Добавил:
Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:
Учебный год 22-23 / Finch - Corporate Insolvency Law - Perspectives and Principles.pdf
Скачиваний:
7
Добавлен:
14.12.2022
Размер:
7.09 Mб
Скачать

666 gathering and distributing the assets

Alternatives to pari passu

In moving to consider possible alternatives to pari passu it is useful to focus, again, on what a regime for distributing an estate post-insolvency should achieve. The contention in this book is that insolvency laws and processes should be designed to produce acceptable combinations of efciency, expertise, fairness and accountability characteristics.166 This implies that the devices and processes that make up the regime for distribution should offer players in the marketplace a range of low-cost modes of protection against insolvency risks but that they should also avoid allocating risks in ways that produce unfairness or inefciency and should satisfy principles of accountability and transparency in seeking to ensure that both fairness and efciency concerns are satised.

The means for delivering the above desiderata may, accordingly, be to offer a range of devices (for example, security, retentions of title, trusts) but to set those devices up so that they are legally certain as well as identiable and employable at minimal cost. The protections offered by insolvency law should also be designed to protect vulnerable parties who

would bear insolvency risks inefciently or unfairly if left unprotected. How are the vulnerable to be identied?167 It can be repeated, rst, that

parties will not be vulnerable if they can (at reasonable cost) secure preferential positions in distributions or if they can (again at reasonable cost) adjust terms and loan rates to reect risks borne. The Crown is able to position its tax levels in a manner that anticipates default rates and this is a consideration that endorses the Enterprise Act 2002s abolition of the Crowns preferential status. Employees, in contrast, exemplify parties who are ill-positioned to adjust their credit rates to take account of default risks.168 Some traders may be unable to adjust rates because the time scales they work to are too short, the costs of information collection are too high or relevant data may be unavailable. Accepted commercial procedures within a trade may, moreover, make accurate risk assessment non-feasible.

Another sign of vulnerability one also noted in chapter 14 is a low capacity to absorb losses. The ability to spread risks increases a partys capacity to withstand the consequences of default.169 The Crown, again,

166See ch. 2 above.

167This section builds on V. Finch, Is Pari Passu Passé?[2000] Ins. Law. 194 at 20610.

168See generally B. Gleig, Unpaid Wages in Bankruptcy(1987) 21 UBC L Rev. 6183. But

see p. 609 above.

169 S. S. Cantlie, Preferred Priority in Bankruptcyin Ziegel, Current Developments, pp. 43344.

bypassing P A R I P A S S U

667

is well placed and can spread default risks across taxpayers who, in turn, are likely to be able to cope with marginal increases in tax rates without suffering catastrophic consequences. Resilient traders tend to be those

whose businesses are not totally dependent on the viability of one particular debtor170 and who are involved in the supply of goods or services to a large

number of customers. If one of their customers becomes insolvent they are less exposed to disaster than those trade creditors who deal with only one main customer. Most trade creditors are relatively protected in this respect, as are many tort victims. Employees, on the other hand, are seldom able to spread default risks and so are highly vulnerable.171 Tort creditors and consumer creditors, as has been seen, will tend to be lower-cost risk bearers than employees since they will usually have other sources of income, funds and products, and risks will be spread by such diversication.

Bearing in mind such issues of fairness to the vulnerable and ef- ciency, it is almost time to consider particular alternatives to pari passu but before doing so we should map out the limitations of the role that pari passu plays in the insolvency process.172

The rst such limitation is in the breadth of that role. It can be argued that by the time the pari passu principle comes into play many of the difcult insolvency law questions have been posed and answered.173 There is force in this point. The role of pari passu is dened and limited by the shape of exceptions and bypassing arrangements that insolvency law allows. As has been indicated, those exceptions and bypassing devices raise, in themselves, numerous issues of efciency and fairness (not to mention expertise and accountability). To allow the use of such devices is not merely to reduce the role of pari passu, it introduces principles and priorities to override pari passu. When teachers say The sweets will be distributed equally to all children in the classwe see a single, clear principle of fairness. When they say All red-haired childrens appetites will, however, be satised rst and then equal distribution will take place, the fairness of Animal Farm comes to mind.

Limitations of scope do not in themselves, however, constitute reasons for abandoning pari passu. Questions arise as to the acceptability of the overriding principles that qualify pari passu but it could still be argued

170 Ibid. 171 Ibid.

172For arguments that pari passu is less important than it is generally held out to be, see F. Oditah, Assets and the Treatment of Claims in Insolvency(1992) 108 LQR 459 at 46876; Mokal, Priority as Pathology; L. C. Ho, Goodes Swan Song to Corporate Insolvency Law(2006) 17 EBLR 1727; see also ch. 14 above.

173See Mokal, Priority as Pathology, esp. pp. 5878.

668 gathering and distributing the assets

that pari passu is the most appropriate method of redistributing residual assets and that other principles would, even in relation to the residual assets, produce signicantly different (perhaps less acceptable) results for residual claimants.

If, however, the role of pari passu is seen in terms of ensuring that unsecured creditors are dealt with in an efcient and fair way, it should be noted that there are approaches to this issue that go beyond asking how the residual assets should be distributed and that these can be seen as further limitations on the importance of pari passu. Five such approaches can be noted. These look to protect unsecured creditors through:

*rethinking how the estate is constructed (for example, by considering priorities and deferrals);174

*procedural protections (for example, improving transparency and disclosure through insolvency regimes);

*substantive protections (for example, augmenting the residual estate with the section 176A prescribed part fund or directorscontribution through personal liability);

*reducing insolvency risks (for example, through training of directors, corporate governance improvements, educating traders in reasons for corporate collapse, encouraging banks and secured creditors to monitor);

*spreading insolvency risks: either across groups of companies;175 or through compensation schemes;176 or through insurance mechanisms.177

If these alternatives are borne in mind it can be concluded that the role of pari passu is modest, given that issues concerning pari passu are linked to, and surrounded by, a host of not inconsiderable questions. This does not, however, mean that pari passu is of insignicant importance.

A second limitation of pari passus role is that it is not wholly clear. The principle can be said to be weak because it operates in a confused manner due to the multiplicity of potential exceptions and bypassing arrangements encountered in law and practice. The above discussion

174A class of creditor that might be dealt with specically by statute is the company director: see ch. 14 above, pp. 61314.

175On insolvency issues raised by corporate groups see ch. 13 above.

176As in the travel industry via ABTA: see p. 654 above.

177On insurance limitations and availability see S. Shavell, On Liability and Insurance(1982) 13 Bell Journal of Economics 120; V. Finch, Personal Accountability and Corporate Control: The Role of Directorsand OfcersLiability Insurance(1994) 57 MLR 880 at 88792.

bypassing P A R I P A S S U

669

suggests that there is scope for clarifying the rules governing exceptions and bypasses. Such clarication might be expected to reduce the costs incurred by parties seeking to protect themselves from insolvency risks but distributional consequences may ow: ordinary creditors who are still ill-placed to secure protections may be faced with a yet smaller residual estate as other parties take greater advantage of newly facilitated protections.

A number of questions are raised. A rst issue is whether particular exceptions and bypasses are justiable in themselves. This chapter and the last have explored a number of issues that arise on that front. A further matter, however, is whether, as a collectivity, the array of exceptions and bypasses involves too great a degree of confusion and too large a mass of uncertainty to offer efciency and fairness. Viewed collectively, the question is whether a simpler, more rational and legally certain array of devices might be devised. If it is accepted that wellresourced, well-informed creditors will take any steps they think rational to protect themselves against the risks of insolvency, the challenge is to allow them to do this at lowest cost consistent with the fair treatment of other unsecured creditors: to achieve an acceptable balance of efciencyserving and distributionally fair ends. At present, it could be argued, the worst of two worlds is achieved: the well-resourced expend too much money and time on protection and the poorly-resourced are left with too small a fund to draw from. Such reasoning suggests that a statutory clarication of the law relating to exceptions and bypasses would have much to offer provided that this reduced legal uncertainties and the costs of achieving protections while, at the same time, it provided adequate protections for those who cannot reasonably be expected to negotiate themselves into protected positions.

The nal question for consideration in this chapter is whether the residual ordinary creditors who are left with a collectively fairfund should be allocated shares in it pari passu or by other principles of distribution. To return to the children in our Orwellian classroom, distribution to the pupils might be governed by a principle of evenness but alternatives could be argued for. Larger shares could, for instance, be given to well-behaved children; to those who lodge confectionery claims rst; to those who shout loudest; to those who need sugar most; to those who fared badly in prior distributions; or to those who would create most trouble if not favoured.

Let us now turn to consider the main alternatives to pari passu distribution of the residual estate.