
- •6 Rescue
- •What is rescue?
- •Why rescue?
- •Informal and formal routes to rescue
- •The new focus on rescue
- •The philosophical change
- •Recasting the actors
- •Comparing approaches to rescue
- •Conclusions
- •7 Informal rescue
- •Who rescues?
- •The stages of informal rescue
- •Assessing the prospects
- •The alarm stage
- •The evaluation stage
- •Agreeing recovery plans
- •Implementing the rescue
- •Managerial and organisational reforms
- •Asset reductions
- •Cost reductions
- •Debt restructuring
- •Debt/equity conversions
- •Conclusions
- •8 Receivers and their role
- •The development of receivership
- •Processes, powers and duties: the Insolvency Act 1986 onwards
- •Expertise
- •Accountability and fairness
- •Revising receivership
- •Conclusions
- •9 Administration
- •The rise of administration
- •From the Insolvency Act 1986 to the Enterprise Act 2002
- •The Enterprise Act reforms and the new administration
- •Financial collateral arrangements
- •Preferential creditors, the prescribed part and the banks
- •Exiting from administration
- •Evaluating administration
- •Use, cost-effectiveness and returns to creditors
- •Responsiveness
- •Super-priority funding
- •Rethinking charges on book debts
- •Administrators’ expenses and rescue
- •The case for cram-down and supervised restructuring
- •Equity conversions
- •Expertise
- •Fairness and accountability
- •Conclusions
- •10 Pre-packaged administrations
- •The rise of the pre-pack
- •Advantages and concerns
- •Fairness and expertise
- •Accountability and transparency
- •Controlling the pre-pack
- •The ‘managerial’ solution: a matter of expertise
- •The professional ethics solution: expertise and fairness combined
- •The regulatory answer
- •Evaluating control strategies
- •Conclusions
- •11 Company arrangements
- •Schemes of arrangement under the Companies Act 2006 sections 895–901
- •Company Voluntary Arrangements
- •The small companies’ moratorium
- •Crown creditors and CVAs
- •The nominee’s scrutiny role
- •Rescue funding
- •Landlords, lessors of tools and utilities suppliers
- •Expertise
- •Accountability and fairness
- •Unfair prejudice
- •The approval majority for creditors’ meetings
- •The shareholders’ power to approve the CVA
- •Conclusions
- •12 Rethinking rescue
- •13 Gathering the assets: the role of liquidation
- •The voluntary liquidation process
- •Compulsory liquidation
- •Public interest liquidation
- •The concept of liquidation
- •Expertise
- •Accountability
- •Fairness
- •Avoidance of transactions
- •Preferences
- •Transactions at undervalue and transactions defrauding creditors
- •Fairness to group creditors
- •Conclusions
- •14 The pari passu principle
- •Exceptions to pari passu
- •Liquidation expenses and post-liquidation creditors
- •Preferential debts
- •Subordination
- •Deferred claims
- •Conclusions: rethinking exceptions to pari passu
- •15 Bypassing pari passu
- •Security
- •Retention of title and quasi-security
- •Trusts
- •The recognition of trusts
- •Advances for particular purposes
- •Consumer prepayments
- •Fairness
- •Alternatives to pari passu
- •Debts ranked chronologically
- •Debts ranked ethically
- •Debts ranked on size
- •Debts paid on policy grounds
- •Conclusions
- •16 Directors in troubled times
- •Accountability
- •Common law duties
- •When does the duty arise?
- •Statutory duties and liabilities
- •General duties
- •Fraudulent trading
- •Wrongful trading
- •‘Phoenix’ provisions
- •Transactions at undervalue, preferences and transactions defrauding creditors
- •Enforcement
- •Public interest liquidation
- •Expertise
- •Fairness
- •Conclusions
- •17 Employees in distress
- •Protections under the law
- •Expertise
- •Accountability
- •Fairness
- •Conclusions
- •18 Conclusion
- •Bibliography
- •Index
administration |
385 |
the disposal of an administration order application or the coming into effect of an out-of-court appointment of an administrator.109
The interim moratorium becomes effective, if applying to court for administration, as soon as the application is made. When a floating charge holder applies under paragraph 14, the moratorium takes effect from the date a copy of the notice of intention is filed at the court, as that is when the company or directors are seeking to appoint. The provisions of paragraphs 42 and 43 of Schedule B1 generally apply during the period of the interim moratorium.110
When an administrator has been appointed there is a general moratorium on the enforcement of remedies without the consent of the administrator or the permission of the court.111 As noted previously, the moratorium is procedural in nature, suspending the power to enforce rights but not destroying such rights. The company cannot then be wound up112 and the consent of the administrator or the leave of the court is required for such actions as enforcing a security against the company, repossessing goods in the company’s possession under a hire purchase agreement, exercising a right of forfeiture by re-entry,113 or the commencement or continuation of any other legal proceedings or levying distress against the company or its property.114 Protection also extends to property owned by the company but in the possession of third parties such as lessees.115 An administrative receiver cannot be appointed when the company is in administration and an administrative receiver already in office must vacate.116
Financial collateral arrangements
At this point consideration must be given to the insolvency effects of the Financial Collateral Regulations 2003117 and their implementation of the
109Para. 44.
110Except that winding-up petitions on public interest grounds under IA 1986 s. 124A or
Financia l Se r vices and Marke ts Act 20 00 s . 367 are not prevented: see fur th ‘Public Interest Liquidation: PIL or Placebo?’ [2002] Ins. Law. 157 and ch. 13 below. The appointment of administrators by qualifying floating charge holders (QFCs) (under
para. 14) is similarly not prevented under the interim moratorium, nor is the appointment of administrative receivers.
111Paras. 42, 43 – applicable whether the administration is out of court or via a court order.
112Para. 42(2)(3).
113See Metro Nominees (Wandsworth) (No. 1) v. Rayment [2008] BCC 40.
114Para. 43.
115Re Atlantic Computer Systems plc (No. 1) [1992] Ch 505, [1992] 2 WLR 367, [1990] BCC 859.
116Paras. 43(6A), 41(1).
117Financial Collateral Arrangements (No. 2) Regulations 2003 (SI 2003/3226).
386 |
the quest for turnaround |
EU Directive on Financial Collateral Arrangements.118 The purpose of the Directive was to enhance the effective use of financial collateral across the EU and its implementation involves streamlining arrangements for creating collateral and providing for easier realisation of collateral through enforcement.119 For insolvency lawyers, the significance of the 2003 Regulations lies in their neutralising certain insolvency provisions so as to benefit particular lenders. The Regulations go beyond the Directive and apply to all banks and companies taking financial collateral. Such collateral includes cash and financial instruments (government securities, shares, bonds and other financial instruments such as units in collective investment schemes).120 Collected book debts and other sums credited to bank accounts will be covered but not uncollected book debts or other types of collateral, such as commercial property, plant and machinery. The Regulations apply to security interests such as mortgages and fixed charges and to floating charges provided that the collateral is ‘in the possession or control of the collateral taker’.121
In the case of such collateral, Regulation 8 disapplies various insolvency provisions relating to administration and winding-up, notably: the Schedule B1 paragraph 43(2) veto on enforcing a security when the company is in administration without the consent of the administrator or the court’s permission; the Schedule B1 paragraph 44 interim moratorium on enforcing a security that operates as soon as an application for administration is made; the Schedule B1 paragraph 41(2) rule that any receiver shall vacate office if required to do so by the administrator; and the Schedule B1 paragraphs 70–1 power of the administrator to dispose of property subject to certain types of charge.122 The effect of the Regulations is to assure lenders of easy enforcement in the case of insolvency. Such provisions, however, can be seen as reducing the availability of company cash deposits to fund administrations and to
118Directive on Financial Collateral Arrangements 2002/47/EC.
119See S. Lawson, ‘New Financial Collateral Regulations’ (2004) Recovery (Autumn) 22; A. Sharp, ‘The Collateral Directive – A New Way of Thinking About Security’ (2004) 17
Insolvency Intelligence 145.
120Lawson, ‘New Financial Collateral Regulations’.
121‘Given the current debate on floating charges, this can only safely apply to floating charges that have crystallised.’ See Lawson, ‘New Financial Collateral Regulations’, p. 22 and J. Benjamin, Financial Law (Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2007) pp. 476–8.
122The 2003 Regulations also disapply the automatic avoidance provisions of the
Insolvency Act 1986 s. 245 (floating charges), s. 127 (property dispositions) and s. 88 (share transfers after a winding-up resolution): see Sharp, ‘Collateral Directive’, pp. 147–8.
administration |
387 |
fly in the face of the Enterprise Act’s conception of administration as a rescue mechanism.123
Preferential creditors, the prescribed part and the banks
Other important provisions of the Enterprise Act 2002 concern priorities and the protection of vulnerable creditors. The Crown’s status as preferential creditor was abolished by section 251 of the EA.124 It is estimated that this will result in some £70 million per annum flowing to other creditors.125 The EA also introduced ‘ring-fencing’ of a prescribed proportion of the company’s net floating charge proceeds. These proceeds are to be made available to the company’s unsecured creditors and only surpluses of funds following such use will be available for distribution to the floating charge holders.126 The ‘prescribed part’ of funds for ring-fencing is stipulated by Statutory Instrument.127
123See the comments of practitioners: Sharp, ‘Collateral Directive’; Lawson, ‘New Financial Collateral Regulations’: ‘Secured lenders will have increased leverage over cash assets which may otherwise be used to fund the administration … [They] may be able to avoid the new prescribed part provisions altogether either by taking certain floating charge assets for themselves or relying on the Regulations to disapply the prescribed part provisions once the charge has crystallised.’
124Paras. 1, 2, 3–5C, 6, 7 of the IA 1986 Sch. 6 are deleted. Preferential debts that remain are: unpaid contributions for occupational pensions; four months of unpaid employee wages and holiday entitlements; and unpaid levies in respect of coal and steel production. See further ch. 14 below.
125See IS, Regulatory Impact Assessment for Insolvency Provisions in the Enterprise Act 2002
(IS, London, 2002) (hereafter ‘EA 2002 RIA’) para. 5.29 – this is based on the Crown recovering £90 million per annum preferentially in all insolvencies and the estimate that this would drop to some £20 million per annum when the Crown became unsecured.
126See IA 1986 s. 176A. This is an echo of the Cork Report’s proposal for a 10 per cent fund: Report of the Review Committee, paras. 1538–49. On the ‘prescribed part’ see further ch. 3 above and ch. 13 below. Whether, on the wording of s. 176A, a floating charge with an unsecured balance is entitled to participate in the prescribed part funds has been a matter of debate. The Insolvency Service is of the view that the floating charge holder is not entitled to participate in any distribution, a view upheld by His Honour Judge Purle QC in Permacell Finesse Ltd (in liquidation) [2008] BCC 208: noted D. Offord, ‘Case Digest’ (2008) 21
Insolvency Intelligence 30. See also Re Airbase (UK) Ltd, Thorniley v. Revenue and Customs Commissioner [2008] BCC 213: noted A. Walters, ‘Statutory Redistribution of Floating Charge Assets: Victory (Again) to Revenue and Customs’ (2008) 29 Co. Law. 129; see also ch. 15 below. For a contrary view see G. McPhie, ‘New Legislation’ (2004) Recovery (Autumn) 24.
127See Insolvency Act 1986 (Prescribed Part) Order 2003, SI 2003/2097 – 50 per cent of net property where that net property is less than £10,000; above £10,000, then 50 per cent of the first £10,000 in value and 20 per cent of the excess, up to an overall limit of £600,000. See also ch. 3 above.
388 |
the quest for turnaround |
For the banks, as holders of post-EA (or ‘qualifying’) floating charges, the EA produces a significant alteration in substantive rights. Whereas a receiver owes a duty to look only to the interests of the floating charge holder, the administrator has a duty to act in the interests of the creditors as a whole and in pursuance of the ‘tiered’ objectives set out now in Schedule B1, paragraph 3(1)(a), (b) and (c). Under paragraph 3(3) of Schedule B1 the administrator, as noted, is only to realise property to distribute to one or more secured or preferential creditors if (a) he thinks that it is not reasonably practicable to achieve either of the objectives in 3(1)(a) or (b) (i.e. rescuing the company as a going concern or achieving a better result for creditors as a whole than would be likely in a winding up) and (b) he does not unnecessarily harm the interests of the creditors of the company as a whole. The reforms do not change priorities in an insolvency but may have a substantive effect on the floating charge holder. This is because a floating charge holder who appoints an administrator rather than an administrative receiver is dealing with a regime in which the administrator has to take into account interests other than the floating charge holder’s and in which rescuing the company has a degree of primacy in relation to satisfying the secured creditors’ interests.
Lobbying by powerful lenders in the period leading up to the EA produced a set of impressive procedural rights for the banks.128 The British Bankers’ Association (BBA) argued forcefully during 2001 that administrative receivership had been a very successful ‘engine for reconstruction and enterprise in the UK’.129 Receivership, said the BBA, had allowed secured creditors to ‘appoint somebody who is able to act quickly and manage the restructuring process in a way which has saved businesses and jobs in a cost effective manner’.130 The thrust of this argument was that any new administration procedure that was to be rescuefriendly had to be streamlined and fast. The Enterprise Act 2002 moved towards such streamlining by removing the need for a Rule 2.2 report and limiting the number of circumstances requiring a court
128A remarkable dilution of the Government’s original intentions achieved by the banks’ ‘tremendous power in the lobby’: see J. Willcock, ‘How the Banks Won the Battle for the Enterprise Bill’ (2002) Recovery (June) 24, 26 (quote attributed to D. Mond of Hodgsons).
129BBA, Response by the BBA to the Insolvency Service White Paper, Insolvency – A Second Chance (October 2001) (hereafter ‘BBA, Response to White Paper’).
130Ibid., p. 3; on receivership as a rescue procedure, see ch. 8 above.
administration |
389 |
procedure.131 Now a lender (bank) files a notice of appointment declaring that: they are the holders of a qualifying floating charge in respect of a company’s property; the charge is enforceable; and the appointment is in accordance with Schedule B1 to the Insolvency Act 1986.132 For the secured lender, appointing an administrator will differ little from the current process for appointing a receiver. Banks are able to use the streamlined appointment procedure in all cases, not merely situations of urgency, and they are able to determine who should be appointed to the post of administrator.133 This gives the banks the power to insert their chosen administrator with speed and without regard to the other creditors or the courts. As has been observed: ‘Even if the company or its directors choose an administrator, effectively the holder of the floating charge can choose an alternative administrator.’134 The overall effect, then, is that floating charge holder concerns have largely been sought to be met in the Enterprise Act – to the extent that one group of practitioners has argued: ‘It may be better to describe the reforms as a “transmutation” or “merger” of administrative receivership and administration
131The Association of Business Recovery Professionals (R3) estimated a standard r. 2.2 report to be between £4,000 and £8,000 (based on £1 million turnover, £500,000 book value of assets expected to realise £200,000): see EA 2002 RIA, para. 5.27.
132If there is a prior qualifying charge (per Sch. B1, para. 14(2)) to that held by the lender (the bank), then the bank may not appoint an administrator unless it has given at least two business days’ written notice to the prior charge holder (enabling the prior qualified floating charge holder to consider appointing an administrator itself): see Sch. B1, para. 15.
133See Sch. B1, paras. 14(1), 18(3). On how the court resolves competing proposals regarding the identity of the administrators where there is no QFC see R. Tett and F. Paterson ‘World Class Administrators’ (2005) Recovery (Summer) 24; Re World Class
[2005] 2 BCLC 1. See also The Oracle (North West) Ltd v. Pinnacle Services (UK) Ltd
[2008] EWHC 1920 – where significant creditors have a clear preference for one administrator over another and the secured creditor and other creditors are neutral, the court should decide in favour of the wishes of those creditors, particularly given that
administration is intended for their benefit.
134 S e e M . S te v e n s o n , ‘ The Enterprise Bill 2 002 – A Move T owards a (2002) 18 IL&P 155, 157. Mond argues: ‘I don’t like the fact the bank can appoint an administrator of its own choice without reference to the court. That is very, very dangerous. It feels like a back door way of receivership’ (quoted in Willcock, ‘How
the Banks Won the Battle’, p. 26). See also p. 428 below on the effect this may have to incentivise administrators to keep the banks happy. If an administration application is made by a party other than the floating charge holder (e.g. by a company or directors) and the floating charge holder applies to have its chosen administrator appointed instead, the court shall allow this unless it thinks it right to refuse ‘because of the particular circumstances of the case’ (Sch. B1, para. 36(2)).