
- •CONTENTS
- •CONTRIBUTORS
- •PREFACE
- •Introduction
- •I. A Positive Account
- •II. Normative and Historical Accounts
- •III. Explaining Legal Doctrine
- •A. Willful Breach
- •B. Comparative Fault
- •Conclusion
- •ACKNOWLEDGMENT
- •Introduction
- •C. Summary
- •Conclusion
- •Introduction
- •B. Some Striking Nuances in Common Law Systems
- •II. A Market Function Approach
- •A. Ethics or Economics – The Wrong Question
- •B. Party and Market Expectation as Guidelines
- •D. Fault, Foreseeability, and Other “Softeners” of Strict Liability
- •Conclusion
- •I. Fault and Uncertain Contractual Intent
- •II. An Expanded Law and Economics Approach to Fault
- •III. A Fault-Based Approach to Contract Damages
- •Conclusion
- •Introduction
- •A. A Model
- •B. Fault
- •C. A Comparison: Strict Liability Versus Negligence
- •II. Doctrine
- •A. Impossibility/Impracticability
- •B. Reasonable or Substantial Performance
- •C. Good Faith and Best Efforts
- •D. Interpretation/Implied Terms
- •E. Conditions
- •F. Damages
- •Introduction
- •I. Unconscionability
- •A. Markets
- •B. Moral Fault
- •II. Unexpected Circumstances
- •III. Interpretation
- •IV. Mistake
- •C. Cases in Which the Nonmistaken Party Neither Knew nor Had Reason to Know of the Mechanical Error
- •V. Nonperformance
- •Conclusion
- •Introduction
- •I. Modernizing Tort and Contract Around Fault
- •II. Explaining the Fault Swap
- •Conclusion
- •Introduction: From Fault to Negligence – and Back
- •I. Tort Law
- •III. Gratuitous Transactions: Bailment and Agency
- •A. Coggs v. Bernard
- •C. Siegel v. Spear and Comfort v. McGorkle
- •D. Medical Malpractice, Occupier’s Liability, and Guest Statutes
- •IV. Frustration and Impossibility
- •Conclusion
- •Conclusion
- •A. Analogies in Criminal Law
- •B. Lay Assessments of Culpability
- •C. Two Ways of Defining “Willful”
- •B. “Willful” as a Test for Inefficiency?
- •B. Optimal Damages Under Strict Liability
- •Conclusion
- •II. Cost of Correction Versus Diminution in Value
- •B. Treatment by the Courts
- •Conclusion
- •Introduction
- •C. An Information-Based Explanation
- •B. Informal Lessons from the Example
- •D. From Moral Hazard to Adverse Selection
- •II. Willful Breach Doctrine
- •A. Overcompensatory Expectation Damages
- •B. Tort Damages for Bad-Faith Breach
- •C. Restitution
- •Conclusion
- •Introduction
- •I. Expectation Damages and Willful Breach
- •II. Willfulness, Material Breach, and Damages
- •Conclusion
- •Introduction
- •A. Noncooperation
- •B. Overreliance
- •A. Setting the Stage
- •B. Noncooperation
- •1. When Should Avoiding Overreliance be the Default Rule?
- •Conclusion
- •Introduction
- •I. Stipulation, Fault, and Mitigation
- •II. Encouraging Stipulation
- •A. How Courts Encourage Parties to Stipulate
- •B. Two Advantages of Stipulation: Knowledge and Mitigation
- •Conclusion
- •Introduction
- •II. Comparative Negligence
- •III. Mitigation
- •IV. Reasonable Reliance
- •V. Causation
- •VI. Foreseeability
- •Conclusion
- •I. Summary of the Argument that Breach May Not Be Immoral Given the Incompleteness of Contracts
- •F. When Is Breach Immoral and When Is It Moral in Practice?
- •II. Criticism and Discussion of the Foregoing Argument
- •Conclusion
- •Introduction
- •I. Promise De-moralized, Contract Moralized
- •II. Contract and Promise: More on the Relationship
- •IV. Harm, Fault, and Remedies for Breach
- •V. Fault and Institutional Harm
- •Conclusion: Toward a Moral Law of Contract
- •I. Breach as Moral Harm
- •III. Moral Norms as Default Rules
- •Conclusion
- •CASE INDEX
- •SUBJECT INDEX
Fault at the Contract-Tort Interface • 117
it acknowledges that part of what parties to a contract are involved in is the generation of a public good – in this case the public good of safe products.51 This idea should not sound farfetched. It is intuitive that contracting parties generate a public good in the shape of trust in the market, or the idea of safe contracting. Consider, for example, the difference between analyses of nondisclosure and misrepresentation: When dealing with silence regarding features of the transaction, we are willing to consider information as a possible entitlement whose allocation should be sensitive to efficiency concerns.52 But the analysis of misrepresentation is fundamentally different, quintessentially fault based, and obviously reliant on sources outside the parties’ own agreement – and yet, no less contractual for that. Nondisclosure can theoretically be overcome simply by asking the right question. Misrepresentation, however, threatens to unravel the basic background trust without which market transactions would be far more difficult.
Conclusion
Th e point of this analysis has obviously not been to suggest the optimal scheme for governing problems of products liability. Rather, the much more modest goal has been to show that whichever side of the tort-contract boundary is relevant for solving the problem, the parties cannot be conceived of as sole originators of the solution. To paraphrase Leon Green, the polity is a party to every contract.53 Contract, like tort, is a mode of social regulation whose rules ought to serve social goals. The idea that the parties’ own interests, narrowly construed and bargained over, could exhaust the relevant social goals was a pipe dream of late nineteenth-century legal science. Today, at times, it appears that contracts enthusiasts tap into the rhetoric of that dream – and its resurrection does more to confuse than illuminate current thinking. Recalling the roots of contract as a fault-based regime and the reasons that drove nineteenth-century theorists to characterize it as based on strict liability reminds us of the socially imposed duties that function as building blocks of contract. One may hope the reminder will serve as a mild corrective for some of the confusion.
51For an analogous argument in the context of medical malpractice, see Jennifer Arlen, Contracting over Malpractice Liability (Law & Economics Research Paper Series, Working Paper No. 08–12, 2008), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1105368.
52See Anthony T. Kronman, Mistake, Disclosure, Information, and the Law of Contracts, 7 J. Legal Stud. 1, 22–7 (1978).
53Leon Green, Tort Law Public Law in Disguise (pts. 1 & 2), 38 Tex. L. Rev. 1, 257 (1959–60). For the contract version of the claim, see Cohen, supra note 23.