
- •Contents
- •Preface
- •Razak
- •The Symbolic Balance of Power
- •The Unwritten History of Resistance
- •Resistance as Thought and Symbol
- •The Experience and Consciousness of Human Agents
- •3. The Landscape of Resistance
- •Background: Malaysia and the Paddy Sector
- •Middle Ground: Kedah and the Muda Irrigation Scheme
- •Land Ownership
- •Farm Size
- •Tenure
- •Mechanization
- •From Exploitation to Marginalization
- •Income
- •Poverty
- •Institutional Accers
- •4. Sedaka, 1967-1979
- •The Village
- •Rich and Poor
- •Village Composition
- •Land Tenure
- •Changes in Tenancy
- •Changes in Rice Production and Wages
- •Local Institutions and Economic Power
- •The Farmers' Association
- •The Ruling Party in Sedaka
- •Class-ifying
- •Double-cropping and Double Vision
- •From Living Rents to Dead Rents
- •Combine-Harvesters
- •Rituals of Compassion and Social Control
- •The Remembered Village
- •Ideological Work in Determinate Conditions
- •The Vocabulary of Exploitation
- •Bending the Facts: Stratification and Income
- •Rationalizing Exploitation
- •Argument as Resistance
- •Obstacles to Open, Collective Resistance
- •The Effort to Stop the Combine-Harvester
- •"Routine" Resistance
- •Trade Unionism without Trade Uniom
- •Imposed Mutuality
- •Self-Help and/or Enforcement
- •"Routine" Repression
- •What Is Resistance?
- •Rethinking the Concept of Hegemony
- •Penetration
- •Conflict within Hegemony
- •Who Shatters the Hegemony?
- •Bibliography
- •Index
148 • HISTORY ACCORDING TO WINNERS AND LOSERS
and of other villages in Kedah is not one of dramatic and sharp contrasts between a small monopolistic landlord class on the one hand and a great mass of undifferentiated poor peasants on the other. This is not Morelos in 1910. The stratification of Sedaka, while not a seamless web from top to bottom, is diverse enough to militate against the creation ofa solid phalanx ofvictims. The presence of bystanders and neutrals tempers what might otherwise be a sharper conflict. Finally, the local conflict that does exist is further tempered by the fact that virtually all paddy cultivators share certain interests (fur example, Malay political domination and a high support price fur paddy) despite their class antagonisms. All of these factors make fur "ordinary" fOrms of class struggle rather than a conflagration.
I turn, with these qualifications in mind, to a brief social history of Sedaka's green revolution by class. I shall ask how each of the major changes in production relations has been experienced and interpreted by the rich and by the poor-by winners and losers. From these interpretations, which can be seen as two, class counterpoints to the economic facts presented in the previous chapter, it should be possible to construct a picture of village class relations.
DOUBLE-CROPPING AND DOUBLE VISION
There are by now scores of studies of the consequences of double-cropping in Muda, many of them quite sophisticated. Reflecting the interests of international donors and the Malaysian state, they are virtually all concerned with production, incomes, and growth. In their entirety, it might seem they offer a more or less exhaustive account of the consequences of the green revolution in Kedah.
We should scarcely be surprised, however, if the overall assessment of doublecropping held by the actual participants in this drama differs significantly in tone and content from the official account. After all, the participants have their own narrow and homely concerns. Nor should it surprise us if the vantage point of the well-to-do should diverge sharply from that of the poor. Ifone asks villagers about the impact of double-cropping, what emerges is a core zone of general agreement that gives way to a zone of dispute as well as a zone of differences in perspective. It is in these last two zones that class is decisive.
Virtually everyone agrees that double-cropping has brought with it some beneficial changes. They note the rebuilding and patching of houses, the fact that only two of the richest villagers had motorcycles before 1972 while many of the wealthier households now have them, that the roads and bus service now allow them to visit Alor Setar and nearby relatives. But the big news that completely overshadows these welcome conveniences is the simple fact that, fur the first time in living memory, virtually everyone has enough rice to eat throughout the year. Even well-off villagers rarely fail to mention this, fur they can remember crop failures when even their supply gave out. For the poor, of course, the basic fear that has always plagued the peasantry has been all but
HISTORY ACCORDING TO WINNERS AND LOSERS • 149
banished. It is the first thing that comes to their minds: "Even the poor can hold out now, they caneat" (Dullah); "There's enough rice" (Sukur); "The rice is never used up." (Wahid). Their subsequent complaints about recent hardships must be seen against the backdrop of this cardinal achievement. And yet, one may look in vain through piles of official reports to find any recognition of the single result of double-cropping that dominates all others so far as the peasants are concerned.
Beyond this narrow but important zone of consensus, evaluations diverge. Neither the rich nor the poor of Sedaka are unifOrmly enthusiastic about the changes double-cropping has brought about. Given the recent setbacks the poor have experienced, their complaints are to be expected. The complaints of the larger farmers, however, are curious, since they have been the principal beneficiaries of this highly touted scheme. At first one is tempted to refer their grumbling to a universal human (at any rate, peasant) perverseness that only grudgingly admits to good fOrtune, but the nature of their complaints betrays an unmistakeable class perspective. They are resentful, above all, that it is no longer possible to buy land. Thus Haji K.adir says that things were "better before" irrigation when "we could save money and buy land at only M$1,000 a relong." Kamil, who rents 15 relong, grumbles that he is no better off now than he was ten years ago and that land is now out of reach. What is involved here is not only a nostalgia fur the days when land went fur M$1, 000 a relong but also fur the days when poor smallholders were furced by debts (jua! janji) to fOrfeit their land to creditors. This is, in fact, how Haji K.adir and others made their small fOrtunes. Kamil senses that this avenue of mobility is now closed to him.
This does not exhaust their complaints. They grumble about the high cost of living, the difficulty and expenses of getting fieldhands when they need them, and the fact that even they often need loans. In more reflective moods, prosperous villagers occasionally regret the loss of leisure and the entertainment they once enjoyed between the harvest and the next planting-a time when most of their poorer neighbors were off looking fur work. Now they are busy all year round. They miss especially the small feasts, games, and Islamic chanting that had graced the off-season befure 1972. 18 Seldom is this lament terribly acute, fur no one would be willing to furego a second crop of rice in order to recover these cultural amenities.
18. The feast they most often mention is the kenduri berendul, literally "cradle feast," celebrated fur recently born infants, which includes a ceremonial haircutting and, for girls, circumcision. During my stay this was celebrated only twice. The games they mentioned included main gasing, or competitions with spinning tops, and bersi!at, the Malay/Indonesian act of self-defense, both of which are very rarely seen today. The Islamic chanting from the Koran includes berdikir and berzanji, which are still occasionally perfOrmed, often by groups that are paid a fee, at feasts in the village. All of these activities are described as hiboran, or "entertainment."
150 • HISTORY ACCORDING TO WINNERS AND LOSERS
When it comes to the effects of double-cropping on their own economic situation, the comments of the substantial farmers in the village are oddly out of keeping with the narrow facts of the matter. All these families have benefited substantially, to judge from their incomes and possessions. And yet, many of them acknowledge no improvement; they say things are about the same as before. If pressed, they may admit to some slight easing: ''I'm a bit better off"; "We don't have to scrimp so"; "We can just get enough to eat." 19 When it comes to what irrigation has done for the village poor, though, these men are far more expansive. To hear them tell it, the poor have done very well. One of them says, "Since the change in seasons, even coolies (that is, landless laborers) are using motorcyles." Another, complaining of the cost of labor, insists that wage workers have become so comfortable that they can afford to be choosy. They often claim that nowadays the poor are as comfortable (senang) as the rich were before doublecropping. In effect, they greatly underplay their own gains and at the same time overdramatize the new prosperity of the poor-a pattern that we shall see repeated.
For villagers in more precarious circumstances, matters are more straightforward. After acknowledging that their basic food supply is secure, they generally go on to emphasize how their prospects have worsened. As Hamzah notes, "I work nonstop, [but} there's not a chance of becoming comfortable." He and others in the same boat contrast the substantial gains of the well-off with their own difficulty in providing their families with necessities such as fish, clothing, and school expenses. While the rich complain that they have no leisure, the poor have the mirror-image complaint: that they have no work. They can and do recite in minute detail who hired them and how much they earned in the past, comparing that income with the current lack of work. For them, unlike the rich, the watershed is not the beginning of double-cropping but the entry of combine-harvesters. Their sense of time, the significant dates in their lives, are necessarily different, as is their experience. A majority of them, it is true, are almost certainly no worse off than they were prior to the irrigation scheme. But their point of reference is now the first four or five years of double-cropping (1972-76) when work was plentiful and wages high. It is from that point that they measure their current hardships and it is perhaps only in the context of these hardships that the early years of irrigation have become "the good old
days." |
' |
At the core of this reversal of fortunes, |
in their view, is not simply the |
impersonal working out of technological change, but the elimination of human dependencies. Karim, whom Haji Kadir once cited as a rare example of the hard-working poor, captures the perspective of many poor villagers. Before, he
19. Sudah tambah sikit; tak kena layang macham dulu; boleh makan saja. Layang means "to slice thinly," hence "to scrimp."
HISTORY ACCORDING TO WINNERS AND LOSERS • 151
explains, "those who were hard up depended on people who were well-off. "20 He mentions, as did Pak Yah, wages paid in advance as an example and tells me that they are no longer given and instead poor villagers have only the Chinese pawnshop as a creditor of last resort. "They [the landowners}," he continues, "don't need us any more; if we don't come to thresh paddy, they can just call the machine. " Mansur, another landless villager, covers much the same ground as he deplores the evaporation of postharvest zakat peribadi he once received from cultivators for whom he threshed but who no longer need his help. The village poor, then, not only realize precisely what they have lost in wages, in work, and in gifts but are quite well aware that they are no longer an integral part of rice production at all. 21
FROM LIVING RENTS TO DEAD RENTS
Fixed cash rents payable before planting were not unknown befure double-crop- ping, but it was only with the expanding cash economy after 1971 that they became the rule rather than the exception. We encounter once again a nearly intractable zone of disagreement about the facts when it comes to determining how many tenants actually lost part or all of their farms when the switch to prepaid rents was made. Estimates range from a maximum of about ten to a minimum of three or fuur. The higher figure is closer to the village consensus while the lower figure finds support among a handful of wealthy villagers. There seems no way to decide the matter. Razak, fur example, had rented 5 relong under the traditional arrangements from his older brother (an outsider) until 1972, when his brother announced that he was taking it back to give to his own son to cultivate. Razak claims that his brother used this as an excuse to kick him off the land and gives as evidence the fact that two seasons later his brother rented the land out again to a new tenant, with the rent to be paid in advance. The story is plausible, in part, because dismissing a tenant to give the land to one's own child is one of the few ways of displacing a tenant that is seen as legitimate. For precisely that reason, it is often viewed as a ploy used by landlords who wish to act discreetly. But it is impossible to be certain of the facts in this case or in many others, where the landlord claims that the tenant simply decided to give up the land. In any event, the "damage estimate" attributed to the shift to sewa tunai is extensive if one listens to most villagers and relatively paltry if one listens to a few of the wealthiest.
For those who rent out land on any appreciable scale, the advantages of sewa tunai are obvious. As the rent is no longer denominated in paddy equivalents,
20. Orang susah-lah bergantung kapada orang senang.
21. This is, of course, especially true of the pure wage laborers in Sedaka, but it is also true of the more numerous marginal smallholders and tenants who have traditionally relied on fieldwork wages fur a larger share of their income.
152 • HISTORY ACCORDING TO WINNERS AND LOSERS
the landlord's return is not hostage to farm-gate prices. Should the paddy price increase, the cash rent can simply be raised the following season; should it decrease, the tenant absorbs the loss. Prepaid rents, of course, arrive five or six months earlier under the new arrangement, giving the landlord the use of the capital fur that much longer. Above all, sewa tunai avoids disputes and confrontations on the threshing floor in the case of crqp damage or failure. It was never an easy matter to determine the cause of a harvest shortfall, whether it was due to the· negligence of the cultivator, in which case no remission was granted, or whether it was due to weather or pests, in which case a remission was ordinarily negotiated. The size of the remission was also a source of acrimonious exchanges that often left both sides feeling shortchanged. Now the landlord need never even look at his fields or listen to the dubious pleas of his tenants after a bad season. Only one option is open to a dissatisfied tenant: giving up the tenancy.
Those who adopt a landlord's perspective are naturally delighted. Kamil, himself a large tenant, but whose rents are very modest (M$120 per relong, per season), notes that "cheating" was 'common under the older, sewa padi system. 22 The cheating might take the furm of surreptitious harvesting at night befOre the official harvest began, spiriting away some of the grain at the actual harvest if supervision was lax, shoddy threshing so as to leave much paddy on the stalks to be gleaned and kept later, and above all spurious claims of crop damage to cover any or all of these subterfuges and thereby reduce the rent. Tenants, to be sure, walked a fine line in pursuing these strategies which, if pushed too far too often, might lead to their dismissal. Under sewa tunai, however, all of these ploys are simply irrelevant. Haji Salim, a very large landowner and entrepreneur who lives just outside the village, makes it clear that prepaid cash rents provide an element of labor discipline. "These people [tenants} are scoundrels," he says. 23 BefOre sewa tunai, he adds, they could cultivate carelessly and then ask fur a reduction in rent, claiming that worms or caterpillars had damaged the paddy. Now, however, "If they give the money first, they have to look after the crop carefUlly, they can't just play around. They have to take it a bit more seriously. "24
The disadvantages of sewa tunai fur tenants are as palpable as the advantages for landlords. Those who know most poignantly about the disadvantages are, of course, those who actually lost their tenancy when the shift was imposed. Even fur the majority who managed to raise the cash in time, the costs were considerable. They typically took loans on their wives' gold jewelry (given to most
22.Masa sewa padi, penyewa boleh tipu, senang-lah! Kamil is referring here to actual sharecropping, which has long since disappeared from the usual meaning of sewa padi.
23.Orang ini jahat. This phrase might also be translated as "These people are playing tricks."
24.Kalu bagi duit dahulu, depa kena jaga kuat, tak boleh main-main saja, kena ambit berat sikit.
HISTORY ACCORDING TO WINNERS AND LOSERS • 153
women by their parents upon marriage) and paid 2 percent a month to the pawnshop in Yan until it was redeemed, hopefully, after the harvest. If the paddy crop was good, this proved a minor inconvenience; if the crop was poor, however, it became a financial crisis. 25 The jewelry might be fOrfeit, the husband might have to leave the village to find work elsewhere, or debts might simply accumulate. As sewa tunai has become more prevalent, it has also exerted a subtle but unmistakable influence on other furms of tenancy. Those lucky enough to have tenancies in which the rent is payable after the harvest and thus, in principle, is negotiable are increasingly reluctant to avail themselves of this privilege fur fear that the landlord will retaliate by moving to prepaid rents. 26
The key objection from the tenants' perspective is simply that the rent is fixed and bears no relation to the paddy yields of a particular season, that is, to the tenant's ability to pay. As they say, "You can't take it into account, you can't bargain, you can't compromise, you can't do anything. "27 This, is not simply a statement of fact delivered in an impersonal way. The phrase most often heard in connection with sewa tunai-often enough to have become almost a sloganis, "If the paddy is ruined, that's your (the tenant's} lookout."28 It is spoken with gestures and facial expressions to imitate a callous landlord announcing the facts of life to his tenant. It implies, of course, that the state of the paddyand therefOre of his tenant-most definitely ought to concern any self-respecting landlord.
What is involved here, as most villagers see it, is thus a shift in rents that mirrors a portentous shift in the quality of class relations. The attitude of landlords when rents were adjustable was described as magnanimous (senang kira). 29 This term is the opposite of berkira, or "stingy" and "calculating," which is normally the most devastating charge made against the rich, as we have seen. To be senang kira is to inhabit a social world in which an amicable reciprocity prevails and in which no one is trying to take undue advantage of others. It is a value as much breached as observed but is no less powerful fur that reason. The contrast between how things were and how they are is apparent from Amin's description. "Befure they said, 'If the harvest is bad, [we'll} reduce (the rent} a
25.Wahid is an illustration: he rents 6 relong and would ordinarily be expected to fall in the middle range of village incomes despite his large family. For the past two seasons, however, he has had quite poor yields of nine or ten gunny sacks per relong and fairly high rents that are not negotiable. As a result his earnings have been minimal and he is openly debating giving up two of his three rented plots and working much of the year in Penang.
26.This holds true fur many tenancies in which the landlord is a close relative as well.
27.Tak boleh rundingkan, tak boleh tawar-menawar, tak boleh tolak ansur, tak boleh apa-apa.
28.Padi rosak, hang punya pasal.
29.Senang kira might be translated literally as "easygoing about calculating."